The Coming Trade War
By
Henry C.K. Liu
Part I: The Coming Trade War and Global Depression
Part II: Dollar Hegemony Against Sovereign Credit
Part III: Trade in the Age of Overcapacity
Part IV: Scarcity
Economics and Overcapacity
This article appeared in AToL on July 28, 2005
Neoclassical economics developed at a
time when wealth was
limited to what a relatively primitive industrial society could
produce, and
demand for goods was always greater than their supply.
It is the economics of scarcity rooted in the medieval rule of parsimony, or principle
of economy, frequently used by Franciscan monk William of Ockham (ca.
1285-1349), which came to be known as Ockham’s Razor. Or to put
it
another way, scarcity, leading to the need for economy, is the
determinant
behind economics theory. The Franciscans, with their devotion to the
poor and
opposition to an opulent church, were the modern-day communists of the
medieval
Church.
Marxism is rooted in German philosophy.
Dialectic materialism as expanded by Karl Marx
(1818-83) is based on Hegelian dialectics, a term for the natural
tendency of
the mind to proceed by creating contrasting opposites. A thesis
inevitably
produces an antithesis, which would equally inevitably be followed by a
reconciliation and fusion into a synthesis, which in turn becomes the
new
thesis, to be opposed by a new antithesis. It is a cyclical concept of
life
discovered by the Daoists more than two millennia before Georg Wilhelm
Friedrich Hegel (1770-1831), albeit that the Daoists emphasize
fundamental
constancy while Hegel emphasizes conceptual change.
The more things change, the more they stay
the same, according to Daoists.
Hegelian dialectics introduced philosophy into the
Western
study of history as a view of human social evolution through time.
Social
reality is a process developing through time, a consequential unfolding
of
connected events, necessary, logical and deterministic. By materialism,
Marx asserts
that the basic element in social organization is economic. Rejecting
Hegelian
idealism of ideas forming society, Marx asserts that ideas are formed
by the
economic institutions of society, at the base of which are the
“relations of
production” which determine the shapes of religion, politics,
philosophy, law
and morality.
Yet Hegelian ideals are the stuffs of revolution,
the
speeding up by tour de force the natural evolution of dialectics.
Communism is
a transitional stage rooted still in the neoclassical economics of
scarcity. It is through communism that
society will eventually evolved into socialism based on an economics of
plentitude. Yet communists are not evolutionists; they are
revolutionaries who
want to frog-leap the evolutionary process. They
are in essence idealists. Thus communists
are Marxist in the theory and
Hegelian in practice.
Christianity is not known for its tolerance. It is a
religion of “tough love.” Nicolo Machiavelli (1469-1527) recounted the
pious
cruelty of Christianity. David Hume (1711-76) exposed the intolerance
of
Christians in comparison with the Pagans. Friedrich Wilhelm Nietzsche
(1844-1900) attacked Christian love as a fraudulent disguise for
virulent
hatred for all that was humanly vigorous, beautiful and noble. The
history of
Christianity is replete with militant religious intolerance.
The history of Christianity is closely linked to the
evolution of capitalism, notwithstanding that Jesus overturned the
tables of
the money lenders and expelled them from the Temple because those
responsible
for maintaining the holiness of the holy were unable to separate
service to God
from service to Mammon, the demon of love of money. Christianity
subscribes to
the notion of collective genetic guilt, as capsulated in the concept of
original sin. By that concept, all Germans are perpetually guilty of
the sins
their ancestors committed in the Holocaust, all North Americans are
perpetually
guilty of the sins committed by their ancestors on Native Americans and
all
Whites are perpetually guilty of the sins committed on Blacks and other
colored
peoples. The Bible records that Abraham confronted God’s decision of
punitive
destruction for Sodom and Gomorrah with the demands of justice, urging
Him to
consider the innocent along with the wicked. God’s decision on Sodom
and
Gomorrah was an act of indiscriminate religious terrorism. It set a
morally
questionable precedent for state terrorism such as the Blitz of London,
the
bombing of Dresden, the two atomic bombs dropped on Japan, the bombings
of
Vietnam and modern-day insurgent terrorism. While critical of clerical
corruption, Luther mounted an attack on what he regarded as a
structural flaw
in Christian theology, by declaring the right of every individual to be
his own
priest through revelation from the Bible, in the name of the spiritual
equality
of all believers. The Reformation was misnamed. Luther
was not interested in saving a corrupt
Church through reform; he
aimed to save Christianity by dismantling orthodox theology. But the
Bible, the
source of Luther’s religious revolution, is a holy book with many dark
sides.
Monotheism,
Scarcity and Imperialism
Biblical faith itself has been a stunning moral
source for the critique of
biblically-based religious doctrine. The monotheism myth, the belief in
the one
true God, creator of heaven and earth, constitutes a system in which
identity
depends on the rejection of multiculturalism and the subjugation of
personal free
will and independence. Some modern writers have placed monotheism at
the root
of evil in the Western world. Monotheism’s vehement legacy is the
implied
consequence of the law of scarcity, which is built upon a logic that
rules the
scarcity paradigm that proclaims that there will never be enough of the
blessings and good things necessary for prosperity, such as land,
resources,
even food and water, let alone oil, to go around for all to enjoy
freely.
But the law of scarcity, like monotheism, is a
baseless
myth, because it does not reflect the visible truth about the real
world. The
scarcity myth has come to be regarded as a law in large measure through
the
enormous influence that the Bible has exerted on the making of the
Western
mind, and thus the Western fixation on material accumulation. There is ample evidence that scarcity is the
result of man-made mal-distribution rather than a natural state.
Buddhism views the world as a place of plenty, thus
Buddhists have no desire or need to accumulate material things. For
Buddhists,
the only accumulation worthy of effort is good deeds. Joy belongs to
the giver.
The law of scarcity does not derive its all-inclusive power and its
pervasive
influence from facts about the real world or communal human
experiences. Its
authority flows from faulty metaphysical principles and misguided
Christian
beliefs about the nature of God. Scarcity is encoded in the Bible as a
principle of Oneness (one land, one people, one nation) and in
monotheistic
thinking (one Deity). It becomes a demand of exclusive allegiance that
threatens with violence of exclusion. Imperialism and globalization are
direct
geopolitical outcomes of the Christian quest for the holy grail of
Oneness.
While the dark side of the Bible
sanctions the formation of a collective
identity that is singular, static and exclusionary, it also provides
hopeful
glimpses of an identity that is multiple and mobile, inclusive and
evolving,
governed by the good “principle of plentitude” and not the evil law of
scarcity. The principle of plentitude affirms that there are enough of
the good
things to go around, and proclaims the ethical imperative of
generosity, and
envisages a world of ceaseless giving. Neoclassical economics dismisses
the
principle of plentitude as being outside of the concerns of economics.
Charity
is a voluntarism in the province of morality, not economics. When
President
Bush promotes voluntarism as a substitute for public welfare programs,
he is
advocating the abdication of government responsibilities, declaring
that
compassion is a personal and not a state function, while he injects
self-righteous morality in US foreign policy. Because
Americans are a compassionate people,
they are expected to
exempt their government from being compassionate also. As for the all
voluntary
army, there is nothing voluntary about it; it is all economic coercion.
Economics science needs to repudiate scarcity and to rehabilitate
plentitude.
Today the monotheistic notion of market fundamentalism is given
expression through
the doctrine of free trade, with an unbalanced preoccupation with human
political rights rather than human economic rights and welfare, and the
flawed
assumption that political equality can be achieved without economic
equality,
all of which are distorted moral principles that are so taken for
granted in
the neo-liberal West that it tends to view as a symptom of deformed
mentality
questions regarding the value system that underlies such warped
morality.
Neo-liberals have become decadently self-satisfied with unquestioned
slogans of
the indisputable economic benefits of political freedom and equality.
They have
become happily trapped in self-delusions that deny glaring realities
that
reflect neither freedom nor equality, nor economic benefits to the
majority.
They find solace in blaming the undeniably obscene outcome on the bad
decisions
by market participants rather than the structural fault of the market
system.
Cathedrals, the greatest achievement in Medieval Europe, were not built
by market
forces. Postmodernists are even worse; they are notoriously dismissive
of the inquiring
search for historical foundations to seek self-celebration in devising
new
meanings for well-understood words to justify contemporary anomalies as
timeless truth.
The importance of the idea that every
individual is created in the image of God
is dramatically revealed in the concept of the Garden of Eden. The
story of the
expulsion by God of the first man and woman from the plentiful Garden
of Eden
is viewed as a fall from an initial blessed state of wholeness, peace,
and
perfection, a descent from a regime of plentitude to one governed by
the law of
scarcity. The law of scarcity stands for a regressive and destructive
worldview. Scarcity, the assumption that someone can only prosper when
someone
else does not, proliferates fratricide and genocide. Scarcity is an
idea that
the writers in the Bible invented and sadistically inscribed in the
mind of the
faithful, a law manufactured by monotheism out of necessities in a
primitive
society in which insufficiency was the norm, and the desire to stand
apart and
excel was necessary for survival of the specie and must not be viewed
as
something shameful. To have more than
others in a world of scarcity is regarded as a sign of heroic
accomplishment.
Selfish love is not conceptually inconsistent; and not even
undesirable, for it
is a permissive basis for drawing sharp boundaries between the beloved
and the
rest of the world.
The Ideal
of Plentitude
Although generally overwhelmed in the Bible by the law of scarcity,
God's
making man in his image exemplifies the ideal of plentitude. The law of
plentitude means the rejection of one God in favor of many gods; and it
requires not merely diminishing the distance between the divine and the
human
but heroically eliminating it. As reality shows man in a great variety,
the
image of God must also be multidimensional.
The biblical story of the Tower of
Babel is a mythical tale
of God crushing man’s godly ambitions and punishing him with
divisiveness. The
consequence of unsuppressed pride and rebelliousness to God on the part
of the
people is bondage to human overlords. And thus the division of people
into
peoples of many different tongues is God’s strategy for keeping humans
human in
order to preserve deity. Striving to preserve unity and aspiring to
godliness,
the people resolved to build a city, construct a tower towards God and
make for
themselves a name. The name of the city where men sought to reach God
was
Babel, a word which comes from a root meaning “confusion” and which
contains
the Hebrew word for “heart.” The story of Babel thus prizes not
monumental
structures conceived by human minds and produced by human hands, but
the human
heart which brings man closer to God. A single world nation united by a
universal language promotes a false sense of human powers, of what
human beings
can accomplish by taking matters into their own hands. Monotheism
abhors
pluralism, but pluralism is a gift that God bestows on humankind to
make us
more human. Like Adam and Eve, the builders of Babel were cast out of a
peaceful, easy life of plenty and fell to a realm of the scarcity for
challenging God. Scarcity is a devise to keep humans ungodly.
Much of neoclassical economics has to do with improving
efficiency to increase production to come closer to eliminating
undefeatable
scarcity. The objective is always to increase supply through new
investment for
greater productivity and efficiency. Yet
for neoclassical economics, the quest for the elimination of scarcity
is like
trying to catch the hood ornament of a moving car from the driver’s
seat, with
the goal remaining unreachable at any speed, or any amount of
investment. But the
world economy now, through technological progress and deregulated
markets, has
entered a stage of global overcapacity in which neoclassical economics
of
scarcity has become obsolete and the management of aggregate demand is
the necessary
solution. Material overcapacity is a result of mental undercapacity.<>
A New Economics of
Plentitude
According to the rules of neoclassical economics, over-consumption
is a path to financial ruin. But overcapacity is also a path to
financial ruin
in a market economy. Capacity represents sunken investment which
requires
continuous positive returns. Under-utilization of capacity translates
directly
into inefficiency, a deadly sin in economics because idle plants are
non-performing assets that result in financial losses. Overcapacity is
not
merely a temporary under-utilization of capacity; it is the systemic
inability
to achieve full or at least optimum utilization. Yet
overcapacity is a structural condition in
the world of scarcity economics, because excess capacity is the
condition
needed to prevent the emergence of shortages, which is another name for
scarcity. But scarcity is needed to maintain economic value as
expressed in
market prices. Thus the market model of neoclassical economics must
constantly
be plagued with the curse of scarcity while simultaneously preventing
scarcity
with the more fatal disease of overcapacity. This contradiction is the
internal
paradox of neoclassical economics that traps the market economy in an
arrangement of never being able to enjoy the full capacity of its
productivity.
The insecurity generated by looming scarcity drives savings
which as investment adds to more overcapacity. And
savings reduce current consumption,
meaning lowering demand which
adds to overcapacity. The challenge of a market economy in an age of
structural
overcapacity then shifts from how to produce more to how to sell more.
Marketing
becomes the critical task of management. The answer for decades has
been to use
planned obsolescence to ensure recurring demand. Another answer was to
lower
prices to broaden the market. Advertising stimulates the desire for
goods, but
only rising income increases demand for goods.
A more rational solution than planned obsolescence would be
to end its inherent waste and to manage real demand to sustain full
utilization
of capacity to produce lasting quality products. This
means consumers need to have sufficient
income to buy quality goods and services produced by the market
economy. But
neoclassical monetary economics has created a financial scheme in which
the
people producing the goods cannot afford to buy them unless profit is
greatly
reduced if not eliminated, and the people receiving the profit from
goods production
cannot consume more of these goods. The reservoir of productivity is
overflowing while the defective plumbing of neoclassical monetary
economics
continues to block the delivery of goods to a public deliberately kept
thirsty
for more goods. At times, needed aggregate demand is created by
irresponsible
monetary policy, either with the depreciation of money, which is the
monetary
effect of inflation, or with easy credit, leading to debt bubbles that
can
cause severe economic damage at times of reckoning.
It is time to shift from the economics of
scarcity to a new economics based on the concept of plentitude to cure
the
modern-day plague of scarcity in a land of overcapacity.
Mercantilism and
Fiat Money
Unless products are sold for gold to Martians, or at least
to foreigners or colonial subjects in a mercantilist trade regime,
lowering
prices requires a corresponding lowering of wages, which in turn
shrinks
effective demand further. Mercantilism is not merely a quest by nations
for
gold, but a quest for national purchasing power in the international
market as
expressed by the relatively constant monetary value of gold. In a world of fiat currencies not backed by
gold, mercantilism cannot exist by definition. Any nation that
habitually
incurs trade deficits will find its fiat currency not accepted by its
trading
partners. Any nation that incurs export trade surpluses denominated in
a
foreign fiat currency is engaged in reverse mercantilism, i.e.,
shipping real
wealth overseas for paper.
Thus it is outrageously preposterous for the US, a country
of recurring trade deficits denominated in fiat dollars, to accuse its
exporting trade-surplus partners of practicing mercantilism when the US
trade
deficit is essentially an undisguised abuse of unearned privilege of
inexhaustible national purchasing power in the form of dollar hegemony
- an
international monetary anomaly that permits the US to print paper
dollars in
exchange for real products from its trading partners exporting to the
US
market. Dollar hegemony is based on oil
being denominated in dollars in the world market. When the US, in the
name of
national security, would not permit a Chinese company, such as CNOOC,
to use
its trade surplus denominated in fiat dollars to purchase a US-based
oil
company, 80% of whose assets are located in Asia that will never enter
the US domestic
oil market, it is not a move to protect oil supply in the US. It is in fact a move to protect dollar
hegemony.
Protecting Dollar
Hegemony by Making the Fiat Dollar less
Fungible
But such a policy to protect dollar hegemony in effect makes
the fiat dollar less fungible. The latest report shows CNOOC being put
in a box
of no escape in its effort to outbid rival Chevron Corporation in the
competition to buy Unocal Corporation. The
Unocal board was reported on July 20 to be backing a sweetened offer
from
Chevron that will pay $63 a share in cash and stock, up from a previous
offer
of $60.50 a share. CNOOC’s all cash
offer stood at $67 a share on July 20. CNOOC
needs to raise its cash offer to $70 a share to win, but the higher
offer would
solicit more political opposition from the US government over the use
of dollar
loans from Chinese state-owned banks. The competition will then move
further
from one over money into the arena of geopolitics.
Apparently, the dollar is less useful when held by the
Chinese state. When money is not useful to some, it is not useful to
all. Money
must stay fully fungible to preserve its full function and value. Money not accepted from anyone to buy anything
anywhere cannot be acceptable universally. When the dollar is not
universally
accepted, it presents a greater threat to US national security than the
sale of
any one oil company.
The Answer to
Overcapacity is Consumption by the World’s
Poor
The size of the US market, large as it is, is insufficient
to absorb the continuous growth of the world’s new productive potential
unleashed by the promise of globalization. It is not possible, let
alone moral,
for 4% of the world’s population to consume the full productive
capacity of the
world. For the global economy to grow to its full potential, the whole
population of the world needs to be allowed to participate with its
fair share
of consumption. Yet economic and monetary policymakers everywhere
continue to
view full employment and rising fair wages as the direct cause of
undesirable
inflation, which is deemed a threat to sound money.
To be valuable, money is made scarce, meaning
some must have less than enough, thus making money desirable. Thus relative poverty is at the heart of
neoclassical monetary economics. Being rich requires others to be kept
in
relative poverty, meaning some must have less money. If being rich is
celebrated as a prized luxury, then the majority needs to remain
relatively
poor. Wealth is not viewed as god’s gift to all by neoclassical
economics, but
a scarce reward worth fighting over. The
competitive quest for wealth is the driving force of the market economy
and in
turn human civilization under capitalism. The fear of poverty keeps the
population working and the existence of pervasive poverty sustains the
privileges of the rich.
Yet the work ethics has been detached from wealth since the
advent of finance capitalism. The game now is to do the least amount of
work
for the richest reward. In any modern city, if those making over
$1,000,000 a
year suddenly stop work, it would take weeks before it is even noticed,
but if
all those making less than $50,000 suddenly stop working, there would
be chaos
and total collapse of urban life within days. Neoclassical economics as
practiced in a market economy is an inherently undemocratic system that
rejects
economic equality and freedom from scarcity. Thus
it is a contradiction for the US to
promote democracy and freedom
around the world through the spread of market capitalism.
Dollar Hegemony
Causes US Job Loss
The coming global trade war being launched by the rich
economies of the world is equivalent to a hunter shooting himself in
the foot
to scare away the ants attracted by the honey overflowing from his
backpack.
Economist John Kenneth Galbraith famously quipped that the trickling
theory of prosperity
means if you feed the horse enough oat, the sparrow will eventually
benefit
from the horse’s droppings. Democracy in the developed economies is
increasingly being co-opted to impose trade restraining tariffs against
the low-wage
exporting economies which have been shipping real wealth produced at
slave
wages to the US for paper dollars. With such advantageous terms of
trade, it is
nothing but foolhardy for the US to impose tariffs to curb this joy
ride made
possible by dollar hegemony. Unemployed US workers do not understand
that it is
not cheap imported goods made by low-wage labor overseas that is the
real cause
of the loss of jobs in the US. Rather,
the real cause of job loss in the US is the global monetary regime of
dollar
hegemony which makes it unnecessary for the US economy to have
production jobs
inside the US.
Under dollar hegemony, all the US needs to do is to print paper
dollars with which to exchange real goods from other countries in the
name of
global trade. But it is more convenient to blame foreign workers than
to fault
central bankers hiding behind the respectable shield of acclaimed
monetary
experts. The trouble is that the benefits of this monetary joy ride at
the
expense of low-wage workers in the developing economies are not fairly
distributed even within the rich economies, with US factory workers
bearing all
the pain while those in the finance sector keeping all the joy. Jobs
will only
return to the US if US wages become lower than those in the developing
countries. Either way, the lowering of wages or the loss of high-wage
jobs,
causes pain for US workers while producing profit for the shareholders.
In a
democracy, this mal-distribution of pain and benefits leads to
misguided
protectionism that hurts the US as a nation and threatens world
stability. The
combination of dollar hegemony and misguided protectionism in the US in
the
form of recriminatory cycles of rising tariffs among trading partners
will also
launch the world into another global trade war that will lead to
another global
great depression which in turn will leads to new shooting wars and
political
revolutions.
No single economy can profit unfairly for long at the expense of the
rest of an
interdependent world. There is an urgent need to restructure the global
finance
architecture to return to exchange rates based on purchasing-power
parity, and
to reorient the world trading system toward true comparative advantage
based on
global full employment with rising wages and living standards. The key
starting
point is to focus on dollar hegemony, not foreign low-wage workers.
World trade
needs to be financed by a multi-currency regime in which exports are
paid in the
currencies of the exporting nations, not in fiat dollars. This will
enable the
exporting nations to reap the benefits of earned external demand for
their
currencies that can be satisfied only by equivalent imports to keep
international
trade balanced.
Keeping the Poor
Poorer
Internationally, the rich nations, and domestically, the
rich within rich nations, have been gaining control over a
fast-expanding
portion of the world’s wealth and becoming increasingly ruthless in
furthering
the expansion of that control, particularly as key resources become
overstretched,
pollution mounts and the number of malnourished multiplies around the
world. Supply-side economics has been
distorted to keep supply lean in order to maximize market value of
assets. Yet
internationally, the rich countries are feeling increasingly threatened
by
rising middle-income nations, and domestically, the rich inside rich
nations
are feeling threatened by economic democracy.
A recent study by Goldman Sachs, a major global investment
bank, predicted that by 2050, four developing countries: China, India,
Brazil
and Russia, could be larger than the six biggest economies today: US,
Japan,
Germany, UK, France and Italy. Yet there is no reason for that to be
alarming
to the rich countries. The four
developing countries have a population of 2.7 billion people, more than
quadruple the population of the six biggest economies today of 681
million. It’s
a puzzle why Goldman Sachs left out Indonesia which has a population
larger
than Brazil, perhaps because Indonesia is still solidly under US
domination. And
2050 is almost half a century away, at which time the average per
capita GDP of
the four developing countries would still be less than a quarter of
that in the
six big economies. At any rate, if current terms of trade continue,
much of the
GDP in the newly-rich nations would be owned and controlled by the
currently
rich nations.
Yet there are signs that the rich economies are determined
to resist this equalizing prospect by trying to co-opt the elite in
these
developing economies as a new comprador class to help perpetuate the
historical
dominance of the rich nations. The Western financial media tirelessly
feature
sensational success stories of new internationalist entrepreneur
billionaires
in the developing economies while downplaying achievements of the
national
bourgeoisie and state-owned enterprises. Sales revenues of major
state-owned
enterprises in China reached more than 5.55 trillion yuan ($671
billion) in
2004, an increase of 25.8% year-on-year, bringing in a profit of 478.46
billion
yuan ($58 billion), a rise of 57.6% over the same period a year
earlier, with
total assets up to 9 trillion yuan ($1.1 trillion, or $4.4 trillion on
a PPP
basis). Eight Chinese state-owned enterprises were listed among the
Fortune 500
companies in 2004. The state-owned sector is growing at a faster rate
than the
economy as a whole. State-owned enterprises connote a bad image in the
mind of
neo-liberals. On the one hand, they
condemn state-owned enterprises as economically inefficient. On the
other hand,
they accuse state-owned enterprises as unfair competition for private
enterprises. And foreign state-owned
enterprises are considered national security threats by the US.
But what is a state-owned enterprise? It is one owned by the
state which is in turn is owned by all the people. It is equivalent to
a public
corporation or a public authority in a market economy. A so-called
private
corporation is owned by private shareholders, among whom sometimes are
government-owned
entities acting as private investors. And
if state-owned enterprises are inherently
inefficient, there is no
need to fear unfair competition from them. China
operates on a socialist market economy,
which means that
state-owned enterprises are a key component. US-China
trade cannot expand to its full
potential if the US considers
Chinese state-owned enterprises as unwelcome threats.
Wealth by Divine
Right
Forbes Magazine’s 100 richest people in China in 2004 have
$29.2 billion in combined assets, a growth of 42% compared with those
for the
year-earlier ranking. Worldwide, Bill
Gates alone was listed as having a net worth of $58.2 billion in 2004
while
five Walton family members had a combined asset of over $100 billion. One individual in the US is more than twice
as rich as the richest 100 in China put together. And
Forbes might have undercounted Gates’
wealth. On January 4, 2000, Microsoft (MSFT) stock price peaked at
$116.56,
putting Bill Gates’ wealth at $228 billion; or $131.6 billion by
acceptable
accounting standards after capital gain tax calculations if he were to
liquidate his shares under then governing tax laws. The number of MSFT
shares
owned by Gates, according to a 1995 Microsoft Proxy Statement was
141,159,990
shares. Adjusted for splits in December 1996, February 1998, and March
1999,
Gates was reported to own 1.95 billion shares
of MSFT, roughly 20% of the company. At
peak market price, Gates was worth $227.3 billion. Microsoft has a
total of 10.7 billion shares outstanding, worth
a total of $1.24 trillion at its peak market price,
greater than China’s GDP in
2000. If Gates had never sold any of his MSFT stock since the
company
went public, his share in the company would be worth $384.27
billion at peak price.
Gates’ assets outside of MSFT shares are not public. It is
estimated to be at least equals to holdings in MSFT as a conservative
diversification strategy. His venture
capital investments gains in new start-up are incalculable. Fortune
Magazine
estimates that Gates’ MSFT wealth alone expands at an average rate of
$50
million per day or $35,000 per minute. The gap between Mr. Rich and Mr.
and Ms.
Average is 311 times as great in the Age of Gates as it was in the Age
of
Rockefeller, and historians called that the Age of Robber Barons. We have now the Age of Wealth by Devine Right
in which one person can have his wealth increased by $50 million a day
while
almost half of the people of the world have to survive on less than $2
per day.
Obscenity is not adequate a term to describe the disparity.
Helplessness of
Small Nations
The small nations of the world, unlike Brazil, China, India
and Russia, are too weak to resist oppressive policies foisted on them
in the
name of free trade by international trade and finance organizations
controlled
by the rich nations. The World Development Movement has just produced a
report
on Senegal in West Africa, detailing a depressingly familiar tale of a
debt-stricken country forced to adopt the full range of stabilization
measures
prescribed by the IMF and the World Bank: cut public spending, tighten
monetary
and fiscal policies, focus on export-led growth, push trade and
investment
liberalization, deregulate internal prices, privatize state-owned
enterprises,
roll back the state’s role in the economy and abrogate the sovereign
right to
guide its own economic destiny.
The neo-liberal prescriptions of the Washington Consensus
are supposed to save countries like Senegal from poverty. Yet the
reality is
that the liberalization of agriculture has deprived native peasants of
their
traditional livelihoods. The percentage of malnourished in the
population rose
to 25% during the 1990s and 80% of people live on less than $2 a day. Senegal was an obvious candidate for debt
relief, but such relief is contingent on the ‘conditionalities’
attached to the
Senegalese poverty reduction strategy, by selling off the country’s
public
assets and natural resources to multinational corporations from the
industrialized world.
In Malawi, agents of the Washington Consensus demanded that
the government should reduce subsidies for small farmers, remove price
controls
and regulations and privatize the state-run body that ensured food was
available across the country and let the market work its wonders. The
result
was that prices rose 400%, with widespread hoarding in the market while
famine
spread. In Zambia, agricultural tariffs were removed, subsidized farm
credit
halted, food import quotas lifted, and the currency devalued to aim for
unrealistic export-led growth. The result was that exports as a
percentage of a
shrinking GDP fell from 36% in 1991 to 27% in 2001.
US Paranoia toward
China Alienating Allies
Predictably, China again emerges as the main target of blame
and fear. Talks of pre-emptive strikes and militant alliances against a
rising
China are again rampant in US political/military circles. The
Australian
Broadcasting Corporation reported that in June 2003, the Bush
administration
decided China’s expanding role on the world stage required an annual
forum among
US allies to discuss issues surrounding China, and invited the UK,
Canada, New
Zealand, Japan and Australia to participate. The meetings were kept
ultra-secret, in order to create an atmosphere open to frank discussion
that
would not be restrained by possible adverse reaction in world opinion. At the first meeting, those attending decided
to call themselves the Halibut Group. The name grew out of an in joke -
none of
the China experts present could work out how to say "halibut" in
Mandarin. When the Halibut Group started, the Deputy Secretary of State
at the
time, Richard Armitage, telephoned the Australian Ambassador in
Washington,
Michael Thawley, to invite Australia to participate. But there were
conflicting
opinion in Canberra about whether to get involved. Some saw it as a
good chance
to present to US policymakers Australia’s view on China; but the
prevailing
view was that Australia would gain more through bilateral contacts with
the US,
and at the same time, avoid any offence to Beijing. So Australia told
its best
friend and ally it preferred to not participate, to the disappointment
of the
US. Most nations, including long-time US
allies, will not support any revival of US policies of containing China.
The Textile Quota
Issue
The US in May 2005 re-imposed quotas on seven kinds of
Chinese textiles and clothing products in response to a 54% import rise
above
2004 level. The dispute over textile quotas is merely a transitional
issue over
the phasing in of WTO rules on the expiration of quotas. Textile, like
agriculture, has been one of the most contentious issues in the WTO, as
it was
in the former GATT system. It has gone through fundamental changes
under a
10-year schedule agreed to in the Uruguay Round multilateral trade
negotiations
launched at Punta del Este, Uruguay in September 1986 and concluded in
Geneva
in December 1993, signed by Ministers in Marrakesh, Morocco in April
1994.
The system of import quotas that had dominated textile trade
since the early 1960s was to be phased out in April 2004. By January 1,
2005,
the sector became fully integrated into normal GATT rules. In
particular,
textile quotas came to an end, and importing countries will no longer
be able
to discriminate between exporters. The Agreement on Textiles and
Clothing will
itself no longer exist: it was the only WTO agreement that had
self-destruction
built in. The export growth of Chinese textiles is a normal temporary
phenomenon in a process of returning to free trade. The unreasonable
arrangement and over-protection made by the US and the EU in the
process of
integration of textiles are the main causes of the problem.
The original quota system distorted severely the textile
trade of the world and restricted the exports of Chinese textiles by
assigning
a quota for China far short of its capacity. Textile integration
eliminates
this trade distortion. It is normal that rapid increase of Chinese
textile
exports will happen for temporarily before normalizing. The latest
textile
research report by WTO shows that increase of textile export from China
will be
lower than expected after textile integration takes full effect due to
factors
involving tariff limitation and the labor cost advantage in other
developing
countries. Textile integration not only brings development opportunity
to
China, but also to the whole world. China is a production power in
textiles and
also a big textile consuming country. Eighty per cent of the textiles
produced
in China are sold domestically because textile is the first consumer
goods a
poor population can afford to buy. The China’s market with a population
of 1.3
billion will offer immense opportunities global exports of garments,
textiles
for home and industrial purposes, textile raw materials such as cotton
and
wool, synthetic fibers, in addition to design services and
manufacturing
machineries that are made mostly in advanced economies. After entry
into WTO on
December 11, 2001, China fulfilled its promise ahead of schedule with
the
general tariff level reduced to 10.4%. With the exception of quotas on
the
import of cotton and wool there are no restrictive measures in the
import of
textiles.
China took decisive action in April to ease rising concern
in trading partners by hiking textile tariffs on more than 70 products
by 400%
effective June 1. The announced rise sent panic through the country’s
textile
and garment industry. Some have predicted factory closures and job
losses. The
Ministry of Finance said in a statement tariffs would rise from 0.2
yuan (2.4
US cents) to 1 yuan (12 US cents) per unit. The largest tariff increase
would
be from 0.3 yuan (3.6 US cents) to 4 yuan (48 US cents) per unit. And a
new
tariff of 3 yuan (36 US cents) per kilogram will be imposed on exports
of flax
yarn. Chinese textile manufacturers said their profit will be squeezed
as they
currently earn only 1 yuan (12 US cents) to 2 yuan (24 US cents) from
each
shirt. Earlier protective measures initiated by the US had practically
shut
Chinese companies producing cotton shirts out of the US market. Some
entrepreneurs predicted that a large number of textile manufactures
would go
bankrupt by August or September.
"We are encouraged by this move that the United States
and China may be able to resolve other trade differences with a similar
sense
of fairness and moderation," said Charlie Martin, president of the
American Chamber of Commerce in China. He said this voluntary step by
Beijing
demonstrated China was adopting a constructive approach and was
sensitive to
the hardships which the removal of quotas has brought for some American
workers. Unfortunately, the US initiated
safeguard
measures against three categories of Chinese textile products earlier
in May;
similar measures were imposed on another four categories before the end
of May.
The textile industry in China employs 19 million people,
about the size of the population of Australia, and jobs will be lost
because of
the restrictions. As a result, analysts predicted, about 100,000
Chinese
workers in this sector might lose their jobs. Youngor Group Companies,
China's
biggest maker of men's suits and shirts and a supplier to Marks &
Spencer
Group Plc of Britain and Polo Ralph Lauren Corporation of the US, said
on June
9 it is losing orders to rivals in India. Hong Kong-based Zhongxing
Cotton Ltd
sells about 200,000 metric tons of cotton to Chinese manufacturers a
year,
sourcing from the United States, West Africa and Uzbekistan. Zhongxing
also
represents Cargill Cotton of the US. Consumption
of cotton “will be moderated,”
Jeff Coey, director of China
and Southeast Asia at Cotton Council International, said in an
interview on May
31. Cotton Council is the international division of the Memphis-based
National
Cotton Council of America. Cotton prices on the New York Board of Trade
dropped
5.3% in the past 12 months, according to Bloomberg data.
China’s cotton imports were down 56%, in the
first four months of 2005, compared with the year-earlier period,
according to
customs data. An April 26 report by the
US Foreign Agricultural Service said US cotton production this year is
forecast
at 5.5 million tons, 13 per cent less than last year.
China announced days after the European Union sought formal
talks with Beijing over two types of textile imports - flax yarn and
t-shirts -
that it will abolish export tariffs on 81 categories of textile
products and
scrap scheduled tariff increases on 74 types of textiles as trade
tensions with
the European Union and US escalated, bringing the EU a step closer to
imposing
limits. The announcement came ahead of a visit to Beijing of US
Commerce Secretary
Carlos Gutierrez.
China’s cost advantages are limited to lower labor cost.
There are big gaps in capital, design and development, brand name
building and
marking between China and the other advanced countries in the world
market.
Much opportunity awaits exploration in exchange and cooperation in
textile
areas between China and other countries. Quantitative
growth is not an objective China
is pursuing in textiles
export. The orientation going forward includes improvement of
industrial
structure, raising added value, promotion of brand names and improving
on
design and marketing. Chinese textiles export to the US in 2004 was
valued at
$9.06 billion, accounting for only 5% of the total trade volume between
the two
countries. The current dispute over
textile is a political friction unilaterally created by the US, along
with
currency valuation and restriction on Chinese direct investment in the
US.
The World Bank’s
spokesman on Asia, Peter Stevens, said in a June 29 speech that
proposals
by US and European lawmakers to impose restrictions on low-price
Chinese
imports were unfair and hypocritical. In a compromise worked out with
the EU in
early June, China agreed to limit the growth of exports in 10
categories of
textiles to Europe to between 8% and 12.5% a year through 2007. “Trying
to deal
with the emergence of China and the rise of India through antiquated
measures
like tariff protection is like trying to hold back the tide with a
little wall
of sand,” Steven said, adding that the US and EU should engage in more
dialogue
with Asia. “The notion that somehow by increasing tariffs on
Chinese
textiles, jobs in textiles are going to return magically to the US is
incredible,” Stephens said at a luncheon of the Singaporean-German
Chamber of
Commerce.
China Also Suffers
from Job Loss
There is a general misconception that job losses in the US
are caused by the growth in Chinese manufacturing.
Studies have shown that much of the job loss
in the US has been caused by structural shifts in the US economy. There is evidence that such job loss is a
design by US policy. Federal Reserve
Chairman Alan Greenspan told Congress in public testimony that thinking
jobs
are better than doing jobs. The
US will keep higher-paying jobs in financial
services, management, design, development, sales and distribution and
let the
emerging economies have the low-paying assembly line jobs in factories
owned by
US companies. Even small business, a key component in job creation, is
increasingly taking advantage of low-cost telecommunication and
transportation
to play the wage arbitrage game through cross-border out-sourcing. When
US job
growth slows, the US stock market, which measures the global
performance of listed
companies, rises. US labor unions have watched helplessly drastic drops
in
membership that translate into loss of political leverage in shaping US
economic policy. Now that effects of cross-border wage arbitrage are
hitting
the high-tech sector, laying off highly-paid US high-tech workers and
giving
their jobs to cheaper workers overseas, the political reverberation are
louder.
In this jobless recovery, these better-educated workers have the
political
clout to turn US policy towards protectionism.
Such structural shifts are also occurring in
the Chinese economy. A 2004
study by the US Conference Board found that China has been losing more
manufacturing jobs than the US as productivity surges in the world’s
most
populous nation. China lost 15 million manufacturing jobs between 1995
and
2002, compared with 2 million shed in the US. This is not surprising,
since
industrialization has been occurring at a faster pace and from a lower
base in
underdeveloped China than in already developed US. Yet US job losses
have led some
US politicians and business leaders to complain that jobs have been
outsourced
to countries such as China where pay is lower. But few economists have
proposed
ways to make trade lift Chinese wages. Rising
productivity is behind the loss of
factory jobs everywhere in the
world, even in China. The US economy is the only one in the world that
enjoys
productivity gains without actually producing more real goods. But
worse than
in the US, rising productivity has translated even less into higher
wages in
China. This is because 60% of the Chinese export sector is financed by
foreign
direct investment which has no incentive to raise local wages, since
demand for
their export products is independent of local purchasing power.
Chinese labor productivity grew at an annual rate of 17%
between 1995 and 2002, meaning factories in the country were producing
more
with less labor. But wage rise has been averaging below 10% annually
from an
already excessively low base, discounted by an average annual inflation
rate of
over 5%. The year 2001 saw a per-capita annual wage rise by 14.6%, the
number
of employed workers decreased to 54.41 million and the wage sum totaled
572.18
billion yuan, a growth of 12.2%. Average
total income per worker, including wages and welfare funds, amounted to
11,881 yuan
in 2001, a 14.1% rise over 2000, with an 18% gap from productivity
growth rate.
This means Chinese wages measured by productivity were actually
falling. Due to
widening wage disparity, both average and median income rose at a
slower rate
than GDP. Twenty-six of China’s 38 major
industries registered job losses over the period surveyed, according to
data
from 51,000 companies. At the same time, jobs in China’s service sector
were
increasing, consistent with economic development. This
disconnection between productivity and
wages also occurred in the US. Between 2000 and 2004, US productivity
rose 3.8%
annually on average while the median family income fell by 0.9%. During the three decades between 1975 and
2004, US productivity growth consistently outpaced family income
growth, with
productivity doubling while median family income rose only about 12%,
according
to findings from the Economic Policy Institute. In
both countries, workers have not been
getting their fair share of
economic growth.
Growth and Job Loss
This significant empirical data
validate what has been
suspected for sometime in theory. The
implications are mind-boggling. If notwithstanding all the outsourcing
from the
US as a result of cross-border wage arbitrage, the world’s fastest
growing
economy is also losing manufacturing jobs due to a faster rise in
productivity
(17%) than GDP growth rate (9%), then the world’s industrial economy is
going
through what its agricultural economy went through a century ago. Overcapacity is the plague of the modern
industrial
economy, as agricultural overproduction was the plague of the
agricultural
economy of an earlier age. The farm
workers went to the cities and into factories, and not a few went to
die in high-casualty
wars in the 19th and 20th Some
have gone into the service sectors
where, except in financial services, wages are generally lower than in
factories. centuries. Where will the
factory workers of the world go in a market economy of finance
capitalism? Even
war deaths have been greatly reduced in number through new war
technology.
Are Jobs Necessary For Prosperity?
Perhaps the idea of a job as a mean of generating income
needs to be re-examined in the post-industrial society.
The job is the creation of the industrial
revolution. Prior to that, under agricultural feudalism, people had
livelihoods, doing what they excelled and enjoyed.
The job was a venue through which impersonal
labor and time are sold for money at a rate that prevents the worker to
buy and
consume all of what he/she produces so that the excessive production
can be turned
into profit, what Marx called surplus value. When the domestic market
stagnated
from this structural imbalance of demand and supply, goods were sold
overseas
to earn the profit needed to pay for the capital goods that increased
productivity
and to provide returns on capital required to finance the capital
goods. This
was the impetus behind mercantilism which as Hobson and Lenin observed
as
leading to imperialism.
The victim economies of imperialism were misled by
neo-liberals that foreign trade was the way to reverse the flow of
economic
benefits by exporting to the imperialist economies. What policymakers
in
developing economies failed to realized was that the imperialist
economies have
evolved into finance capitalism in which they no longer need to export
goods to
accumulate wealth. Because the developing economies needed foreign
direct
investment to finance their export sector, they did not receive any of
the
financial benefits from historical mercantilism as the imperialist
economies
once did by robbing the wealth of their colonies by selling them
high-price
manufactured goods in exchange for cheap raw material.
Each New Millionaire requires 100,000 Job Losses to Create
Nowadays, the export of both manufactured products and
profits from the exporting economies is the neo-imperialism that the
developing
economies did not recognize until they were solidly hooked by dollar
hegemony
under which the trade surplus they earned cannot be invested or spent
in their
own local economies. The problem is
exacerbated
when, in the developing economies, capital goods and raw material are
imported,
draining money away from domestic recycling. But
even if capital goods are locally
produced, their production does
not require enough labor to re-circulate enough money to support mass
consumption. One way to look at the
unemployment
statistics is that in China, where some 15,000 new millionaires have
been
created in recent decades, with urban unemployment at 15 million, each
millionaire requires 100,000 job losses to create. The wealth of the
new
millionaires came from the low wages of workers as well as the unpaid
wages of
the unemployed.
Treating Unemployment as Paying Jobs
Raising wages are scant compensation if unemployment in the
economy keeps increasing from structural job losses.
Job creation then becomes a priority and a
policy prerequisite in a modern economy. Government
must adopt policies to create new
jobs to achieve full
employment at high and rising wages to absorb the loss of jobs from
rising productivity
and use sovereign credit to sustain consumption to obliterate
overcapacity that
weakens economic growth. Charlie Chaplin’s
Modern Times has finally arrived in the modern post-industrial economy. Perhaps the economic definition of a job
needs to be reconsidered. What about treating involuntary unemployment
as
paying jobs? The logic is
immaculate. If structural unemployment
is necessary to keep money sound and valuable, it can be argued that a
“natural
rate” of unemployment to prevent inflation is a profitable arrangement
to the
economy and the unemployed should be paid for their selfless service to
society.
In television programming, there is a contractual concept
known as “play or pay,” meaning the network will play the program and
pay the producer
for it, or it can refuse to run the program but still has to pay the
producer
for it. For labor contract, there should
also be “work or pay.” The economy
should either provide a job for everyone looking for work and pay
him/her
wages, or keep him/her unemployed to fight inflation but still pay
him/her
wages. If farmers are paid to reduce production, why shouldn’t factory
workers
be paid for being involuntarily unemployed? The
reason is that farmers historically have
more voting power than
factory workers in the US political system which has evolved from an
agricultural economy.
Individual Sovereign Credit Entitlement
Or perhaps every citizen should be born with his/her
quotient of sovereign credit as a civil right entitlement with which to
keep
the economy humming. Why should the
heirs of the privately rich be the only ones enjoying the legacy of a
rich
pedigree? Citizens of rich nations can
also be born with inheritance from a society of abundant national
wealth. What
kind of democracy is it if the national wealth is not the property of
the
people? Instead of running the economy on consumer debt, as the US
economy
under Fed Chairman Greenspan has been doing, why not run it with
sovereign
credit channeled through consumers that eventually returns to
government as
taxes? Marx appeared to have been
outdated in his urging that workers of the world should unite, for they
have
nothing to lose but their chains. The fact is that in the new economy
of
finance capitalism, workers have to lose their jobs to keep the world
economy
working. If the numbers of workers are
shrinking as the economy expands, workers can become an endangered
species and
the dictatorship of the proletariat can be a meaningless fantasy. In a
market
economy, if income is dependant on work, and if work is shrinking as
the
economy expands from rising productivity, then income cannot possibly
increase
fast enough to support the consumption needed to eliminate
overcapacity. To
avoid the market economy collapsing, ways needs to be found to deliver
basic income
to the consumer independent of employment beyond undignified welfare
payments.
Next: Trade Related Aspects of
Intellectual Property Rights
(TRIPS)
|