|
Liquidity Boom
and Looming Crisis:
As Lqudity Decouples US Equity Markets from the US Economy
By
Henry C.K. Liu
This article appeared in AToL
on May 8, 2007, two months before the financial crisis imploded in
mid-July 2007.
Economic growth in the US
slowed to 1.3% in the first quarter (Q1) of 2007, the worst performance
in four
years of an overextended debt bubble. Yet the Dow Jones Industrial
Average (DJIA)
rose to an intraday all-time high of 13,284.53 to close at 13,264.62 on
Friday, May
4, 2007, rising over 1,000
points or 9% in the same period. The DJIA is now 82% higher than its
low of
7,286.27 on October 9, 2002
during which the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) grew only 38%.
The 10-year Cycle of Financial Crisis
The business cycle
appears to have been replaced by the funancial cycle. The historical
pattern of a 10-year rhythm of cyclical
financial crises looms as a menacing storm cloud over the financial
markets.
The 30% market crash of 1987, in which investors lost 10% of 1987 GDP,
was set
off by the 1985 Plaza Accord to push up the Japanese yen with an aim of
reducing the growing US
trade deficit with Japan.
The 1987 crash was followed 10 years later by the Asian Financial
Crisis of July
2, 1997, with all Asian economies going broke, with some stock markets
such as
Thailand’s losing 75% of their value, and Hong Kong having to raise its
overnight deposit rate to 500% which promptly crashed its real property
market, trying to defend the fixed exchange rates of
their currencies. In Korea,
Daewoo Motors, facing bankruptcy, was forced to be taken over on the
cheap by
General Motors. In Indonesia,
the Suharto government fell from social instability arising from the
financial
crisis. A wave of deflation spread over
all of Asia from which Japan,
already in recession since 1987, has yet to fully recover two decades
later. In
the US, the
DJIA dropped 7.2% on October 27, 1997
and the NY Stock Exchange had to suspend trading briefly to break the
free fall.
Now in 2007, a looming debt-driven financial crisis threatens to put an
end to
the decade-long liquidity boom that has been generated by the circular
flow of
trade deficits back into capital account surpluses through the conduit
of dollar
hegemony.
While the specific
details of these recurring financial crises
are not congruent, the fundamental causality is similar.
Highly-leveraged short-term
borrowing of low-interest currencies was used to finance high-return
long-term
investments in high-interest currencies through “carry trade” and
currency
arbitrage; with projected future cash flow booked as current profit to
push up
share prices.
In all these cases,
a point would be reached where the scale
would tip to reverse the irrational rise in asset prices beyond market
fundamentals. Market analysts call such as reversals “paradigm shifts”.
One
such shift was a steady fall in the exchange value of the dollar, the
main
reserve currency in international trade and finance, to cause a sudden
market
meltdown that quickly spread across national borders through contagion
with selling
in strong markets to try to save hopeless positions in distressed
markets.
There are ominous signs that such a point is now again imminent, in
fact
overdue, in globalized markets around the world.
Weak
Economic Data
US Gross Domestic
Product (GDP) growth of 1.3% for Q1 2007 released
by the Commerce Department on Friday, April 27 was even weaker by
almost half
than the 2.5% growth rate logged in the fourth quarter (Q4) of 2006.
The main
culprit was a housing slump caused by a meltdown in the sub-prime
mortgage
sector. Homebuilding dropped by 17% on an annualized basis and is
expected to
worsen going forward. That came after investment in homebuilding was
slashed at
an even deeper 19.8% pace in Q4 2006. There are no signs that the
housing slum
has hit bottom, or that its adverse impact on the economy and the
financial
market has been fully felt globally.
Deprived of
expanding wealth effect by falling home prices, USconsumer spending
was up only 0.3% in April on a 0.7% rise in personal income,
while core inflation was muted. Consensus estimates had been for a 0.5%
rise in
spending on a 0.6% gain in income. Adjusted for inflation, consumer
spending
was actually 0.2% lower month on month, its biggest drop since
September 2005, suggesting
that without additional cash-out refinancing on rising home values,
high energy
prices might have finally dampened consumer willingness and ability to
spend on
non-energy purchases.
GDP measures the
value of all goods and services produced in
the domestic economy. It is considered by economists and policymakers
as the
best overall barometer of economic health. US
economic performance in Q1 2007 was weaker by 0.5 percentage points
than even
the forecasted low expectation of 1.8%.
Federal Reserve
Chairman Ben Bernanke and Treasury Secretary
Henry Paulson both made obligatorily optimistic statements denying the
likelihood of a recession this year, even though former Fed chief Alan
Greenspan has openly put the odds at one in three.
Even though the
economy slowed in Q1 2007, inflation pressure
continues to complicate Fed policy deliberation. Core prices, excluding
food
and energy, rose at a rate of 2.2% in Q1 2007, up from a 1.8% pace in
Q4 2006.
Overall prices jumped by 3.4% in Q1 2007, compared to a 1.0% decline on
an
annualized basis in Q4 2006.
The
Fed’s Dilemma
While Federal
Reserve policymakers traditionally view
inflation as the main danger to the economy, they optimistically
predict that
inflation will moderate going forward as the central bank stays with a
tight
monetary policy. Since June 29, 2006,
the Federal Reserve has not moved the Fed Funds rate target, the
interest rate
at which depository institutions lend balances to each other overnight.
Before
that it had lifted rates 17 times at a “measured pace” of 25 basis
points over
a 36-month period, for a total 425 basis points to ward off inflation.
The current
Fed funds rate target is 5.25%, from a low of 1% set on June 25, 2003. Many economists
and money market
participants predict the Fed will continue to leave rates unchanged at
its next
meeting on May 10, 2007.
The Fed’s stated
goal is to cool an overheated economy
sufficiently to keep inflation in check by raising short-term interest
rates,
but not so much as to provoke a recession. Yet, in this age of finance
and credit
derivatives, the Fed’s interest rate policy no longer holds dictatorial
command
over the supply of liquidity in the economy. Virtual money created by
structured finance has reduced all central banks to the status of mere
players
rather than key conductors of financial markets. The Fed now finds
itself in a
difficult position of being between a rock and a hard place, facing a
liquidity
boom that decouples rising equity markets from a slowing underlying
economy
that can easily turn towards stagflation, with slow growth accompanied
by high inflation.
Wealth
Effect Exhausted and Dissipated by Maldistribution
The wealth effect
from rising equity prices has been caused
directly by a debt bubble fed by overflowing liquidity created beyond
the Fed’s
control, by the US
trade deficit denominated in dollars returning to the US
as capital account surpluses. This debt-driven liquidity boom is
exacerbated by
a falling dollar which artificially inflates offshore earnings of
transnational
corporation to support rising share prices pushed up by too many
dollars
chasing after a dwindling supply of shares caused by corporate
share-buyback
programs paid for with low-interest loans.
Further, the wealth
effect from the equity bubble has not
been broadly distributed, resulting in a boom in the luxury consumer
market catering
to the beneficiaries of capital gain while the broad consumer market
catering
to wage earners stalls. The newly rich in the financial sectors are
buying
multi-million-dollar first and second and even third homes, while
average
workers are buying cheap t-shirts and sneakers made in China.
The highest pay hedge fund managed took home $1.7 billion in 2006,
while the
average worker pay was $28,000 a year. The minimum wage was $5.15 per
hour. If
the minimum wage were to rise at the same rate as CEO pay, it would be
$22.61
per hour in 2006.
Wages
Decline while Returns on Capital Soar
Another troubling
bit of economic news came from the Labor
Department that while the DJIA rose 5.9% in Q1 2007 with inflation at
2.2 %, wages
and benefits grew by only 0.8%, down slightly from the low 0.9%
increase in Q4
2006. Wages and salaries went up 1.1%, the fastest since 2001, but
benefit
costs edged up only 0.1%, the slowest since Q1 1999 despite rising
medical
cost, reflecting a trend by companies to maximize their earnings by
abdicating
their social responsibilities to their workers and to society.
Labor’s share of the
GDP growth of 1.3% amounted to a
negative 2.6% after a 3.4% inflation adjustment, while capital’s share
was a
positive 2.5%. If labor’s share of GDP growth were to be kept at
neutral after
inflation, capital’s share would register a negative 0.1%. This is not
good
news to anyone except the Fed which views rising wages as inflation.
And if
labor’s share of GDP growth remains negative, companies will not be
able to
sell their products and will be forced to layoff workers to maintain
profit
margins, thus slowing economic growth still further.
Jobless
Expansion
Consumers spending
rose at a 3.8% pace in Q1 2007, slightly
weaker than the 4.2% growth rate logged in Q4 2006. This signals the
depletion
of the wealth effect from asset inflation. US
job creation slowed to its weakest pace in more than two years in April
as
layoffs extended beyond manufacturing and construction to retail trade.
Unemployment
rose to 4.5% in April from 4.4% in March with only 88,000 new jobs
created in
April, compared with an increase of 177,000 in March. The slowdown in
job
creation reflects recent economic weakness but is likely to be viewed
perversely
by the Federal Reserve as a welcome sign that wage inflation pressures
are
easing. Heavy job losses in the retail sector were a sign of a
“broad-based
deceleration” in employment in the service sector. The retail
sector shed 26,000 workers while
house builders cut 11,000 positions and manufacturers eliminated
19,000. Heavy
job losses in the retail sector were a sign of a “broad-based
deceleration” in
employment in the service sector, underlined fears about the resilience
of
consumer spending.
In April, private
sector jobs registered the weakest growth
in four years, increasing by only 64,000. Service firms added 106,000
jobs,
goods producers cut 42,000, small businesses created 45,000 jobs and
about
24,000 government jobs were added, adding up to
a job growth of 88,000, lower than the 100,000 forecasted. Unit labor
costs, a
much-watched inflation signal, rose at only 0.6% annualized, way below
expectations
of 2.1%. In the manufacturing sector, while jobs continue to decline,
the cost
figures were higher: productivity was up 2.7% while unit labor costs
grew as
well at 2.7%, reflecting growth in high-tech, big-ticket manufacturing
such as
commercial aircraft where the US still commands global competitiveness.
This
job-less recovery is still 6.7 million private sector jobs short of the
typical
recovery 67 months after a previous business-cycle peak.
New
Geometry of Debt Securitization
The mortgage sector
before the age of securitization was
shaped like a cylinder in which risk was evenly spread throughout the
entire sector
thus all mortgages share the aggregate cost of default. This even
spread
of risk premium is viewed as market inefficiency. Securitization
through
collateralized debt obligations (CDO) permits the unbundling of
generalized risk
embedded in all debt instruments into tranches
of escalating risk levels with compensatory higher returns and in the
process
squeezes additional value out of the same mortgage pool by maximizing
risk/return efficiency.
The geometry of CDO
scuritization transforms the cylinder
shape of the mortgage sector to a pyramid shape with least risky tranches at the top and the
more risky tranches with commensurate
premiums towards
the bottom, so that a greater aggregate risk premium can be squeezed
out by the
security packagers and investors as profit. This extra value when
siphoned off repeatedly
from the overall mortgage pool required an ever larger base of
sub-prime mortgages
in the new pyramid shape, thus increasing the systemic risk further.
Sub-prime
borrowers are no longer just low-income borrowers. They include
high-income borrowers whose
incomes and collateral value do not provide sufficient reserve for
sudden changes
in market conditions. A sub-prime borrower is one who over-borrows
beyond
prudent standards. The extra risk premium value thus taken out of the
mortgage
sector contributes to the increase in liquidity to further feed the
debt
market, pushing the low credit standard of sub-prime lending further
down. As prime credit customers having already
borrowed to their full credit limits, growth can only come from
lowering credit
standards, turning more prime borrowers into sub-prime borrowers.
This is the
structural un-sustainability of CDO securitization,
irrespective of the state of the economy since risk of default is
shifted from
the state of the market to the direction of the market. Any slight turn
in
market direction will set off a downward spiral crisis. The initial
upward phase
of this cycle is euphoric, but any addiction, but the pain will come as
surely
as the sun will set in the downward phase. Not many economists or
regulators
have yet focused on this structural defect of CDO securitization. The
recent
Congressional hearings on sub-prime mortgages completely missed this
obvious
structural flaw.
China’s
Foreign Reserves Mirage
China’s
latest foreign reserves data showed that there is as much as $73
billion in
unexplained new reserves. The People’s Bank of China (PBoC), the
central bank, now
holds over $1.2 trillion in foreign reserves, the most among the
world’s
central banks, except the US Federal Reserve which can create dollars
at will
and therefore needs not hold any foreign reserves. The Wall Street
Journal
explained the Chinese foreign exchange puzzle by suggesting that the
“leading
suspect is a possible series of foreign-currency swaps by Chinese
banks.” The
Journal reported that foreign exchange trading among Chinese banks in
2006 was
“more active than widely known.” The PBoC did not provide any comments
or an
explanation. The question is whether the funds were in fact swaps,
which would
mean only minor implications for the broader economy, or if they
actually were dollar
inflows, which could further stimulate an overheated economy.
Dollar inflows would
require further monetary tightening by
the PBoC, on top of the numerous interest rate and bank reserve
requirement
hikes over the past year, to reduce the risks of an equity bubble
fuelled by expanded
money supply. On April 29, China
raised the required banks reserve for the fourth time this year,
reducing the
amount available for bank lending in a new effort to cool an investment
boom
that could spark a financial crisis. The order by the central bank came
on top
of successive interest rate hikes and investment curbs imposed on real
estate,
auto manufacturing and other industries over the past year. The effort
has had only
limited success in slowing the frenzy growth of investment. The amount
of reserves
that lenders must keep with the central bank was raised 0.5 percentage
point to
11% of their deposits, from 7.5% of deposits before the first increase
in June
2006. The increase to 11% from 10.5% will take effect on May 15, 2007.
The central bank
said “the increase in bank reserve is aimed
at stepping up liquidity management of the banking system and to guide
a
reasonable growth of credit.” The consumer price index rose 3.3% in
March,
above the government’s 3% target. And fixed-asset investment
countrywide grew a
robust 23.7% during March. The economy grew 10.7% in 2006, the highest
rate
since 1995. The central bank said China’s
international balance of payments problem is boosting excessive
liquidity in
the Chinese economy.
China’s
Phantom Trade Surplus
Chinese global trade
surplus hit a record $177.5 billion in
2006, up 74% from the previous year.
Take away $73 billion
of capital inflow and $60 billion in returns on foreign capital, China
net trade surplus is only about $40 billion in 2006. By comparison Japan’s
trade surplus was $168 billion and Germany’s
trade surplus was $146 billion in 2006. US trade deficit
with China
widened to a record US$233 billion in 2006, out of a global
total of $857 billion. If the US
reduces its trade deficit with China, China
will reduce its own trade deficit with its other trading
partners, without much impact on the US
global trade deficit.
Dollar
Hegemony Distorts Chinese Economy
The adverse effect
of dollar hegemony on the Chinese economy is becoming clearly
visible. As the dollar-denominated trade surplus mounts, the PBoC is
forced to
tighten domestic macro monetary measures in order to neutralize the
increased
RMB money supply resulting from buying up the surplus dollars in the
Chinese
economy with yuan. The Chinese trade surplus is causing a monetary
bubble in
the Chinese economy while real wealth is leaving China
in the form of exported goods, causing a rising money supply chasing
after a
shrinking asset base.
The dollars that the
PBoC buys with Chinese yuan go to
finance the US
debt bubble. The new yuan money, instead of going to finance
development of the
interior region in China,
is attracted by speculative real estate and equities, pushing prices up
beyond
fundamentals. The Shanghai Stock Exchange Composite (SHCOMP) rose 27%
in a
month after a 7% drop that spooked world markets in late February,
including a
3% drop in the DOW. The Shanghai real
estate bubble keeps growing in a speculative frenzy while rural
villages are
starving for capital.
China
Re-Exports Dollars
Led by China and Japan, all the exporting
economies,
saddled with dollars that cannot be used in their domestic economies
without
creating a monetary crisis, are fuelling a global liquidity boom
focused
on the importing economies led by the US,
where the dollar is a legal tender that involves no conversion cost.
This
global liquidity boom denominated in dollars will cause inflation in
the dollar
economy that will spill over to all other economies. The US
real property boom has created huge service demands that lead to tight
labor
markets. The global commodity bubble of the past three years has
increased costs of living and production, adding over 5% to global GDP
growth.
Although commodity inflation has been absorbed through low-interest
consumer
borrowings and lower-wage labor in the past, it is now finally showing
up as
higher-cost factor inputs. China
has kept the global cost of manufacturing artificially low by not
paying adequately
for pollution control and worker wages and benefits, including
inadequate
retirement provisions. Domestic political pressure within China
is forcing the government to normalizing full production cost, which
will boost
global inflation.
Finance
Globalization and Inflation
Finance
globalization has increased the elasticity of
macro trends, causing a delayed effect in inflation. But it has
not
banished inflation all together, nor has it eliminated the business
cycle. It
has merely extended the historical cycle from 7 years to beyond 10
years.
Global inflation has picked up by 60 basis points in the past four
quarters. If the trend continues, major central banks will have
to focus
on fighting inflation by cooling the liquidity boom. To avoid a drastic
market
collapse, anti-inflation measures would need to be implemented at a
“measured
pace” which means it may take as long as two years to take effect. The
problem
is that the system which operates on ever rising asset values cannot
weather a
two-year-long anemic growth. Thus even a soft landing will quickly turn
into a
crash.
Bonds will be the
first asset class to decline in market value
in this anti-inflation cycle which will eventually also affect other
asset
classes. As the flat or inverted yield curve spikes upward back to
normal,
making the spread between long-term and short-term rates wider, the
commodity
bubble will burst, followed by the stock market in a general
deflation. Such
a deflation cannot be cured by the Fed
adopting inflation targeting through printing more dollars because
inflation
targeting is merely transmitting price deflation to a monetary
devaluation. Globalization and hedging has merely postponed but not
eliminated cyclical inflation.
Globalization has
stunted wage inflation
as the main transmission between monetary growth and inflation.
Hedging only
reassigns unit risk to systemic risk. It
does not eliminate risk. Instead, excessive liquidity fuels asset
appreciation beyond
economic fundamentals. To generate demand from the wealth effect,
appreciated
value must be monetized through debt. As debt rises, systemic
risk rises
with it. As globalization spreads demand growth around the world,
inflation has
taken longer than normal to show up in outdated data interpretation.
The burst of the
tech bubble, the 9/11 shock, the manufacturing
and IT outsourcing caused sharp disinflation in 2002 to neutralize
debt-driven dollar
inflation. The average dollar inflation of in the OECD economies
decelerated from 3.2% in second quarter of 2001 to 1.1% third quarter
of 2002.
The threat of dollar deflation caused the Fed to cut the Fed funds rate
to 1%
on July 9, 2003 and kept it
there for 12 months until July 7, 2004
while the Bank of Japan maintained a zero interest rate. This in turn
led to a
massive liquidity boom that fed an escalating US
trade deficit.
Before the emergence
of dollar hegemony through which it
became possible to finance the US
trade deficit with a US
capital account surplus, Fed chairman Paul Volcker has to raise Fed
funds rate
to an all-time high of 19.75% on December 17, 1980 to curb US
stagflation caused by a rising trade deficit. Five years later, in
1985,
Volcker engineered the Plaza Accord to force the Japanese yen up
against the
dollar to curb US trade deficit with Japan, promptly pushed the
Japanese
economy into sharp deflationary depression from which Japan has not yet
fully
recovered. Volcker’s victory over US
inflation was won with forcing deflation on Japan.
Global
Liquidity Boom Sourced by Dollar Supply Increase
The fountainhead of
the global liquidity boom is located in
the vast increase of the supply of dollars, both as a result of Fed
monetary
policy and of dollar-denominated structured finance under dollar
hegemony. This
liquidity boom has helped create demand through inflating asset
markets. The
wealth effect of property inflation produced both producer and consumer
spending
power released by debt. Commodity inflation has given producer
economies,
such as oil states, windfall income to invest in the advanced
economies.
Declining cost of capital fueled a new wave of financial expansion
through private
equity and hedge fund acquisitions finance with high leverage.
What
Is Liquidity and How Is a Liquidity Boom Created?
Liquidity is
affected by a monetary environment created by central
bank policies and actions. Lowering interest rates increases liquidity.
Easing
money supply measures relative to growth in nominal economic activity
also increase
liquidity. The level of liquidity in corporate
or individual balance sheets relates to cash and credit positions with
which to
invest or spend. But availability of money alone does not create
liquidity
which requires a market in which assets can be bought and sold without
regulatory restrictions or causing fundamental shifts in price levels.
The
demand for assets relative to their supply also affects liquidity.
Market confidence fundamentally affects
liquidity which depends on states of mind of market participants
relating to
appetite for risk-taking.
Hedge funds
contribute significantly to the increase of liquidity by enlarging
investor
appetite for risk-taking. Collateralized
debt obligations (CDOs) and credit derivatives have acted
to expand liquidity in the credit markets through disintermediation and
innovation. Banks have moved from the traditional
“buy-and-hold” mode to the “originate-and-distribute” mode, whereby
they
distribute portfolios of credit risks and assets to other market
players
through securitization. Banks also act increasingly as suppliers
of revolving credit
independent of their deposits as they obtain additional credit
protection
through credit derivatives.
A liquidity boom
requires the continuing confluence of all
these factors, an even slight change in any of which can have an
unraveling
effect that puts a sudden end to it. A
precipitous fall in the dollar could trigger market sell-offs as it did
after
the Plaza/Louvre Accords of 1985 and 1987 to first push down and later
push up
the dollar, which contributed to the 1987 crash. Another cause of
the 1987 crash was a threat
by the House
Ways and Means
Committee to eliminate the tax deduction for interest expenses incurred
in
leverage buyouts. Still another cause was the 1986 Tax Act, while
sharply
lowering marginal tax rates, nevertheless raised the capital gains tax
to 28%
from 20% and left capital gains without the protection against inflated
gains
that indexing would have provided. This caused investors to sell
equities to
avoid negative net after-tax returns and contributed significantly to
the 1987
crash.
The
Danger of a Liquidity Bust
Today, any one
factor out of a host of interconnected
factors, such as new regulation on hedge funds, or sharp changes in the
yuan
exchange rate against the dollar, or an imbalance between tradable
assets and available
credit, etc, could bring the current liquidity boom to a screeching
halt and
turn it into a liquidity bust. With
finance globalization and the dominance of derivative plays by hedge
funds and
private equity firms, any minor disruption can turn into a financial
perfect
storm that makes the collapse of Long Term Capital Management look like
a
tempest in a tea cup.
William Rhodes,
Chairman, President and Chief Executive
Officer of Citibank, N.A. and Chairman, President and Chief Executive
Officer
of Citicorp Holdings Inc., wholly owned subsidiaries of Citigroup Inc
of which
Rhodes is Senior Vice Chairman, wrote in March 2007: “During the last
big
adjustment that started in July 1997 in Thailand and spread to a number
of
Asian economies including South Korea, followed by Russia in 1998 - and
led
ultimately to the bail-out of Long Term Capital Management, the US
hedge fund -
a number of today’s large market operators were not yet in the mix.
Today,
hedge funds, private equity and those involved in credit derivatives
play
important, and as yet largely untested, roles. The primary worry of
many who
make or regulate the market is not inflation or growth or interest
rates, but
instead the coming adjustment and the possible de-stabilizing effect
these new
players could have on the functioning of international markets as
liquidity
recedes. It is also possible that they could provide relief for markets
that
face shortages of liquidity. Either way, this clearly is the time to
exercise
greater prudence in lending and in investing and to resist any
temptation to
relax standards.”
The five-year global
growth boom and four-year secular bull
market may simply run out of steam, or become oversaturated by too many
late-coming imitators entering a very specialized and exotic market of
high-risk, high leverage arbitrage. The liquidity boom has been
delivering
strong growth through asset inflation (property, credit spreads,
commodities,
and emerging market stocks) without adding commensurate substantive
expansion
of the real economy. Unlike real physical assets, virtual financial
mirages
that arise out of thin air can evaporate again into thin air without
warning. As
inflation picks up, the liquidity boom and asset inflation will draw to
a close,
leaving a hollowed economy devoid of substance.
Massive fund flows
from the less experienced non-institutional,
retail investors into hot-concept funds such as those focusing on
opportunities
in BRIC (Brazil, Russia, India and China) or in commodities, or in
financial
firms involved in currency arbitrage and carry trades, have caused a
global
financial mania in the past five quarters which has defied gravity
which will
all melt away in a catastrophic unwinding some Tuesday morning.
Inflationary
pressure in the US
and other OECD economies makes a cyclical bear market inevitable and an
orderly
unwinding unlikely. Central banks cannot ease because of a liquidity
trap that
prevents banks from being able to find credit worthy borrowers at any
interest
rate. Banks would be pushing on a credit
string and global liquidity could decline, causing risk asset
valuations to
contact suddenly and sharply. A liquidity trap
can also occur when the economy is stagnant and the nominal interest
rate is close or equal to zero, and the central bank is unable to
stimulate the
economy with traditional monetary tools because people do not expect
positive
returns on investments, so they hoard cash to preserve capital. Capital
then
becomes idle assets.
As the decade-long US
consumption collapses from exhaustion, a secular bear market will set
in
where rebounds are smaller and do not wipe out previous losses. Because
Asia’s growth has been
driven by
low-wage export, it will not be ready fill in as the global growth
engine in
time to prevent a global crash. China
is just beginning to change its development model to boost worker
income and household
consumption and may take as long as a decade to see the full effects of
the new
policy. China’s
only option is to insulate itself from a global meltdown by resisting
US
pressure to speed up the opening of its financial markets. China’s
purchasing power is too weak to save the global economy from a
deflationary
depression.
A global financial
crisis is inevitable. So much investment
has been sunk into increasing commodity production that a commodity
market
bust, while having the effect of a sudden tax cut for the consuming
economies,
will cause bankruptcies that will wipe out massive amounts of global
capital.
A financial crisis
could trigger a global economic hard
landing. Global financial markets look suspiciously like a pyramid game
in this
over-extended secular bull market. The proliferation of complex
derivative
products catering to short-term trading strategies that aim to get the
biggest
bang for the buck creates massive uncertainty surrounding leverage in
the
global financial system. A commodity burst could cause correlation
trades to
unwind in other markets, which could snowball quickly into a massive
financial
crisis.
When markets are
hot, fund manager companies tend to market
funds aggressively, especially ones with hot concepts. Commodity, BRIC,
etc, have
been the hot concepts in this cycle. Tens of billions of dollars have
been
raised by such funds from the less experienced retail investors over
the past
three quarters in Japan, Korea, Taiwan, Hong Kong, etc. This source
of money has fueled rapid
price appreciation in the recipient markets.
Starved of good
returns in the US,
long-term investors have been allocating funds to emerging market and
commodity
specialists to chase the good performance. Such funds have flowed
disproportionately into small and illiquid stocks, causing them to rise
in
rapid multiples. Their good performance attracts more funds and
reinforces the
virtuous cycle.
Rising leverage is
another technical factor that has artificially
boosted liquidity in the hot markets. Derivative products like warrants
are a
major factor. Some funds leverage up to increase exposure to high-beta assets. Beta is a coefficient
measuring a stock’s relative volatility, a
covariance of a stock in relation to the rest of the stock market.
Capital
preservation strategies prefer low-beta
stocks. High-beta assets offer high
returns for taking high risks.
Before finance
globalization, if short-term dollar interest
rates were higher than longer-term interest rates, a condition
reflected by an
inverted yield curve, US Treasury bond prices could not be boosted by
carry
trades between currencies. Today, borrowing short-term low-interest
currency to
invest in longer-term debt in high interest currencies, thus earning
the
“carry”, or interest rate spread, between the two types of debt
denominated in
separate currencies is routine. If short-term rates in the US
are prohibitively high, or higher than long term rates, then
carry-traders can
simply do most of their borrowing overseas in a foreign currency.
Furthermore, if
the 4% spread between short-term Japanese interest rates and US T-Bond
yields
is not sufficiently rewarding, the return can be boosted to 40% using
routine
10:1 leverage.
More lucrative
still, borrow in Japanese yen to invest in
Brazilian or Turkish bonds, using various derivatives to hedge currency
or
credit risk and pass it on to counter-parties at the cost of a
relatively small
insurance premium. The supply of “hot money”, money that can be shifted
around
rapidly in response to changes in expected returns now seems to be
endless
because if monetary conditions start to get tighter in one part of the
world
then the speculators can always find a source of low-cost financing
somewhere
else. And the Bank of Japan (BOJ), and later joined by the Federal
Reserve, with
their zero or near-zero, or at least below-neutral interest rates,
effectively
underwrites the whole process.
The financial
markets experienced minor shocks recently when
the BOJ soaked-up a lot of liquidity and hinted on the need to commence
a
rate-hike program. The minor shocks in fact forced the BOJ to back away
from
its planned monetary tightening to keep the speculative frenzy going.
This is
the reason why the inversion of the US
yield curve which normally mean liquidity was about to contract, has
not yet
triggered a liquidity recession. A liquidity boom will continue as long
as a
major central bank with large foreign reserves, such as the BoJ,
continues to
price short-term credit at bargain-basement levels and leaves its
borrowing
window open to all comers. The People’ Bank of China also contributes
to the
global liquidity boom by its willingness to continue to buy long-term
US
T-bonds even if rates falls. The US
current account deficit is the key driver of the liquidity boom. Those
who
clamor for a reduction of the US
trade deficit are unwitting calling for a US
recession.
When the ongoing
meltdown in the sub-prime mortgage spreads
to other parts of the credit markets, the Federal Reserve will be
forced to
implement a monetary ease. But a liquidity trap will activate the
dynamics of
an inverted yield curve, with long term rate falling faster than the
Fed funds
rate. When demand for bank reserves decreases due to a general slump in
loan
demand, then the Fed has to destroy bank
reserves in order to prevent
a collapse of Fed funds rate to zero.
A
Liquidity Trap with $50 trillion of Idle Assets can be a
Doomsday Machine
A liquidity trap can
be a serious problem because the world
is still plighted with excess liquidity potential: massive foreign
reserves
held by central banks, bulging petro-dollars, hedge funds and private
equity
funds, massive increases in global monetary base, $4 trillion in
low-yielding
Chinese bank deposits ready for release for higher yields, $5 trillion
in
low-yielding U.S. time deposits maturing, $10 trillion in low-yielding
Japanese
financial net worth plus $27 trillion in medium-yielding U.S. household
financial net worth waiting to be monetized for aggressive yields. A
global
liquidity trap of with $50 trillion of idle assets will implode like a
doomsday
machine.
The exchange rate is
a measure of the relative value of
these currencies, not the intrinsic value of the dollar. When the euro
rises
against the dollar, it is possible that both currencies have fallen in
purchasing power, but the euro has merely fallen less than the dollar.
This is
what drives the liquidity boom that has decoupled the equity markets
from the real economy.
|
|
|
|
|