Super
Capitalism, Super Imperialism and Monetary Imperialism
By
Henry C.K. Liu
Part I: A Structural Link
Part II: Deregulation:
Global War on Labor
This article appeared in AToL
on October 13, 2007
The long-range consequence
of the
Carter deregulation policies
and practices that had begun during 1977-1981 was magnified during the
Reagan
period of 1981-89, with greater emphasis on changing the tax regime to
favor
the rich, industry deregulation to lower prices by lowering quality,
and a shift
of power from unions to management. Carter took the first steps towards
dismantling the post-World War II social safety net and
retirement/pension
system, and encouraging job market restructuring in the name of freedom
and
efficiency. Reagan’s conservatism was merely skin-deep and rhetorical,
being
the president with the largest federal deficit in history, whose
policies were
outright antagonistic towards the interests of the poor whose rank was
constantly enlarged by the steady decline of the middle class. Reagan’s
rhetoric labeled government as the enemy, not the protector of the
people.
Ironically, his policies made his rhetoric ring true.
The Reagan government had been the ruthless
enemy
of the US
middle class.
Bush Sr. Lost
to
Clinton: It’s the Economy, Stupid!
During the presidency of George Bush senior,
1988-1992, the
emphasis shifted to policies promoting US
corporate
investment overseas, trade, and on
implementing neo-liberal policies in emerging offshore economies and
markets. The Bush policies produced a prosperous corporate state
while the
nation fell into a domestic recession to which Bush was personally
oblivious
and which caused him to lose the White House to an unknown challenger
from a
minor Southern state, despite victory at war in Iraq.
The
slogan: “It’s the economy. Stupid!” entered US
political nomenclature and dominated the entire Clinton
presidency.
Under Clinton, 1992-2000,
the policy
focus centered largely
on promoting and expanding neo-liberal “free trade” under dollar
hegemony.
Additionally, the Clinton period was characterized by the introduction
of new
formulas for enabling health care cost shifting from corporations to
workers,
by accelerating the diversion of social security payroll taxes to the
US
general budget to create the false appearance of declining federal
budget
deficits and by passing government rules encouraging the further
decline of the
traditional private pension system. The Clinton
fiscal surplus was largely
funded from the pockets of US workers. Clinton
deregulated world trade and introduced dollar hegemony to put the US
middle class in debt in order to feed corporate global profit. The Clinton
prosperity was built on debt addiction, otherwise known as “Rubinnomics”,
after Clinton Treasury
Secretary Robert Rubin.
The
Bush Tax
Cut
for the Rich
Under George W. Bush, once again tax cuts for
corporations
and the wealthy became the pre-eminent policy focus and hailed as the
indispensable dynamo of prosperity while further expanding “free trade”
to
advance democracy. Bush tax and trade policies contributed to a new
wave
of income
shift toward income disparity, combining the worst aspects of both the
Reagan
and Clinton eras, the former being an inequitable tax policy and the
latter
being an anti-labor trade policy. Not surprisingly, the income
inequality gap
accelerated at the fastest rate during the Bush period of 2000-2006,
but the
stage had been set by Carter, Regan, Bush and Clinton. In addition to
tax and
trade-driven income inequality, under George W. Bush other new
income-shifting
policy initiatives were launched as well in health care cost shifting,
retirement system restructuring, and legislated wage compression by
government
edict, targeting overtime pay for millions of hourly paid workers.
US Workers Squeezed by Government and
Employers
While the tax, trade, wage and benefits policies
were being
implemented top down during the two decades between 1980-2006 under
four
presidents from both parties, deregulated corporate policies and
practices that
further contributing to the growing income inequality gap were being
simultaneously
overhauled from the bottom-up, shifting from full-time, permanent jobs
to
part-time, temporary, and independent contract work. Growing
consistently since
the 1980s, more than 44 million of the 137 million employed workforce
in the US,
close to one third, are now part-time, temporary, and contract workers
earning
60-70% of the pay of full-time workers and typically receiving only 20%
of the
benefits.
Management promoted de-unionization policies
launched in the
1980s resulted in the decline of union membership from 22% of the
workforce in
1980 to barely 7% in the private sector in 2006. Two decades of
corporate job
outsourcing policies sent millions of high-paying, liberal benefit jobs
in
manufacturing, technology, and business professional services overseas,
a loss
filled with lower paying domestic service jobs—frequently part-time,
temp, and
contract jobs. Corporate fringe benefits policies shifted fundamentally
during
the same period, resulting in the dismantling of more than 100,000
traditional
pension plans and their replacement with cheaper cost 401-K plans; the
discontinuance and/or shifting of costs of health insurance plan
coverage;
widespread unilateral corporate elimination of retiree health benefits;
reduction of paid vacation and other paid time-offs; and other similar
company-driven cost reduction measures.
The two approaches - corporate policy changes at
the
company-industry level and government policy changes - worked in close
concert
with each other. Government tax, depreciation, and free trade policies
provided
significant financial incentives to corporations for expanding
off-shoring jobs
and consequently dismantling and transferring abroad much of the
manufacturing
sector in the US.
For the first time in US economic history, large sacle layoffs became
an easy corproate profit option. Shares in pulbicly listed companies
rose in value whenever large cost cutting job reduction was announced.
Corporate bankruptcy became a legal escape from costly labor contracts.
Health Care and
Pension
Government agency rule changes allowed
corporations
to
extract for general business use, pension fund surpluses resulting from
an anti-labor business culture, and/or to delay
properly funding of pension plans. Government bodies such as the
National
Labor
Relations Board directly aided corporate efforts to de-unionize while
government
de-regulation and privatization of entire industries further decimated
union
membership ranks and undermined union market power and bargaining
effectiveness.
On the health front, government policy in the
form
of
managed health care under Clinton and consumer-driven health care and
health
savings accounts under George W. Bush, encouraged corporations to more
rapidly
shift health care costs to workers.
The recent settlement of the 3-day old General
Motor
strike involving
74,000 workers (having shrunk from 125,000 in four years) was a staged
farce to
mask a submissive union as a defiant fighter for worker benefits and
job
security. The new contract freezes worker base pay for four years. It allowed GM to shift to a new independent
trust called Voluntary Employees Beneficiary Association (VEBA) $51
billion in
liabilities for union retiree health care by contributing to it only
$35
billion of tax deductible income. The new contract will pay new UAW
workers
lower wages for the same work the GM pays current workers. The two-tier
wage
regime has been credited as a key factor in strong corporate profits.
After a
bitter battle with the union during the 1990s and several bitter
strikes, one
of which
lasted 17 months, Caterpillar emerged victorious with a two-tier wage
system
that has allowed it to grow and prosper. The agreement pays new
employees far
less: about $22 an hour, as opposed to the $40 an hour plus benefits
that
starting workers used to make.
The push by GM to unload its “legacy
cost” is aimed at
matching lower Japanese worker benefits. Both GM and Japanese wage are
now around
$25 per hour. The gap in total labor cost between Detroit
and Japan
is in
benefits, with $75 an hour for GM as compared to Japanese producers of
$55. A pro-labor solution would be to
force the
Japanese car makers to raise its benefit cost to $75 an hour rather
than to
lower GM worker benefit to $55. A pro-labor trade policy would impose
countervailing tariff to offset the difference to level the playing
field
between GM workers and Japanese car maker workers. But
neo-liberal free trade is designed to push
global wages down, not up.
Income Shift
from
Workers to Corporate Profit
Given the magnitudes of these income shifts from
workers, it
is not surprising that corporate profits have increased at double digit
rates
every quarter for the last three and a half years to more than $1.4
trillion;
or that CEOs and the top 5 managers of US corporations have increased
their
total share of national income from around $50 billion a year in 2001
to more
than $140 billion a year in just five years; or that the wealthiest 1%
(1.1
million) households have seen their share of total national income
reported grow
to levels of 20-22% of total national income, levels not seen since the
gilded
age of the 1920s.
National income that passes through the conduit
of
the
corporation is disbursed to shareholders, senior managers, and CEOs in
the form
of dividends, interest payment, capital gains, and various forms of
deferred
and total compensation. What is not disbursed may be accumulated and
expended
on corporate expansion (i.e., invested) or held by the corporation as
retained
profits or used for share buy-backs to lift share prices. Official
figures for
retained profits by US corporations are now at the level of more than
$500
billion a year, about $200 billion a year higher than long term
historical
averages.
And those figures only represent retained
profits
that are
reported. Largely unreported are additional profits by
multinational
corporations that get transferred by various accounting means to their
offshore
subsidiaries and affiliates and then held there as un-repatriated
profits for
years to avoid US taxes. The precise totals for such un-repatriated
profits are
not known, either by the IRS or the US government. Morgan Stanley in
2005 reported that the total in offshore un-repatriated
profits held by US corporations amounted to about $700 billion.
A third and even more opaque category of profits
consists
essentially of unknown profits from domestic US or foreign operations
that are
diverted to offshore tax shelters and never reported to the IRS. The
latest
unofficial indication of the level of income held today in offshore tax
shelters is about $7 trillion, up from $250 billion in the mid-1980s.
At least
$4 trillion of that $7 trillion is held by US corporations and wealthy
households, the mix between corporate and individuals remaining
unknown. An
annual additional net flow of income from the US
into such shelters is easily around $200 billion a year, not counting
interest
earned annually on the $4 trillion already there.
This income shift to the wealthy has been a
result
of
government policies providing record tax cuts on capital (dividends,
interest,
capital gains, estate, gift tax, etc), extending from Reagan’s then
record $752
billion tax cut in the early 1980s which launched the nation towards
the
largest peacetime deficit up to that time, to George W. Bush’s sequence
of
annual tax cuts from 2001 to 2006. During George W. Bush’s first
term
alone, more than $4 trillion in tax cuts were passed. Approximately 80%
of
these cuts are accruing to the wealthiest 20% households and largely in
turn to
the highest income groups within that 20%. Should the Bush tax cuts be
made
permanent, the amount will grow to $11 trillion, again with the highest
income
groups receiving the lion’s share of the cuts and income. Additional
corporate
tax cuts amounting to more than $1 trillion were also passed under Bush
and
have contributed significantly to the bulge in corporate retained
profits.
Who Widened
Inequality?
Reich continues in his WSJ Opinion piece: “Yet
the
philosophical debate [on inequality] is coming up all the time these
days, and
it helps explain the new economic populism. Consider, for example, the
Bush
cuts. They’ve mainly benefited the top fifth of taxpayers.
Supply-siders argue
the cuts have generated enough extra revenues to pay for themselves so
they
haven’t enlarged the budget deficit. That’s debatable but let’s make
the heroic
assumption the supply-siders are correct and no one has been made worse
off.
Yet even so, most Americans have not benefited – nothing has trickled
down.
Real median wages have barely budged since they were enacted. So the
underlying
question is whether they’re justified by the fact that rich Americans
have
gained from them while no one has lost ground. The answer is no.
They’ve
widened inequality.”
Reich reminds one of the famous fable by Mencius
(372-289
BC) in which those who retreated 50 paces from the battle line turning
around
and laughing at those who retreated 100 paces for being cowards. The
Bush
administration has not been the only one adding inequality to the US
economy. The philosophical issue of inequality has only come up “these
days”
because neo-liberals thought it was not a worthwhile issue as long as
all
income is rising even though some may rise much faster than others.
Moyers the True
Liberal
Bill Moyers, key participant in President
Johnson’s
Great
Society that was tragically aborted by the Vietnam War, in a June 3,
2004 speech: The Fight of Our Lives,
given at the
Inequality Matters Forum at New York University, said: “Astonishing as
it
seems, no one in official Washington seems embarrassed by the fact that
the gap
between rich and poor is greater than it’s been in 50 years – the worst
inequality among all western nations. Or that we are experiencing a
shift in
poverty. For years it was said those people down there at the bottom
were
single, jobless mothers. For years they were told work, education, and
marriage
is how they move up the economic ladder. But poverty is showing up
where we
didn’t expect it – among families that include two parents, a worker,
and a
head of the household with more than a high school education. These are
the
newly poor. Our political, financial and business class expects them to
climb
out of poverty on an escalator moving downward.”
The inequality that Moyers rightly protests
about
did not
start with the second Bush administration. It started with the Carter
deregulation policies and the neo-liberal trade policies of the
two-term Clinton
administration and Clinton’s
adoption of the “Third Way”
radical centralism approach promoted by British sociologist Anthony
Giddens.
Rubinomics
One month before the Reich article in The
American
Prospect,
I wrote in my article: Paulson,
China
and the turmoil beneath that appeared in AToL
on December
14, 2006,
the following about the anti-labor and anti-equality approach of “Rubinomics”:
The
widening gap
between the richest and poorest US
residents has not been the focus of attention by anyone in the Bush
administration until Henry Paulson, the new Treasury Secretary who sees
it as a
long-term economic policy challenge. Paulson appears to attempt to
reframe the
policy debate on this fundamental issue as a solution to the trade
problem.
The trade problem is rooted in global income inequality which is a
problem that
the US
cannot
solve without first addressing its domestic income inequality.
The wealth gap is a fixture of
the industrialization phase of US
economic history but relative income equality has been the dynamo of
the US
consumer economy. Fordism put the US on the
road to rising industrial wages to create the US middle
class out of factory workers and allowed the US
economy to overtake its older European competitors. The two world wars
gave US
workers income growth that consistently outstripped inflation and
allowed
productivity growth to sustain spectacular growth of consumer demand, a
key
component in the success of the US
economy.
Market
capitalism naturally
produces income disparity and
polarization that lead to recurrent economic crises. To correct this
structural
flaw, the nation adopted an income policy. Income redistribution has
been the
tradition of the US tax regime since the New Deal. With the onset of 8 years
of
supply-side “Reaganomics”, followed
by another 8 years of neo-liberal “Rubinomics”
under Clinton, whom orthodox liberals Democrats accuse as the best
Republican
president in history, inequality has been growing in US society to fuel
a
vibrant economy. While the Republicans adopted a new income policy to
redistribute income upward with the watering down of the progressive
income
tax, the neo-liberal Clinton Democrats used outsourcing in a globalized
market
economy to keep US wages from rising, and built a fiscal surplus by
starving
social spending. The net result is to expand the globalized economy at
the
expense of the US domestic economy.
For
the past two decades,
two-party democracy has failed to
provide alternative choices in economic policy for the US
electorate. And outsourcing is not the only factor driving US wages
down, even
as average worker productivity within the US has surged, average hourly
earnings have stagnated, while the nation’s economic elites have
prospered with
astronomical levels of incomes. New sectors such as the high-tech,
information
technology and financial services operate on the model of low salaries
and high
stock options. Even for investors, the trend has been to favor equity
appreciation over dividend income. Neo-liberal economists seemed to
have
forgotten the basic rule in finance: Income is all. Economic growth
without
income is a fantasy.
Income disparity has now reached obscene levels.
Capital One Financial CEO
Richard Fairbank exercised 3.6 million options for gains of nearly $250
million, on which he pay tax on the lower capital gain rate rather the
income
tax rate. His personal take exceeded the annual corporate profits of
more than
half of the Fortune 1000 companies, including Goodyear Tire
&
Rubber, Reebok and Pier One. Median pay among chief executives running
most of
the nation's 100 largest companies soared 25% to $17.9 million in 2005,
dwarfing the 3.1% average gain by typical US
workers. And Congress is in the midst of a passionate debate over
raising the
minimum wage from the current $5.15 an hour to $7.25 an hour in 2009 in
three
steps, with opponents to the proposed bill claiming that such a raise
would
destroy the US
economy. The
idea of indexing the minimum wage
to inflation is considered a legislative non-starter.
US corporate earnings are at an all-time high
because wages have been stagnant.
Corporations are overflowing with cash but they refuse to pass it on to
their
workers. Instead, corporations adopt share buybacks scheme with the
surplus
cash to raise the market value of the stocks.
To his credit,
Paulson is the first Treasury
Secretary in recent history to focus
on the inequality problem. In his first major speech as Treasury
secretary,
Paulson said: “Amid this country's strong economic expansion, many
Americans
simply aren't feeling the benefits. Their increases in wages are being
eaten up
by high energy prices and rising healthcare costs, among others.”
Paulson gave
notice that this issue will be a priority in his agenda to restructure
the US
economy.
A Federal
Reserve
survey shows that between 2001 and
2004, the median income of
US workers with college degrees barely budged, rising from $72,300 to
$73,000,
after adjusting for inflation. Clinton Administration did almost
nothing to
advance the interests of organized labor or working people more
generally.
Union membership continued its long decline during the Clinton
presidency, standing at 13.5 percent of the total workforce when he
left
office. A paper co-authored by Rubin observed: “Prosperity has
neither
trickled down nor rippled outward. Between 1973 and 2003, real GDP per
capita
in the United States
increased 73 percent, while real median hourly compensation rose only
13
percent.”
New Populism
Against Rubinomics
A new wave of
economic populism is surging along
with Democratic victory at the
[2006 mid-term] polls. Yet these new populists seem to exclusively
target
foreign trade, not realizing that the imbalanced trade is the result
rather
than the cause of the new age of economic inequality, the fountainhead
of which
originated in US domestic policy. If Paulson really wants to deal with
the
problem of persistent US trade deficits, the solution lies not in
Beijing, but
at home in the US.
The new populists argue that the trade agreements
beginning with NAFTA and
continuing through the various World Trade Organization negotiations
have
failed to protect workers’ rights to organize unions and thus raise
wages in
the low-wage countries. Instead, wages in high wage countries have
continued to
stagnate or drift downwards in real purchasing power. They also insist
not only
on an increase in the minimum wage but on tying it to the cost of
living so
that future inflation will not erode its real value, as it has in the
past.
Just as the neo-conservatives have hijacked foreign
policy in the Bush
Administration, the neo-liberal Clinton
wing of the Democratic Party hijacked the party’s economic policies.
The Clinton
neo-liberals imported the Republican ideology that the economy could
achieve
sustained growth only if markets were allowed to operate unregulated
globally.
Treating labor as a captured constituency, the Clinton
administration vigorously supported free trade agreements like Nafta
and agreed
to China’s
admission into the World Trade Organization (WTO) to expand the global
economy
at the expanse of the US
domestic economy, with half-hearted promises of worker retraining and
other
safety-net measures that Clinton’s
balanced budget could not fund. The adverse effects of Reubinomics were
masked
by a temporary burst of unsustainable economic prosperity caused by
corporate
and consumer debt.
The new
populists
want an alternative to Rubinomics,
one that register growths by the income received by the middle class.
They
argue that the national income has increasingly flowed
disproportionately into
corporate profit and the rich. They call for a review of US-led
globalization
and for new terms of trade that do not put the cost of economic
expansion
entirely on the chronic poor, the newly poor and the powerless both
domestically and globally. They call for government regulation in the
terms of
trade to distribute the benefits more equitably.
The free traders
accused the new populists of being
protectionists. Rubin
admits that globalization has not brought job security or rising
incomes to US
workers and that as the global economy expands to benefit the US
in general, it does so at the expense of shrinking the middle class’
share of the economic pie. Yet US Rubinomists stick to the worn-out Maragret
Thatcher claim
of TINA
(There is no alternative), arguing that regulating trade and imposing
market
restrictions would be self-defeating. There is now enough historical
data to
question the false claim of benefits of financial globalization which
has
brought about monetary and financial crises around the world every few
years.
The emergence of unregulated capital, debt and currency markets has
prevented
government around the world from effectively use sovereign credit to
finance
domestic development and force all nations to distorting their
economies toward
over-reliance on exports for fiat dollars that cannot be used in their
home economy and to compete by joining the race
to the
bottom on wages and environmental abuse.
And it is not even clear that Rubinomics
was really responsible for economic growth of the 1990s. Historical
data
suggest that the information revolution greatly improved productivity
even in
economies insulated from Rubinomics,
such as China
and India.
economy. The idea of indexing the minimum
wage to inflation is considered a
legislative non-starter.
The free market does not know best.
Left undirected, a free market will race ahead at unsafe speed towards
accidents waiting to happen. A more balanced US
economic policy away from maximization of profits might have let that
productivity burst lift the global economy into a higher plane without
distortions that are haunting it now.
In his 2003 book, In an Uncertain
World, Rubin
admits: “In retrospect,
the effect of the Clinton economic
plan on business and consumer confidence may have been even more
important than
the effect on interest rates.” Business investment during the Clinton
boom years was not exceptional vigorous. It was the brain-power
intensive
information revolution that helped trigger big gains in productivity
and growth
despite a comparative low capital input compared to earlier
capital-intensive
cycles, such as the railroad age.
The 1997 Economic Report of the President
[Clinton] released in
February, five months before the 1997 Asian financial crisis, predicted
that
growth would average a meager 2.2% over the next four years. The actual
growth
rate turned out to be 3.9%, almost twice. A case can be made that the
high
growth rate was the result of the Fed’s monetary easing in response to
the
Asian financial crises which started on July 2, 1997 in Thailand
and whirled around Asia via contagion like a
tornado.
When contagion hit Wall Street in October, the Fed did what no other
central
banks could do. It printed dollars to provide liquidity to the US
banking system
to not only contain the crisis, but also to allow US banks to buy up
distressed
Asia assets at fire sale prices. It was a clear example of how dollar
hegemony
works.
“Rubinomics” is a doctrine of
aggressive trade liberalization paid for by squeezing domestic and
foreign
workers while balancing the fiscal budget at home by cutting social
programs to
avoid the need for raising taxes progressively. The Clinton Federal
surplus
came directly from the pockets of workers. Yet Rubin has said publicly
that he
understands that income inequality, both domestic and around the world,
will
produce a political backlash at the core that threatens the neo-liberal
trading
system, even the stability of capitalistic democracy. Rubin
acknowledges the
ill effect of globalization on US wages which takes on political
significance
when the squeeze shift from just the poor who seldom vote, to the
politically
active middle class. The favoritism of government policy towards the
rich,
particularly the tax structure, has become so embarrassingly obscene
that even
the super rich such as Warren Buffet complained about its unfairness.
Rubin has launched the Hamilton Project, a policy
group of like-minded
economists and financiers who are developing ameliorative measures to
aid the
threatened workforce and to create a broader political constituency
that will
defend the trading system against populist backlash. Yet how can one
defend a
system that creates wealth by making the majority poor? It is not
possible to
deify Mammon, the demon of the love of money.
The populist tidal wave may well build up to tsunami
scale. As outsourcing move
up the skill ladder, threatening the job security of not just assembly
line
workers, but highly educated, resourceful and active workers in
high-tech, information
technology, medicine and finance, the democratic process will turn
against
neo-liberal globalization. The backlash can turn ugly, mixing
xenophobia with
anti-Semitism. [End of excerpt]
The Below
Minimum
Wage
The minimum wage was $5.15 per hour in 2006. The
Fair
Minimum Wage Act of 2007
(Pub.L 110-28, Title VIII) amends the
Fair Labor Standards Act of 1938 of the Depression New Deal era and
gradually
raises the federal minimum wage from $5.15 per hour to $7.25 per hour.
It was
signed into law on May 25,
2007
as part of the US Troop Readiness, Veterans Care, Katrina Recovery and
Iraq
Accountability Appropriation Act, 2007. The act raises the Federal
minimum wage
in 3 increments: to $5.85 per hour 60 days after enactment (2007-7-24),
to
$6.55 per hour 12 months after that (2008-07-24), and finally to $7.25
per hour
12 months after that (2009-07-24). If the minimum wage were to rise at
the same
rate as CEO pay, it would be $22.61 per hour in 2006, about what
Japanese auto
makers pay their workers.
In his WSJ Opinion article, Reich did attack
income
inequality between CEOs and workers. But he asserts that “depending on
shareholders to rein in CEO pay is like relying on gamblers to rein in
the
owners of Las Vegas
casinos.” Yet casino
operators are more honest than most corporate management the governance
of
which is notoriously abusive of minority rights.
CEO Pay Obscene
The Financial Times reported in a front page
story
on
October 8 that US companies are facing fresh pressure from regulators
and shareholders
to rein in excessive executive pay.
In a special to CorpWatch June 26th, 2007
entitled Soaring Executive Pay
Attacked by
Shareholder Activists, Sam Pizzigati detailed
the
efforts of shareholder activists.
In 2006, the CEOs of the 500
biggest U.S.
companies averaged $15.2 million in total annual compensation,
according to
Forbes business magazine’s annual executive pay survey. The top eight
CEOs on
the Forbes list each pocketed over $100 million.
Larry Ellison, CEO of business software giant
Oracle, was
not in the top eight. Butas the 11th richest man in the world, who
ended 2006 being worth more than $16
billion, he should not complain on missing being among the top ten. University
of Chicago economist Austan
Goolsbee points out that a CEO like Ellison literally cannot spend
enough on
personal consumption to stop his fortune from growing. Goolsbee
calculates that
Ellison would have to spend over “$183,000 an hour on things that can’t
be
resold for gain, like parties or meals, just to avoid increasing his
wealth.”
In
2006,
Yahoo shares had sunk 35%, or about $20 billion, in
value. Top talent, according to press reports, was jumping ship, not
because of
low pay but because of loss of confidence in the company’s future. A
leaked
internal Yahoo memo -- known in tech sector circles as the “Peanut
Butter
Manifesto” – said that, like peanut butter on toast, Yahoo management
was
spreading the company dangerously thin.
Yahoo
CEO Terry Semel pocketed $71.7 million in 2006, over twice the
take-home
of any other chief executive in Silicon Valley.
Since
2001, the year he left Hollywood
to
take Yahoo’s top slot, Semel has cashed out an additional $450 million
in
personal stock option profits.
By
early June, three major shareholder advisory companies – which
advise large
investors how to vote at corporate annual meetings – urged a “no” vote
on the
re-election of three Yahoo board members who had served on the
company’s
executive pay committee. One of the three companies, Proxy Governance
Inc.,
noted that Semel’s compensation was running 926% “above the median paid
to CEOs
at peer companies.” Shareholder activism forced the Yahoo corporate
board to
announce Semel’s resignation.
Angelo Mozilo is CEO
of Countrywide Financial, the largest
U.S. home mortgage lender which the New York Times describes its entire
operation, from its computer system to its incentive pay structure and
financing arrangements, as intended to wring maximum profits out of the
mortgage lending boom no matter what it costs borrowers. He collected
over $285
million in the last 11 years, and $48 million in 2006. At Countrywide’s
annual
meeting in May, 2007, Mozilo presented a list showing that Countrywide
was 12th
in a list of U.S.
companies that had generated the greatest returns for shareholders.
That placed
it ahead of corporate giants Dell and Berkshire Hathaway whose top
guns,
Michael Dell and Warren Buffett, he noted, had both become
“multibillionaires.” Mozilo’s not-so-subtle message to shareholders: At
$285
million, I’m a bargain. Two months later, Countrywide, facing
insolvency from
exposure to the subprime mortgage melt-down, had to be bailed out by
Bank of
America.
Home builder Toll Brothers
CEO Robert
Toll earned $29.3 million in 2006. The
company’s net income in 2006 fell 15 percent. For the fiscal
first
quarter ended January 31, 2007,
Toll Brothers earned $54.3 million, or 33 cents per share, down from
$163.9
million, or 98 cents per share, in the year-earlier quarter. The
results
included write-downs of $96.9 million for the lower value of the land
Toll owns
or from forfeiting payments for land options Toll decided not to
exercise, as
well as a $9 million goodwill impairment charge related to its 1999
acquisition
of Silverman Cos. in Detroit.
Total
revenue for the quarter fell 19 percent to $1.09 billion while
contracts for
new homes fell 33 percent to 1,027 units. The value of the contracts
fell 34
percent to $749 million. During
third quarter 2007, Toll’s revenue fell some 21% to $1.21 billion
compared
to 1.53 billion in 2006. Its net income fell to $26.5 million or 16
cents a
share from $174.6 million or $1.07 a share in the comparable period
last year.
Finally, its backlog of orders stood at $3.67 billion, which is a
decline
of about 34% from the previous year.
Did the $29.3 million CEO
pay provide an incentive to stimulate Robert
Toll to
do better in the future? He owns nearly a fifth of the 5,500-employee
company’s
outstanding shares. That should already be enough incentive to want the
company
to do well.
Or is $29.3 million the
“sufficiently competitive” going rate for CEOs
in homebuilding?
Over the past shares of stock, so seems three years, Robert Toll has
taken home
almost seven times more than his CEO counterparts in the homebuilding
industry.
Reich is Aware
of
Inequitable Worker Pay
Reich admits that the real scandal of CEO pay
has to
do with
what has happened to the pay of most workers as CEO pay has soared.
Shareholder
returns have kept up with CEO pay, but median wages have not. In 1980,
the CEO
of a major company took home about 40 times what the median worker
earned; by
1990, CEO pay was about 100 times the median worker’s pay; in 2006 it
was close
to 300 times. In 2006, Wal-Mart’s Lee Scott Jr. earned 900 times the
pay of the
average Wal-Mart worker.
Reich recognizes that CEO pay is part of a much
larger
problem: the growing portion of the nation’s income that is going to a
small
number of people at the top. The pay packages of many denizens of Wall
Street
are even more outrageous than CEO pay – last year reaching $40 million
for top
traders and over a billion dollars for top hedge-fund managers. Not
since the
robber-baron era has income and wealth been as concentrated as they are
today.
This doesn’t threaten shareholders; after all, most shares are held by
the
wealthy. It threatens democracy, as the wealthy bankroll politicians
who tilt
public policies in the direction of the wealthy – by, say, reducing
their taxes
and cutting public services for everyone else. It also threatens our
economy,
as more and more investment decisions are made by fewer and fewer
people, and
as the middle class loses its capacity to pay for the goods and
services the
economy produces. Amazingly Reich claims that “the answer is not to
grant more
rights to shareholders. It’s to enact a far more progressive income
tax,
including a sharply higher marginal rate on yearly incomes above, say,
a measly
million.”
A Fair Tax
Regime
The purpose of taxation is not to be punitive
but to
anchor
fiat currency while maintaining equity. What gives the dollar currency
is its
role as legal tender for payment of US taxes and for “all debts, public
and
private”, as inscribed on every dollar, which is a Federal Reserve
note. The
key to fair taxation lie on both the revenue side and the expenditure
side: where
the tax revenue comes from and how the tax revenue is spent. A fair tax
regime requires
revenue to be sourced from all fairly, but not equally, and be spent on
public
services and affirmative action programs to moderate inequality. The
problem
with the current US
tax regime is that not only the revenue is sources from the working
poor but it
is also spent to further enhance the already substantial advantages of
the
rich.
Tax
cuts for the rich coupled with privatization of public utility and
services add up to a most onerous regime, on which the
former labor secretary is strangely silent. In simple terms,
it is a regime that puts money in the pocket of the rich who do not
need it,
and take money from the pockets of the working poor who already are in
debt up
to their ears. It is bad enough to milk
prosperity from a debt economy, but a debt economy that allows the rich
to
borrow to make obscene profits and forces the working poor to borrow
merely to survive
will soon turn populism into radicalism. It
is time for all countries to seek solutions
to problems created by run-away
exploitative terms of world trade by focusing again on fundamental
issues of
domestic development before the prodigal global trading system
collapses from
its own contradictions to bring forth a global depression. Unless and
until an
equitable international trading system is negotiated, economic
nationalism is a
proper response to neo-imperialism. |