|
Critique of Central Banking
By
Henry C K Liu
Part I: Monetary
theology
Part II: The European Experience
Part
IIIa: The US experience
This article
appeared in AToL
on November 16, 2002
In the United
States, central banking was not born until 1913 with the establishment
of the Federal Reserve System. The first national bank in the US was
the Bank of the United States (BUS), founded in 1791 and operated for
20 years, until 1811. A second Bank of the United States (BUS2) was
founded in 1816 and operated also for 20 years until 1836. The first
national bank, modeled after British experience, was established by
Federalists as part of a nation-building system proposed by Alexander
Hamilton, the first secretary of the Treasury, who realized that the
new nation could not grow and prosper without a sound financial system
anchored by a national bank.
The national bank
charter was approved by Congress and signed into law by president
George Washington in 1791 when the federal government of the new nation
was only three years old. The new national bank, known as the Bank of
the United States, was to assist the newly formed federal government by
holding its funds and, when necessary, by making loans to it. By
issuing notes that would circulate as legal tender, the national bank
would help to maintain an adequate supply of stable money and by
extending government credit to support an industrial policy to promote
economic expansion.
To understand the
thinking behind Hamilton's proposal for a national bank, it is
necessary to remember that the Treasury was restricted by law to limit
its issuance of money to the coinage of gold and silver, and not to
print paper money. According to orthodox monetary theory under the
influence of the Quantity Theory of Money (QTM), specie (gold- or
silver-backed) money was the only reliable currency, though it could be
supplemented by banknotes fully and freely redeemable for gold or
silver. Congress granted a 20-year charter for the BUS despite
arguments by Thomas Jefferson that the constitution did not give
Congress power to establish a national bank and the charge that the
national bank was designed to favor mercantile interests over agrarian
interests, and the rich over the common man, in the name of national
interest.
The federal
government subscribed one-fifth of the capital of $10 million of the
BUS, with a loan of $2 million immediately advanced from the BUS to the
government, with the remaining $8 million subscribed by private
investors. The BUS acted as exclusive fiscal agent for the government
and also conducted commercial banking business. Despite being well
managed and financially profitable, the BUS antagonized state-chartered
banks and Western frontier and Southern agrarian interests, which
formed a coalition that successfully blocked its rechartering in 1811.
Jefferson's
opposition to the establishment of a national bank was key to his
overall opposition to the entire Hamiltonian program of strong central
government and elite financial leadership. Jefferson felt that a
national bank would give excessive power over the national economy and
unfair opportunities for large certain profits to a small group of
elite private investors mostly from the New England states. The
constitutionality of the bank invoked the dispute between Jefferson's
"strict construction" of the words of the constitution and Hamilton's
doctrine of "implied power" of the federal government.
Throughout the
history of the United States, up to the present time, this dispute,
along with the controversy between specie money and fiat money, remains
philosophically unresolved, although in practice both the
constitutionality of "implied power" doctrine and the legality of fiat
currency have been repeatedly upheld by the Supreme Court. Jefferson
considered the whole Hamiltonian banking scheme an unconstitutional
threat to the basic fabric of American civilization. Jefferson
prophesied: "If the American people allow the banks to control the
issuance of their currency, first by inflation, and then by deflation,
the banks and corporations that will grow up around them will deprive
people of all property until their children will wake up homeless on
the continent their fathers occupied ... The issuing power of money
should be taken from the banks and restored to Congress and the people
to whom it belongs." It was a definitive statement against the
political "independence" of central banks. This warning applies to the
people of the world as well.
The most significant
achievement of the Jefferson presidency was the Louisiana Purchase. In
1800, the Treaty of San Ildefonso secretly transferred Louisiana from
Spain to France, which presented the United States with the alarming
prospect of a vigorous and expansionist European power controlling the
mouth of the Mississippi river to block the westward expansion of the
US. James Monroe was sent to Paris to negotiate the purchase of
Louisiana from a willing Napoleon Bonaparte, who earlier had sent an
expeditionary army to Haiti to put down a black slave rebellion with
subsequent plans to occupy New Orleans to exercise French control over
Louisiana. The decimation of the French expeditionary army by yellow
fever, the need for more troops for renewed Napoleonic wars in Europe,
and the difficulty of running the British naval blockade convinced
Napoleon that strengthening the United States as a potential ally under
a pro-French Jefferson and as a potential rival of Britain might serve
French interests.
France agreed to
sell Louisiana in 1803 for $15 million, including in the package an
immense territory extending northward as far as Canada and westward to
the Rocky Mountains, covering more than a million square miles. The
purchase was financed through the then four-year-old BUS. But according
to a strict construction of the constitution, the federal government
did not have authority to acquire new territory or, as provided under
the treaty with Napoleon, to grant full citizenship to its inhabitants,
not to mention the chartering of a national bank. Jefferson swallowed
his scruples about the constitution, became in effect an "implied
powers" advocate and lobbied energetically for Senate ratification of
the Louisiana Purchase.
Hamilton's idea of
national credit was not merely to favor the rich, albeit that it did so
in practice, but to protect the infant industries in a young nation by
opposing Adam Smith's laissez-faire doctrine promoted by advocates of
19th-century British globalization for the advancement of British
national interests. This is why Hamilton's program is an apt model for
all young economies finally emerging from the yoke of Western
imperialism two centuries later, and in particular for opposing US
neo-liberal globalization of past decades.
The creation of a
national bank was one of the three measures of the Hamiltonian program
to strengthen the new nation through a strong federal government, the
other two being 1) an excise duty on whiskey to extend federal
authority to the back country of the vast nation and to compel rural
settlers to engage in productive enterprise by making subsistence
farming uneconomic; and 2) federal aid to manufacturing through
protective tariff and direct subsidies. To Hamilton, a central
government without sovereign financial power, which had to rely on
private banks to finance national programs approved by a democratically
elected congress, would be truly undemocratic and to rely on foreign
banks to finance national programs would be unpatriotic, if not
treasonous.
Hamilton's national
program was opposed effectively by the two special-interest groups with
controlling influence in Congress: the Northern trading merchants and
shippers who had secured a Navigation Act to protect US shipping in
1789 and Southern planters who depended on export of unprocessed
agricultural commodities, neither of which had any interest in curbing
foreign trade even when such trade was harmful to the development of
the national economy. Domestic manufacturing interest did not become
strong enough to obtain much government protection until after the War
of 1812. The dynamics of this politics is visible in the 21st century
in many developing nations where the financial elite prefers compradore
opportunism to economic nationalism.
Congressional
opposition to the first BUS resulted in its charter expiring in 1811
without renewal. However, the financial pressure after the War of 1812
created demands for another national bank. By 1807, France under
Napoleon controlled most of Europe while Britain commanded the sea by
destroying the French fleet at Trafalgar in 1805. This land-sea
stalemate pushed the two rival superpowers to economic warfare through
British blockades against French overseas trade, answered by Napoleon's
Continental System applying sanction against all trade with Britain,
making the neutral United States a collateral-damage victim of
interrupted trade. In the US, agrarian westward expansionism, facing
effective native American resistance under a tribal confederacy
coordinated by Chief Tecumseh, agitated for US conquest of British
Canada, justified as retaliation against the British blockade of US
shipping, despite the fact that most US shippers did not want to
antagonize a powerful Britain in full control of the sea.
The Western
Expansionist Movement found political expression in the election of
1810 and sent to Congress a group of young representatives who became
known as the War Hawks, led by Henry Clay as House Speaker. Despite
belligerent speeches by the War Hawks, the US was unprepared for war,
the most significant shortage being government finance. With tax
revenue covering less than two-thirds of government expenditure, and
without a national bank, the government was compelled to borrow from
banks owned by Eastern mercantile interests who opposed the war for
fear of more British measures against US shipping, leaving the US war
effort ill-financed.
By 1814, having
defeated Napoleon in Europe at the battle of Leipzig in October 1813
with a coalition of Eastern European agrarian feudalism, Spanish
clericalism and German nationalism financed by British capitalism to
the tune of Stg23 million, supported by the matchless British navy and
the combined armies of Russia, Prussia and Austria, the British was
able to send an expeditionary army to foil US hopes of conquering
Canada. The British also landed an invasion army on Chesapeake Bay in
the summer of 1814 and marched into Washington, burning the White
House, nearly capturing president James Madison himself, but were
finally repulsed at Baltimore, a battle that inspired Francis Scott Key
to write The Star Spangled Banner, which later was adopted as
the national anthem.
On January 8, 1815,
another British expeditionary army of veterans from the Napoleonic Wars
was defeated near New Orleans by Andrew Jackson with a kill ratio of
2,000:13 against the British, in a decisive demonstration of the
effectiveness of modern riflemen against 18th-century European troop
formations. It was reminiscent of the triumph of British longbow
archers over French aristocratic calvary in the Battle of Agincourt in
1415, which decimated the French armored knights, the flower of French
nobility, and ended its role henceforth as an effective fighting force.
The Treaty of Ghent
declared the end of the War of 1812, in which neither side achieved
military victory or gained any political advantage. While the treaty
was being signed, a group of delegates from New England met at
Hartford, Connecticut, to discuss secession from the union. By
deviating from Hamilton's cause of national unity, the neo-Federalists
spelled their own political end but not the policy demise of
Federalism, which remained US policy until the Jackson administration.
Had the BUS been in operation, the US war effort might have been better
financed and Canada might have become a part of the United States.
The second Bank of
the United States went into operation with a capital of $35 million in
1816, with the federal government owning only 5 percent of the stock.
For a decade after the War of 1812, there existed no clear-cut party
division in US politics, thus the term "era of good feeling" was
applied. The Republican Party abandoned its original Jeffersonian
opposition to Federalism and adopted Federalist policies, starting with
the establishment of the second BUS, adopting tariffs to protect
struggling US industries and federal appropriation for infrastructure
development. Henry Clay proposed the "American System", based on
Hamiltonian ideals, but unlike Hamilton, Clay cultivated popular
support, not only appealing to the upper class, and sought support from
the agricultural South, not just the mercantile New England states. It
was a national program of federal aid to domestic development and
tariff protection for struggling US industry.
The disappearance of
the first BUS had left the nation's currency system in a chaotic state.
Since 1791, a large number of state banks had been chartered, reaching
208 by 1815, and except in New England, these banks were allowed to
issue notes very much in excess of their capital ratio and to make
loans without sufficient reserves.
BUS2 fulfilled its
basic function during a period of relative prosperity and operated with
popular support. The charter empowered BUS2 to act exclusively as the
federal governments fiscal agent, hold its deposits, make inter-state
transfers of federal funds and deal with Federal payments or receipts.
Like state chartered banks, BUS2 also had the right to issue banknotes
on the basis of a fractional reserve system and to carry out
conventional commercial banking activities, in return for which certain
conduct of a central-bank-like nature was expected of this institution:
in the words of the charter, "the bank will conciliate and lead the
state banks in all that is necessary for the restoration of credit,
public and private, and to steer the banking system toward serving the
national interest", at a time when profit might be higher in serving
foreign interests. Despite being 80 percent privately owned, BUS2
operations were subject to supervision by Congress and the president.
BUS2 was dominant relative to all other banks, being responsible for
some 20 percent of all bank lending in the national economy and
accounting for 40 percent of the banknotes then in circulation. It was
conservative in its note-issuing function, holding a specie reserve of
50 percent of the value of its notes while the norm for the remainder
of the banking system was between 10-25 percent.
In 1821, the Monroe
administration forced a declining Spain to sell Florida to the United
States for $5 million, most of which was paid to US citizens with
claims against the Spanish government, for failure to close the Florida
border to runaway slaves and marauding Seminole native Americans. In
return, the US renounced its claim to Texas. The purchase was financed
by BUS2. On December 2, 1823, the US declared the Monroe Doctrine
against European intervention and colonization in the Americas, from
Argentina to Alaska.
The hopes of Clay's
national program in diminishing sectional conflict and class
differences were not realized. The chief beneficiaries of the banking
and tariff legislation were the trading businesses in the northeastern
states at the neglect of Southern planters and Western farmers. BUS2
quickly came under the control of eastern seaboard interests, which
were accused of seeking to dominate and exploit the West in sectional
conflicts. During the decade of 1810-19, five new states - Louisiana,
Mississippi and Alabama in the Southwest; Indiana and Illinois in the
Midwest or old Northwest - came into being. The Land Law of 1800
stimulated public land sale with generous terms of payment spread over
four years, rising from 1 million acres in 1815 to 5 million acres in
1819. A speculative bubble on land was financed by state banks and
government seller credit, which burst in 1819. The collapse was
attributed throughout the West as being caused by the policies of BUS2,
which had made a practice of buying up the notes of state banks and
suddenly presenting them for payment, forcing the state banks to call
in loans to Western farmers, driving them into bankruptcy, with much
Western land falling into the hand of BUS2 private shareholders through
foreclosures.
The 1820s and 1830s
in the United States were a time of extremely rapid but also volatile
economic growth. New natural resources were being exploited as the
frontier expanded and the new techniques of the industrial revolution
were being introduced. The old money supply of gold and silver specie
was stretched and found inadequate for the liquidity needs of the
growing economy. In 1830, the total value of the gold and silver specie
in circulation in the economy amounted to one-fiftieth of the gross
national product. The emergence of a number of banks operating
fractional reserve note-issuing systems was the automatic result.
The
private banknotes were underwritten by varying proportions of specie
and although not legal tender, they were widely accepted in payment for
debts, albeit usually discounted below their par value. The quality of
banknotes varied. Fraud was commonplace by unscrupulous bankers who
managed to persuade or bribe local state legislatures to grant them
liberal charters to commence a banking business. In 1828, the 17 banks
chartered in Mississippi circulated notes with a face value of $6
million from a specie base of $303,000. The classic conflict between
easy money and good money ensued, with the economic benefits of easy
money regularly destroyed by bad money.
It was in such an
environment that BUS2 operated. Among its functions was to discipline
and support the state-chartered banks without shutting off easy money.
As the federal government's fiscal agent, it received banknotes in
payment for taxes. The Bank would then present these banknotes to the
issuing state-chartered banks in order to redeem them for the gold
necessary to pay the taxes it had collected to the federal Treasury's
account. In this way, state-chartered banks were forced to keep a
higher stock of specie on reserve than would otherwise be necessary.
Conversely, BUS2 could also act as a lender of last resort to
state-chartered banks in trouble by not presenting these notes for
redemption but rather allowing these banks to run into debt to BUS2.
The state-chartered banks were institutions of economic democracy,
offering credit to the masses, not just to big business. Some were
named people's banks or other names of democratic or socialist
connotation. They generally financed local small business, farms and
homes.
The political
environment of that period was marked by the populist ideology of
Jacksonian democracy. Focused around Andrew Jackson, who was elected
president in 1828, this ideology was an coalition of convenience among
agrarianism, nationalism, populism and libertarianism. The one unifying
element of this group was a deep hostility to a privileged East
Coast-based moneyed aristocracy. The Philadelphia-based BUS2 with its
patrician president, Nicholas Biddle, became an easy target in this new
climate. Libertarians, while sounding sensible on a small scale, always
fail to understand that individual liberty has no place in organizing
large-scale national enterprises. Complex organizations, whether in
business or government, require wholesale compromise of individual
liberty.
The ideology that
underlay the struggle against a national bank was highly variegated,
with contradicting internal inconsistencies. It was a peculiar blend of
moral judgment, economic logic and populist sentiment fused by
pragmatic calculations to attack the political legitimacy of a national
bank, its legality and its economic rationale.
The role played by
vested interests in motivating the anti-BUS forces can also be traced
to the substantial personal gains that would accrue to key members of
the Jackson administration should BUS2 be discontinued. The New York
financial community at the time was competing with Philadelphia to be
the country's premier commercial center. Martin Van Buren, Jackson's
second-term vice president and eventual successor, was particularly
identified with Wall Street in this Wall Street (New York
internationalist) versus Chestnut Street (Philadelphia nationalist)
battle.
The state-chartered
banks disliked being constrained by BUS2's practice of redeeming their
banknotes with little or no notice, and with blatant arbitrariness in
the selection of a target, often based on thinly disguised sectional
bias. This forced a much higher bank reserve ratio and hence restricted
their lending activities in geographic sections deem contrary to
national priorities. A new class of nouveau riche, self-made
entrepreneurs and speculators, emerged, a class to which Jackson and
many of his associates belonged. They disliked the restriction of
credit generally, and credit allotment controlled by established
Northeastern financiers particularly, as they relied on liberal credit
from the friendly state-chartered local banks for needed funds, the way
leverage-buyout financiers and corporate raiders and New Economy
entrepreneurs relied on junk-bond investment bankers in the 1980s and
'90s.
The New York
financial community was divided over the question of the wisdom of the
attack on BUS2. Some of the state-chartered banks grudgingly
acknowledged BUS2's positive role in disciplining the banking system
and its activities as a lender of last resort. Political ideology and
economic logic also played a role behind the opposition of a national
bank. The opposition had much popular support in national politics
which enabled Jackson to dismantle BUS2. Like Ronald Reagan, Jackson
was elected to Washington to rein in Washington.
The strongest
opposition came from states-rights advocates who vehemently opposed the
substantial power wielded by a federally chartered national bank. Many
considered the chartering of the bank an unconstitutional extension of
the power of Congress, particularly when, in their judgment, the first
national bank had failed to serve the national interest without
sectional bias and had pandered to sectional interests around the
northeastern seaboard. This position was summarized by Jackson, who
described BUS2 bank as an unconstitutional threat to democratic
institutions by the federal authorities. With the dismantlement of
BUS2, the power of intervention in the banking and monetary systems was
left in the hands of individual states until the Civil War.
State-chartered banking systems served the separate interests of each
state, which often were at odds with the national interest.
A key strand in the
anti-national-bank thread was the libertarians. They challenged the
legitimacy, more on moral than constitutional grounds, of any
government intervention in the economy or in society beyond minimum
necessity. Libertarians, while sounding sensible on a small scale, fail
to understand that individual liberty to organize large-scale national
enterprises is a mere fantasy. "Small is beautiful" remains merely a
romantic slogan of hippiedom.
The 1800s were an
age of primitive laissez-faire philosophy in the United States when
domestic markets were not yet sophisticated enough to require
government intervention against trade restraint in the sense that Adam
Smith used the term "laissez-faire" to denote activist government
action to keep markets free. This libertarian philosophy was related to
and associated with the Free Banking school, which challenged on
ideological grounds the necessity of government intervention in the
monetary system.
Free Bankers were in
favor of a paper currency based on a fractional reserve system. But
they argued that BUS2's regulatory function was unnecessary and
ineffective because in a completely unregulated financial system, free
competition would automatically protect the public against fraud
through market discipline, on the principle that fraud was basically
bad for business. They argued that what was wrong with the banking
system was that free competition was obstructed by the monopolistic
privileges granted to BUS2 in its charter and this created an unhealthy
reliance on regulatory protection rather than market self-discipline,
in a form of consumer moral hazard that believed naively that if a
business was regulated, consumer interest would automatically be
protected. In the context of the dominant economic paradigm of the
1830s, the importance of the central government's role in regulating
the money supply was not as self-evident as is today. And for the
Western frontiersman, his love of individual liberty exposed him to
easy victimization by organized finance from the East.
Economist Joseph A
Schumpeter (1883-1950) observed that in the first part of the 19th
century, mainstream economists believed in the merit of a privately
provided and competitively supplied currency. Adam Smith differed from
David Hume in advocating state non-intervention in the supply of money.
Smith argued that a convertible paper money could not be issued to
excess by privately owned banks in a competitive banking environment,
under which the Quantity Theory of Money is a mere fantasy and the Real
Bills doctrine was reality. Smith never acknowledged or understood the
business cycle of boom and bust.
The
anti-monopolistic and anti-regulatory Free Banking School found support
in agrarian and proletarian mistrust of big banks and paper money. This
mistrust was reinforced by evidence of widespread fraud in the banking
system, which appeared proportional to the size of the institution.
Paper money was increasingly viewed as a tool used by unconscionable
employers and greedy financiers to trick working men and farmers out of
what was due to them. A similar attitude of distrust is currently on
the rise as a result of massive and pervasive corporate and financial
fraud in the so-called New Economy fueled by structured finance in the
under-regulated financial markets of the 1990s, though not focused on
paper money as such, but on derivatives, which is paperless virtue
money.
Andrew Jackson in
his farewell speech addressed the paper-money system and its natural
association with monopoly and special privilege, the way Dwight D
Eisenhower warned a paranoid nation against the threat of a
military-industrial complex. The value of paper, Jackson stated, is
liable to great and sudden fluctuations and cannot be relied upon to
keep the medium of exchange uniform in amount.
In contrast to the
Free Banking School, the anti-paper specie-currency zealots aimed at
abolishing the system of fractional reserve paper money by removing the
lender of last resort. They were further split into gold bugs, silver
bugs and bimetalists.
Both advocates of
the Free Banking School and proponents of specie currency saw the
dismantling of the bank as very fundamental, but to divergent and
conflicting ends. Against this coalition, supporters of a national
bank, such as BUS2 president Nicholas Biddle and politicians such as
Henry Clay and John Quincy Adams, faced a political dilemma. Both
anti-federalist and primitive laissez-faire sentiments were in
ascendancy at the time. The BUS2 was being attacked from both the
extreme left (Free Banking advocates) and from the extreme right
(anti-paper advocates).
The monetary
expansion that preceded and led to the recession of 1834-37 did not
come from a falling bank reserve ratio but rather from the bubble
effect of an inflow of silver into the United States in the early
1830s, the result of increased silver production in Mexico, and also
from an increase in British investment in America. Thus a case could be
made that central banking's role in causing or preventing recessions
through management of the money supply is overstated and
oversimplified.
Libertarians hold
the view that the state had no right to regulate any commercial
transactions between consenting individuals including paper currency.
Thus all legal tenders, specie or not, are government intrusions. Yet a
medium of exchange based on bank liabilities and a fractional reserve
system and/or government taxable capacity is essential to an
industrializing economy. Instead of destroying the fractional reserve
system, the hard-money advocates had merely removed a force that acted
to restrain it.
After 1837, the
reserve ratio of the banking system was much higher than it had been
during the period of BUS2's existence. This reflected public mistrust
of banks in the wake of the panic of 1837 when many banks failed. This
lack of confidence in the paper-money system could have been
ameliorated by central-bank liquidity, which would have required a
lower reserve ratio, more availability of credit and an increase of
money supply during the 1840s and 1850s. The evolution of the US
banking system would have been less localized and fragmented in a way
inconsistent with large industrialized economics, and the US economy
would have been less dependent on foreign investment. This did not
happen because central banking was genetically disposed to favor the
center against the periphery, which conflicted with democratic
politics. This problem continues today with central banking in a
globalized international finance architecture. It remains a truism that
it is preferable to be self-employed poor than to be working poor. Thus
economic centralism will be tolerated politically only if it can
deliver wealth away from the center to the periphery. Central banking
carries with it an institutional bias against economic nationalism.
The Jackson
administration's assault on BUS2 began in 1830 and became a campaign
issue for a second term. In 1832, Jackson used his presidential veto to
thwart a renewed federal charter for BUS2. Jackson then used his
second-term presidential election victory later that year as a mandate
to order the withdrawal of all federal funds from BUS2 in 1833. When
the BUS2 charter expired in 1836, the Philadelphia-based institution
succeeded in being rechartered only as a much reduced state-chartered
bank under the auspices of the Pennsylvania state legislature as the
United States Bank of Pennsylvania. In 1841, without a lender of last
resort, it went bankrupt in a liquidity squeeze speculating in the
cotton market.
The dismantling of
the second national bank preserved the authority of the states over
banking. Large-scale federal intervention in the supply of money did
not take place again until the Civil War. However, Jackson's victory
turned US political culture against centralized institutions in the
banking system. The United States did not develop a central banking
agency until 1913. Even then, the Federal Reserve System was highly
decentralized, consisting of 12 autonomous component banks, one in each
of the regional large cities. Some historians attributed the incoherent
response of the monetary authorities to the 1929 crash and the
resultant run on the banking system. The 1930s Great Depression was due
partly to this decentralization of monetary authority.
Martin Van Buren
succeeded Jackson as president in the 1836 election. The Jackson
administration was able to appoint eight new Supreme Court justices,
including new chief justice Roger Taney from Maryland, who succeeded
John Marshall. The fundamental issues in US politics have often been
manifested more clearly by changes in judiciary attitude. Whereas
Marshall extended the power of the federal government through his
upholding of the implied power doctrine, Taney believed in protecting
the rights of the states, upheld their right to regulate commerce
within their territories and to set economic policy autonomously. While
Marshall regarded sanctity of contracts and private property right with
religious reference, Taney was prepared to allow state regulation of
private property rights for the promotion of the general welfare.
Before his
nomination as chief justice, Taney was Jackson's Treasury secretary,
and it was he who carried out Jackson's order to withdraw federal
deposits from BUS2 beginning in September 1833 to a number of
state-chartered banks that, free of BUS2 supervision, pushed the
economy quickly into a debt bubble, much of it centering on speculation
on the sale of public land. The boom produced a sudden increase of
government revenue and, in 1835, for the first and last time in
history, the US paid off its national debt completely, with a mounting
surplus in the Treasury. In 1836, Congress passed a bill to distribute
the surplus to the states. Far from being an economic blessing, this
development turned out to be an economic disaster.
The fall in money
supply led to a crash in early 1837, precipitated by the Treasury
secretary's issuance of the Specie Circular, requiring payment for
public land sale be made only in gold or silver, not banknotes. The
resultant depression lasted throughout Van Buren's administration, but
his commitment to strict constitutional construction prevented him from
taking any federal action toward recovery. Van Buren's main focus was
putting government's finances on a sound footing. The widespread
failure of state-chartered banks showed the danger of trusting private
banks with government money, and Van Buren decided henceforth to
divorce government finance from private banking. The government should
keep its money in an Independent Treasury, with "vaults" constructed in
major cities where government official would receive and pay out funds
on a strict specie basis.
The federal
government had no further connection with the banking industry until
the National Bank Act of 1863. Although the Independent Treasury did
restrict reckless speculative expansion of credit, it also tended to
create a new set of economic problems. In periods of prosperity,
revenue surpluses accumulated in the Treasury, reducing hard-money
circulation, tightening credit, and restraining even legitimate
expansion of trade and production. In periods of depression and panic,
on the other hand, when banks suspended specie payments and hard money
was hoarded, the government's insistence on being paid in specie tended
to aggravate economic difficulties by limiting the amount of specie
available for private credit.
The 1863 US National
Bank Act amended and expanded the provisions of the Currency Act of the
previous year. Any group of five or more persons with no criminal
record was allowed to set up a bank, subject to certain minimum capital
requirements. As these banks were authorized by the federal government,
not the states, they are known as national banks, not to be confused
with a national bank in the Hamiltonian sense. To secure the privilege
of note issue they had to buy government bonds and deposit them with
the comptroller of the currency.
When the Civil War
began in 1861, newly installed president Abraham Lincoln, finding the
Independent Treasury empty and payments in gold having to be suspended,
appealed to the state-chartered private banks for loans to pay for
supplies needed to mobilize and equip the Union Army. At that time,
there were 1,600 banks chartered by 29 different states, and altogether
they were issuing 7,000 different kinds of banknotes.
Lincoln immediately
induced the Congress to authorize the issuing of government notes
(called greenbacks) promising to pay "on demand" the amount shown on
the face of the note. These notes were not issued as "dollars" but as
promissory notes authorized under the borrowing power of the
constitution. The total cost of the war came to $3 billion. The
government raised the tariff, imposed a variety of excise duties, and
imposed the first income tax in US history, but only managed to collect
a total of $660 million during the four years of Civil War. Between
February 1862 and March 1863, $450 million of paper money was issued.
The rest of the cost was handled through war bonds, which were
successfully issued through Jay Cooke, an investment banker in
Philadelphia, at great private profit. The greenbacks were supposed to
be gradually turned in for payment of taxes, to allow the government to
pay off these greenback notes in an orderly way without interest.
Still, during the gloomiest period of the war when Union victory was in
serious doubt, the greenback dollar had a market price of only 39 cents
in gold. Undoubtedly these greenback notes helped Lincoln save the
Union. Lincoln wrote: "We finally accomplished it and gave to the
people of this Republic the greatest blessing they ever had - their own
paper to pay their own debts." The importance of the lesson was never
taught to Third World governments by neo-liberal monetarists.
In 1863, Congress
passed the National Bank Act. While its immediate purpose was to
stimulate the sale of war bonds, it served also to create a stable
paper currency. Banks capitalized above a certain minimum could qualify
for federal charter if they contributed at least one-third of their
capital to the purchase of war bonds. In return, the federal government
would give these banks national banknotes to the value of 90 percent of
the face value of their bond holdings. This measure was profitable to
the banks, since with the same initial capital, they could buy war
bonds and collect interest from the government, and at the same time
put the national banknotes in circulation and collect interest from
borrowers. As long as government credit was sound, national banknotes
could not depreciate in value, since the quantity of banknotes in
circulation was limited by war-bond purchases. And since war bonds
served as backing for the notes, the effect was to establish a stable
currency.
The system did not
work perfectly. The currency it provided was not sufficiently elastic
for the needs of an expanding economy. As the government redeemed war
bonds, the quantity of notes in circulation decreased, causing
deflation and severe hardship for debtors. Money seemed to be
concentrated in the Northeast, and Western and Southern farmers
continued to suffer chronic scarcity of cash and credit, not unlike
current conditions faced by Third World debtor economies.
After the Civil War,
the Independent Treasury continued in modified form, as each
administration tried to cope with its weaknesses in various ways.
Treasury secretary Leslie M Shaw (1902-07) made many innovations; he
attempted to use Treasury funds to expand and contract the money supply
according to the nation's credit needs. The panic of 1907, however,
finally revealed the inability of the system to stabilize the money
market; agitation for a more effective banking system led to the
passage of the Federal Reserve Act in 1913. Government funds were
gradually transferred from sub-treasury "vaults" to district Federal
Reserve Banks, and an act of Congress in 1920 mandated the closing of
the last sub-treasuries in the following year, thus bringing the
Independent Treasury System to an end.
John P Altgeld, a
German immigrant populist who became the Democratic governor of
Illinois in 1890, attacked big corporations and promoted the interest
of farmers and workers, gave the state an able, courageous and
progressive administration. The question of currency was central to the
US populist movement. Farmers knew from first-hand experience that the
fall in farm prices was caused by the policy of deflation adopted by
the federal government after the Civil War and only ineffectively
checked by the Bland-Allison Act of 1878, coining silver at a fixed
ratio of 16:1 with gold, and the Sherman Silver Purchase Act of 1890.
The Treasury's redemption of silver with gold increased the value of
money and deflated prices.
Despite the rapid
growth of business, the government engineered a sharp fall in the per
capita quantity of money in circulation. The National Bank Act of 1863
also limited banks' notes to the amount of government bonds held by
banks. The Treasury paid down 60 percent of the national debt and
reduced considerably the monetary base, not unlike the bond-buyback
program of the Treasury in 1999. To farmers, it was unfair to have
borrowed when wheat sold for $1 per bushel and to have to repay the
same debt amount with wheat selling for 63 cents a bushel, when the
fall in price was engineered by the lenders. To them, the gold standard
was a global conspiracy, with willing participation by the US
Northeastern bankers - the money trusts who were agents of
international finance, mostly British-controlled.
President Grover
Cleveland, despite winning the 1892 election with populist support
within the Democratic Party, gave no support to populist programs.
Cleveland saw his main responsibilities as maintaining the solvency of
the federal government and protecting the gold standard. Declining
business confidence caused gold to drain from the Treasury at an
alarming rate. The Treasury then bought gold at high prices from the
Morgan and Belmont banking houses at great profit to them. Populists
saw this effort to save the gold standard as a direct transfer of
wealth from the people to the bankers and as the government's
capitulation to international finance capital. Cleveland even sent
federal troops to Illinois to break the railroad strike of 1894, over
the vigorous protest of governor Altgeld.
The election of 1896
was about the gold standard. Cleveland lost control of the Democratic
Party, which nominated 36-year-old William Jenning Bryan, who declared
in one of the most famous speeches in US history (though mostly shunned
these days): "You shall not press down upon the brow of labor this
crown of thorns, you shall not crucify mankind upon a cross of gold."
The banking and industrial interests raised $16 million for William
McKinley to defeat Bryan, who suffered a defeat worse than Jimmy
Carter's. With the McKinley victory, the Hamiltonian ideal was firmly
ordained, but with most of its nationalist elements sanitized. It was
not dissimilar to the Reagan victory over Carter in 1980.
The 16th amendment
to the US constitution calling for a "small" income tax was enacted to
compensate for the anticipated loss of revenue from the lowering of
tariffs from 37 to 27 percent as authorized by the Underwood Tariff of
1913, the same year the Federal Reserve System was established. "Small"
now translates into an average of 50 percent with federal and state
income taxes combined.
The Glass-Owen
Federal Reserve Act was passed in December 1913 under the
administration of president Woodrow Wilson. The system set up five
decades ago by the National Bank Act of 1863 had two major faults: 1)
the supply of money had no relation to the needs of the economy, since
the money in circulation was limited by the amount of government bonds
held by banks; and 2) each bank was independent and enjoyed no systemic
liquidity protection. These problems were more severe in the South and
the West, where farmers were frequently victimized by bank crises often
created by Northeastern money trusts.
The money elite
wanted a central bank controlled by bankers, along Hamiltonian lines,
but internationalist rather than nationalist. But the Wilson
administration, faithful to Jacksonian tradition despite political
debts to the moneyed elite, insisted that banking must remain
decentralized, away from the control of Northeastern money trusts, and
control must belong to the national government, not to private
financiers with international links, despite the internationalist
outlook of Wilson. Twelve Federal Reserve Banks were set up in
different regions across the country, while supervision of the whole
system was entrusted to a Federal Reserve Board, consisting of the
Treasury secretary, the comptroller of the currency and five other
members appointed by the president for 10-year terms. All nationally
chartered banks were required and state-chartered banks were invited to
be members of the new system. All private banknotes were to be replaced
by Federal Reserve notes, exchangeable at regional Federal Reserve
Banks not only for bonds or gold, but also for top-rated commercial
paper, with the hope of causing the money supply to expand and contract
along with the volume of business. With the reserves of all banks
deposited with the Federal Reserve (Fed), systemic stability was
supposed to be assured.
The circumstances
that created the climate in the United States for the adoption of a
central bank came ironically from internecine war on Wall Street that
spread economic devastation across the nation during 1907-08, the
direct result of one huge money trust trying to cannibalize its
competition.
The Rockefeller
interests of "Amalgamated Copper" had a plan to destroy the Heinze
combination, which owned Union Copper Co. By manipulating the stock
market, the Rockefeller faction drove down Heinze stock in Union Copper
from 60 to 10. The rumor was then spread that not only Heinze Copper
but also the Heinze banks were folding under Rockefeller pressure. J P
Morgan joined the Rockefeller enclave to announce that he thought the
Knickerbocker Trust Co would be the first Heinze bank to fail. Panicked
depositors stormed the tellers' cages of the Knickerbocker Bank to
withdraw their money. Within a few days the bank was forced to close
its doors. Similar fear spread to other Heinze banks and then to the
whole banking world. The crash of 1907 was on.
Millions of people
were sold out penniless and rendered homeless by bank foreclosures, and
their savings wiped out by bank failures. The destitute and the hungry
fended for themselves as best they could, which was not very well.
Circulating money was hoarded by any who happened to still have some,
so before long a viable medium of exchange became practically
non-existent. Many business concerns began printing private IOUs and
exchanging these for raw materials as well as giving them to their
workers for wages. These "tokens" passed around as a temporary medium
of exchange.
At this critical
juncture, J P Morgan offered to salvage the last operating Heinze bank
(Trust Co of America) on condition of a fire sale of the valuable
Tennessee Coal and Iron Co in Birmingham to add to the monopolistic US
Steel Co, which he had earlier purchased from Andrew Carnegie.
This arrangement
violated existing anti-trust laws but in the prevailing climate of
depression crisis, the proposed transaction was quickly approved in
Washington. Morgan was also intrigued by the paper IOUs that various
business houses were being allowed to circulate as a medium of
exchange. He persuaded Congress to let him put out $200 million in such
"tokens" issued by one of the Morgan financial entities, claiming this
flow of Morgan "certificates" would revive the stalled economy. As
these new forms of Morgan "money" began circulating, the public
regained its confidence and hoarded money began to circulate again as
well. Morgan circulated $200 million in "certificates" created out of
nothing more than his own "corporate credit" with formal government
approval. It was a superb device to make millions. GE Capital in the
1990s did the same thing with commercial papers and derivatives to
create hundreds of billions in profits.
Conspiracy theorists
assert that the seeds for the Federal Reserve System had been sown with
the Morgan certificates. On the surface J P Morgan seemed to have saved
the economy - like first throwing a child into the river and then being
lionized for saving him with a rope that only he was allowed to own, as
some of his critics said. On the other hand, Woodrow Wilson wrote: "All
this trouble [the 1907 depression] could be averted if we appointed a
committee of six or seven public-spirited men like J P Morgan to handle
the affairs of our country." Both Morgan and Wilson were
internationalists.
By 1908, J P Morgan
was working with senator Nelson Aldrich of Rhode Island, who was
related to the Rockefeller family by marriage, and whose surname was
the middle name of vice president Nelson A Rockefeller, to establish a
private central banking system. Aldrich was the maternal grandfather of
Nelson Rockefeller.
Ironically, the
initial idea of the need for a central bank came from the populist
movement, which began in Lampasas County in Texas when a group of
desperate farmers formed in 1877 the Knights of Reliance to educate
themselves speedily against the time "when all the balance of labor's
products would become concentrated into the hands of a few, there to
constitute a power that would enslave posterity". Uninhibited by the
awesome high science of economics, average citizens in the
late-19th-century United States were pragmatically aware of the
political implications of monetary policy. The Farmers Alliance,
renamed from the Knights of Reliance, held regular traveling lectures
that quickly concluded that the causes of their members' financial ruin
were the gold standard and the private banking system that enforced its
confiscatory terms.
The populists
proposed a solution in August 1886 in a convention in Cleburne, Texas.
The "Cleburne Demand" called for federal regulation of the banking
system and a fiat national currency to meet the liquidity needs of an
expanding economy. Public pressure was making increasingly vocal
demands for a plan to eliminate Wall Street control and exploitation of
the economy for narrow private benefit.
In response,
Morgan's ally, senator Aldrich, arranged to become chairman of the
National Monetary Commission, which received an assignment from
Congress to study the US monetary system and make recommendations of
ways to improve it. Paul Warburg, whose brother Max was in charge of
the Reichsbank, the privately owned national bank of Germany,
emphasized the absolute necessity of setting up a new national banking
system that would prevent Wall Street from putting the United States
through devastating "boom and bust" cycles as it had in the past.
On November 22,
1910, a private railroad car pulled out of the station at Hoboken, New
Jersey, with several powerful people aboard. Others joined the meeting
later. They met at the J P Morgan estate on Jekyll's Island, Georgia.
This secret meeting included senator Nelson Aldrich; A P Andrews,
professional economist and assistant secretary of the Treasury; Frank
Vanderlip, president of the National Bank of New York City, which later
became Citibank; Harry P Davidson, senior partner of the J P Morgan Co;
Charles D Norton, president of Morgan's First National Bank of New
York; Paul Warburg, partner of the banking house of Kuhn, Loeb Co in
New York; and Benjamin Strong of the J P Morgan Co central office in
New York, who later became the first president of the New York Fed and
dominated the new central bank for the first two decades. After nine
days, they produced a bill for Congress that was later submitted as the
"Aldrich Plan". Conspiracy theorists made much about this infamous
secret meeting.
The main resistance
to the Aldrich Plan came from the House of Representatives, where an
official investigation had revealed some of the ruthless operations of
powerful financial interests on Wall Street and definitely fixed
responsibility on Wall Street (especially Rockefeller and Morgan) for
the crash of 1907-08, similar to current public indignation over
Enronitis.
With the tide of
popular opposition rising, it was obvious that the Republicans were not
going to be able to get the Aldrich Plan adopted. Strategy then
switched to influencing the Democratic Party, which immediately came up
with an "alternative" plan to be called the Federal Reserve
Association. It was in essence the Aldrich Plan with a different name.
The next task was to defeat the sitting Republican president, William
Howard Taft of Ohio, in the 1912 election and get a more sympathetic
Democratic administration in power. Taft was popular, but he opposed
the Aldrich Plan. The political strategy was therefore redesigned to
induce another Republican, popular Teddy Roosevelt, to run on a
Progressive ticket against Taft and thus divide the Republican Party.
Morgan officers
provided both the money and the strategy to help Roosevelt win
Republican votes away from Taft. George Harvey, president of the
Morgan-controlled Harpers Weekly, and Rockefeller money got behind
Wilson. The Wilson team included Cleveland H Dodge of Rockefeller
National City Bank, J Ogden Armour, James Stillman, George F Baker,
Jacob Schiff, Bernard Baruch, Henry Morgenthau, and the publisher of
the New York Times, Adolph Ochs. The Morgan officials who managed Teddy
Roosevelt's campaign were also found to have put extensive money behind
Wilson. As might have been expected, the strategy worked and Wilson was
elected with 6.29 million votes while Roosevelt drew 4.12 million votes
and Taft, who won with 7.68 million votes over William J Bryan's 6.4
million in his first-term victory, drew only 3.46 million votes.
Progressivism
reached its high-water mark in the 1912 campaign. Taft plainly had no
chance of re-election, the main contest being between Roosevelt and
Wilson. Both men proposed to revitalize democracy by limiting the
powers of big business. Wilson, winning 42 percent of the popular vote,
polled fewer than Bryan had done in each of his three unsuccessful
campaigns. But with the Republicans split between Taft and Roosevelt,
he carried 40 states to become a minority president.
When Woodrow Wilson
took over the White House in 1913, he brought with him his Wall Street
advisers, including "Colonel" Edward Mandell House, who is now known to
have been the major policy-maker and manager of the entire Wilson
administration. In his personal writings, House describes the
pile-driver tactics that were used to force a bill through Congress
that would authorize the setting-up of the new Federal Reserve System
as a privately owned central bank.
The leading
financiers of Wall Street pretended to protest vehemently against the
bill. In his autobiography, William McAdoo, Wilson's son-in-law, who
became secretary of the Treasury, says he was very impressed by the way
the "bankers fought the Federal Reserve legislation - and every
provision of the Federal Reserve Act - with the tireless energy of men
fighting a forest fire. They attacked it as populist, socialistic,
half-baked, destructive, infantile, badly conceived and unworkable."
But McAdoo found that when he engaged these bankers in private
conversation, he realized their opposition was merely a smokescreen to
hide their true feelings. He wrote: "These interviews with bankers led
me to an interesting conclusion. I perceived gradually, through all the
haze and smoke of controversy, that the banking world was not really as
much opposed to the bill as it pretended to be."
On December 22,
1913, with the prospect of the Christmas holiday pressuring Congress
into final action before the session closed, the House voted 298-60 in
favor of the new Federal Reserve System, and the Senate passed it
43-25.
From its beginning,
the dominant guiding principle of the Fed was financial rather than
economic, though its charter directed it to "accommodate the needs of
commerce and industry". Fed policy-makers concentrated on preventing
inflation to calm investor fear, not on lowering unemployment or
restoring falling farm prices. Fed officials spoke of "liquidation of
labor" as part of sound central-banking principle, which harbors a bias
toward preserving the health of the financial sector over the real
economy. In order to restore the former, it was necessary to punish the
latter. Lose weight to save the heart.
Next: More on the US experience
|
|
|
|
|