|
National
Planning and the American Myth
By
Henry C K Liu
This article appeared in AToL
on June 13. 2002
Adam Smith published The Wealth of Nations in
1776, the year the United States declared independence. By the time the
constitution was framed 11 years later, the founding fathers were
deeply influenced by Smith's ideas, which constituted a reasoned
abhorrence of trade monopoly and government policy in restricting
trade.
What Smith abhorred most was a policy known as mercantilism, which was
practiced by all major powers at the time. It is necessary to bear in
mind that Smith's notion of the limitation of government action was
exclusively related to mercantilist issues of trade restraint. Smith
never advocated government tolerance of trade restraint, whether by
other governments or by big business monopolies. In fact, Smith
advocated an activist government against market failures. A truly free
market cannot tolerate monopolistic practices. Yet unregulated markets
naturally drift towards monopolies. In other words, markets fail when
deregulated. After a decade of deregulation, the evidence of market
failure is everywhere.
A central aim of mercantilism was to ensure that a nation's
exports remained higher in value than its imports, the surplus in that
era being paid only in specie money (gold-backed as opposed to fiat
money). This trade surplus in gold permitted the surplus country, such
as England, to invest in more factories to manufacture more for export,
thus bringing home more gold. The importing regions, such as the
American colonies, not only found the gold reserves backing their
currency depleted, causing free-fall devaluation (not unlike that faced
by current Asian currencies), but also wanting in surplus capital for
building factories for export. So despite plentiful iron ore in
America, only pig iron was exported to England in return for English
finished iron goods.
In 1795, when the Americans began finally to wake up to their
disadvantaged trade relationship and began to raise European (mostly
French and Dutch) capital to start a manufacturing industry, England
decreed the Iron Act, forbidding the manufacture of iron goods in
America, which caused great dissatisfaction among the prospering
colonials. Smith favored an opposite government policy toward economic
production and trade, a policy that came to be known as "laissez faire"
(because the English, having nothing to do with such heretical ideas,
refuse to give it an English name). Laissez faire, notwithstanding its
literal meaning of "leave alone", meant nothing of the sort. It meant
an activist government policy to counteract mercantilism. Neo-liberal
economists are just bad historians, among their other defective
characteristics, when they propagandize "laissez faire" as no
government in trade affairs. At this juncture in history, when the
failures of neo-liberal market fundamentalism is pervasively
discernible, the myth of the American system as anti-statist and
anti-planning needs to be re-examined.
Another interesting item about Adam Smith was that he
advocated, in 1776, a graduated income tax, "the time of payment, the
manner of payment, and the quantity to be paid, ought all to be clear
and plain to the contributor, and to every other person". Reaganites
should put that in their hats and eat it.
After the ratification of the constitution, among the first
acts of Congress was to adopt, on September 2, 1789, a motion by James
Madison to establish a Treasury Department, and to instruct the future
secretary to "digest and prepare plans for the improvement of the
revenue and for the support of the public credit". This instruction led
Alexander Hamilton, the first secretary of the treasury, to establish
the first Bank of the United States in 1791, which after many
transformations ended up as the Federal Reserve system of today.
Hamilton also engineered the first government bailout of
private investors in US history by making the government buy from
investors/speculators, at face value, all the market-discounted debt
instruments and paper money various state governments as well as that
the federal government had issued during the War of Independence. Since
one of the causes for independence had been the right to manufacture,
Hamilton launched a national plan to develop manufacturing that
included government subsidies (called bounties). He also instituted
protective tariffs on imports, and committed massive public investment
in infrastructure. It was the first industrial policy in US history, a
classic national planning measure.
Thomas Jefferson was directly involved in land planning for
political purposes in contrast to economic efficiency. He believed that
his notion of democratic government could be safeguarded by the
widespread ownership of land by small farmers. He would fail in this
aim, as 28 percent of the land in the United States today is still in
government hands, and most non-residential land is owned by big
corporations. Jefferson was influenced by the economic doctrines of the
French Physiocrats, who claimed that the ultimate source of wealth was
land. Jefferson, as president, bought from Napoleon Bonaparte the
Louisiana Purchase in 1803, doubling the land area (and the intrinsic
wealth) of the nation. It was an act of national planning of heroic
dimension.
John Quincy Adams, in 1807, as senator, shepherded through
Congress a resolution to direct the treasury secretary to draw up a
plan for internal transportation. The ensuing Gallatin Plan, named
after secretary Albert Gallatin, aimed to connect the states on a
north-south axis and to provide for transport from the west to the
eastern seaboard. The railroads in the US did not have the benefit of
central planning, except in land policy. But that did not mean the
government was not involved. In encouraging its development for
advancing the national interest, the government granted large tracts of
public land to railroad companies to connect the Midwest and the
Pacific. Twenty square miles of public land (alternative
quarter-sections along the entire rail line) was granted to private
railroad companies for every mile of track, and the feasibility norm
for return on capital in the new industry was 200 percent annually,
excessive by any measure.
The lack of government supervision and regulation led to widespread
political corruption and fraud against investors, and the rate fixing
and price gouging resulted in reduced economic efficiency that
eventually destroyed the industry, except during periods of war
planning. It was only when such abuses ran up against another powerful
special interest, the shipping industry, that an Interstate Commerce
Commission was formed to control the railroads, but still to little
avail. The monopolistic pricing practices of the railroad were a key
factor in the unethical formation of John D Rockefeller's oil empire.
Between the Civil War and World War I, there were three major
economic recessions: 1873, 1883, and 1907. In contrast to Adam Smith's
doctrines, during that period, "trusts" were organized to eliminate
competition at the expense of small businesses, farmers, consumers and
especially labor. As late as 1920, 12-hour days and seven-day work
weeks were common practice in the steel industry, while industrial
companies enjoyed protective tariffs from government and generous tax
benefits such as accelerated depreciation for tax purposes, all
government pro-business intervention measures.
The Sherman Anti-Trust Act was adopted in 1890 to prohibit
restraint of trade, a true classic Adam Smith measure. But the act has
had a history of difficult enforcement due to conservative regulatory
and constitutional interpretation and circumventing devices, such as
holding companies and interlocking directorates, that even the later
Clayton Act of 1914 failed to achieve an effective curb. Whether
anti-trust measures belong to the category of national planning depends
on who is being busted and the attitude of the categorizer toward
planning. Conceptually, they are planning measures pure and simple.
Social Darwinism, resurrected as a miracle diet for national
prosperity in the 1990s, went briefly out of fashion in the US in the
1920s. But in its place, conservatives peddled new arguments that
economic planning for the collective good was beyond human capacity
(the futility/unintended consequence argument), and as being alien to
traditional American values, in denial of historical fact.
World War I forced the US into war planning. The War
Industries Board, the Food Administration, with a government-owned
Grain Corp, injected purposeful priority in resource allocation to
maximize production efficiency, with guaranteed markets and
price-stabilizing measures. Labor standards were instituted, along with
recognition of unions and the right to collective bargaining. Women
joined the labor force with the beginning of the principle of equal pay
for equal work. The government-run Railroad Administration in 1918
handled 10 million ton-miles more than the private companies did under
a free market in 1917.
After the war, national economic planning advocates sought to
continue planning under Theodore Roosevelt's prewar campaign theme of
New Nationalism, the so-called "Square Deal". An influential book by
Herbert Croly, The Promise of American Life, argued for a
Hamiltonian government interventionist approach toward Jeffersonian
populist ends.
War and revolution being half-brothers, the postwar vision of an ideal
economic order came from socialists, syndicalists, guild socialists,
and promoters of consumer cooperatives. Even the Catholics opposed the
"servile state" and offered a program of "distributivism". Of course,
the Church has more than 2,000 years of experience in institutional
planning.
Little if any of the liberal vision touched isolationist
America, which was eager for a "return to normalcy", with wholesale
abandonment of the progressive social regime that won the war. Labor
standards suffered serious slippage, with minimum wage/maximum hours
requirements and collective bargaining discarded as wartime
anachronisms, if not outright evils.
A speculation/inflation spiral developed with the sudden end
of wartime price control, fueled by easy credit for speculation. As
much as one-third of asset value was based on inflation anticipation.
The collapse came quickly, in 1920-21, the sharpest recession in recent
memory, with severe deflation, causing high unemployment (4.75
million), farm failures (453,000) and business bankruptcies (100,000).
Yet the 1920-21 recession, though severe, was short. Prosperity
returned, subject only to a slight dip in 1924 and again in 1927.
Corporate profit rose at an annual rate of 9 percent. Stock prices rose
at an annual rate of 14 percent by 1927, even before the start of the
final bull market run that ended in the crash two years later. Workers
and farmers, who fared well under wartime planning, did not share in
this postwar boom, the so-called Coolidge prosperity, also know in
history as the New Era. Between 1919 and 1930, mergers and acquisitions
eliminated 8,000 manufacturing and mining companies, and 5,000 public
utilities.
Ultimately 10 holding companies controlled 72 percent of all
electricity sales. By 1929, fewer than 200 companies owned half of the
corporate assets and 20 percent of the national wealth. The
concentration of ownership enabled the business owners to increase
their income three times as fast as their employees', which was not at
all what Adam Smith had in mind.
The 1929 crash eventually forced president Herbert Hoover, the
engineer-turned-free-enterprise-businessman, to resort to planning by
carrying out a campaign promise to aid farmers in the Agricultural
Marketing Act, which called for self-regulating producers cooperatives
for each crop, with price control and government guaranteed markets.
While the stock-market crash was not the cause of the Depression, it
was one of the factors that intensified it. Every schoolboy was told
that Hoover did not have a plan to counteract the Depression, except to
wait idly for a return to prosperity around the corner. But in fact
that was Hoover's plan, with full support from the business community,
based on the assumption that the fundamentals of the economy were
sound, and the only trouble was a speculative collapse of the stock
market, and the plan was to insulate business against loss of
confidence. Hoover also mistakenly believed that private enterprise was
the principle element of stability, instead of being a weak point of
the economic structure and a destabilizing agent by nature of booms and
busts. Hoover's plan called for an active collective denial, but
unfortunately, events were unforgiving. Sounds very familiar to what is
going on in the linked economies of the world today.
The Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act was signed into law by Hoover in
June 1930, despite a plea from 1,028 members of the American Economic
Association to veto it. Import duties were raised to 59 percent, the
highest since 1830. Instead of saving the US from the Depression, it
plunged the world into a downward spiral that eventually led to World
War II.
Meanwhile, early reports of successes in Soviet planning
renewed calls from government, business organizations, academe, and
labor unions in the US for a more orderly development than the
free-for-all ways that had led to the collapse of the New Era. It was a
coalition between progressive ideology, which was grudgingly accepted
by business, and scientific management, which business enthusiastically
endorsed.
In 1928, the Soviet Union, under a new state planning
commission called "Gosplan", worked out the First Five-year Plan,
putting an end to Lenin's New Economic Policy (NEP). This plan
succeeded in rapidly developing capital industries but failed in
reorganizing agriculture. Many US management engineers were recruited
by the Soviet First Five-year Plan. Returning to the US in the depth of
the Depression, they brought with them a fresh enthusiasm for national
planning within the capitalistic system that excited public interest.
In 1931, a book about Russian planning, New Russia's Primer, even
made the Book-of-the-Month Club.
Franklin D Roosevelt became president of the United States on March 4,
1933. Neither an economist nor a central planner, not even a
businessman by virtue of being independently rich from birth, FDR was
dedicated to public service. He was assisted by his "brain trust", a
group of progressives such as R G Tugwell and Raymond Moley of
Columbia, Henry Wallace, an agricultural reformer, Herbert Fei, Adolf
Berle and Donald Richberg, experts in law an economics. FDR's
administration marked the entrance of academics into government in the
ancient Chinese tradition. But FDR, likening himself to a quarterback,
called all the shots, some fundamentally contradictory with others. FDR
faced urgent problems: a systemic banking crisis, farm bankruptcies and
high unemployment. His first term was consumed with rescuing the
capitalistic order from its structural faults, and not the
establishment of a new system of central economic planning. Two days
after he became president, FDR forbade the export of gold and directed
banks not to pay out gold in exchange for currency. The Emergency
Banking Act (March 9, five days after inauguration) authorized the
Reconstruction Finance Corp to buy bank preferred stocks, a back-door
nationalization measure.
Of the three new agencies created in quick succession by first
New Dealers - the Agricultural Adjustment Administration (AAA - May 12,
1933), the Tennessee Valley Authority (TVA - May 18, 1933), and the
National Industrial Recovery Act (NIRA - June 16, 1933) which
authorized industrial planning - only the TVA survived in its original
form. The Supreme Court demolished most of NIRA in 1935 and parts of
the AAA in 1936. The flurries of socio-economic legislation passed in
the "first 100 days" were all interventionist. Despite the Economy Act
(March 20, 1933), which pledged to hold down government expenditure and
cutting federal salaries by 10 percent, FDR proposed with congressional
sanction, huge unemployment relief and other social projects such as
the highly successful Civilian Conservation Corps, the first public
environmental protection effort; the Federal Emergency Relief
Administration; the Civil Works Administration; the Work Progress
Administration; the Emergency Farm Mortgage Act; and the Home-Owners'
Loan Act.
The most far-reaching was the Glass-Steagall Act (June 16,
1933), which separated commercial banks from investment banks on the
ground of conflict of interest, which was repealed in 1999. The
Railroad Coordination Act was passed on the same day as Glass-Steagall.
On January 31, 1934, FDR by permission of Congress devalued the dollar,
reducing its gold content by 40 percent. It was a "beggar thy neighbor"
devaluation policy opposed by Adam Smith. The first New Deal promoted
economic planning in industry and agriculture in the Soviet style (some
say the Italian Fascist style), and ran up against a reactionary
Supreme Court. The second New Dealers, including Justice Brandeis,
whose fear of the stifling of free competition by big business was
greater than his embrace of laissez faire, needed a respectable
economic theory to support their spending program in an era of
declining government revenue. They found him in John Maynard Keynes,
through Felix Frankfurter, who introduced Keynes to FDR.
World War II planning was well recognized as the most
important contribution to victory. The Cold War gave planning a bad
name, as it did anything else that had the slightest leftist
association. Grants in support of planning stopped abruptly in academe.
But corporate planning that strengthened the corporate system
institutionally and theoretically flourished as management science.
Just as the church commandeered all talents in the Middle Ages in the
name of God, and the monarchies established royal academies to capture
all talents in the service of the king, postwar America monopolized all
talents, including the whole discipline of planning, in the service of
corporate market capitalism, leaving statism starved for talent.
Corporate planning flowered in shiny computerized corporate
headquarters, while national central planning withered in a neglected
garden. But it does not follow that the latter is genetically inferior.
June 2002
|
|
|
|
|