|
Wages of
Neoliberalism
By
Henry C.K. Liu
Part
I: Core Contradictions
Part II: The US-China Trade Imbalance
Part III: China's Internal Debt Problem
Part IV: Development
Financing and Urbanization
This article appeared in AToL on
July 22, 2006
Similar to other developing countries, the most fundamental
development problem China faces in its path towards industrialization
is
urbanization. Yet China is unique because of its size. China has more
than 200
cities with a population of over one million. While this is more than
any other
country, China today is still a country with a predominantly rural
population.
The largest city is non-coastal Chongqing (15.3 million with
30 million in its metropolitan area) on the bank on the Yangtse River
upstream in
Sichuan province in the southwest interior; next is coastal Shanghai
(13.1
million with 20 million in the metropolitan area) at the mouth of the
Yangtse;
and next is Beijing (12.2 million with 15 million in metropolitan
area), the
nation’s capital.
Only 515 million (40%) of the 1.3-billion Chinese population
are urbanized as of the end of 2003, compared to an average 70% for
developed
countries. Britain was 37% urbanized in 1850, the US 41% in 1910 and
Japan 38%
in 1950. During the past two and a half decades, China has
industrialized to a
far greater extent than it has urbanized. By developed country
standards,
China’s current industrialization level should have generated 60%
urbanization
instead of 40%. That is an urbanization gap of 280 million people,
larger than
the population of the US. Its level of economic development has also
outpaced
its urbanization which should be 50% rather than 40%.
China’s Historical
Conditions
Yet Chinese historical conditions raise doubt on whether
Western norms of urbanization have any relevance for China. Some six
decades
ago China emerged from a century of semi-colonial feudal economy
dominated by
foreign interests into the beginning of a sovereign modern socialist
society
based on agrarian revolutionary ideology which continues to inform
Chinese
politics today. The path of escape from
semi-colonialism was through anti-imperialism by political revolution
against a
decrepit dynasty. The political struggle for national revival was
complex and
protracted, spanning over almost a century of violence that includes a
post-revolution civil war that has yet to end almost six decades after
the establishment of the
People’s Republic. After political revolution succeeded on the mainland
in
1949, the path from a feudal economy has been through modernization and
the
path towards building a modern socialist society is through continuing
socio-economic revolution, not neo-liberal revisionism. These three
paths intertwine
inseparably in Chinese politics. None of them should be confused with
the
insipid infiltration of Westernization which has manifested itself in
the form
of cultural imperialism disguised as universal modernity during the
past two
centuries and as global neo-liberalism in the past two decades.
Today, some 800 million people of China’s population of 1.3
billion still live in rural areas. While China has begun to
industrialize at a
fast pace, industrial workers are still a minority constituent in the
Chinese
political structure. When the Communist Party of China (CPC) was formed
85
years ago on July 1, 1921 in Shanghai by a group of young intellectuals
influenced by new exposure to Marxist ideology, the Party Congress was
attended
by only 58 delegates. They elected Chen Duxiu as the party’s first
chairman who
viewed the urban industrial worker as the natural ideological base for
socialist
revolution. The rural peasantry was
considered too conservative and provincial to be a fertile
revolutionary base
on which to bring China into socialism in the modern world through
revolutionary communism. The CPC at its very beginning constituted
itself as a
minority party of industrial workers and had to pay a high price for
the
ideological mistake.
Still, according to Harvard political scientist/historian
Benjamin Schwartz (Chinese Communism and
the Rise of Mao, Cambridge, Mass. 1958), by 1927 the
communist-organized
“All China Federation of Trade Unions” grew to a membership of 2.8
million
concentrated in a few coastal cities while the rural peasant
associations
represented by Mao Zedong had only around 2 million members, too widely
scattered all over the countryside to be taken seriously as a potent
revolutionary force. While this achievement in organizing industrial
workers
made the CPC one of the larger communist parties in the world at the
time, it
camouflaged its irrelevance in Chinese political reality.
Yet this was when the Koumingtang (KMT) right-wing,
representing the interests of the budding national bourgeoisie and
established
landlords, newly under the nationalistic influence of rising fascism,
and
focusing on urban centers as seats of political power, became alarmed
at the
spread of communist influence among China’s new factory workers. This fear was not based on any long-range
vision of national revival needs, but on short-sighted desire to keep
wages low
to ensure easy profit for a new class of national capitalists and their
foreign
partners and creditors. Within the KMT, the fascist right-wing broke
with the
socialist left-wing, and with the assassination in 1925 of Liao
Zhongkai, Sun
Yatsen’s top aide and heir apparent, seized control of the coalition
government
to suspend cooperation with the CPC by abruptly disarming the Shanghai
workers
militia and liquidating with mass terror all communist organizations in
urban
areas.
Mao Zedong escaped the anticommunist White Terror in
Shanghai and went to the rural interior where, with the help of peasant
general
Zhu De, he founded a guerrilla army in rural Jinggangshan on the border
of
Hunan and Jiangxi provinces to continue resistance. Under the
leadership of
Mao, a vast region with over 60 million inhabitants soon turned
enthusiastically to support a communist administration. The basis for
this
popular support was not abstract Marxist ideology but a practical
program of
socialist land reform that brought long-denied social justice to the
suffering
peasants.
In the spring of 1934, Chiang Kai-shek, led an army of
550,000 newly trained and equipped by Nazi Germany to undertake an
anti-communist “Bandit Extermination Campaign” (Qiao-fei) that
encircled the
100,000-member, ill-equipped Red Army and threatened it with complete
annihilation. In response, the out-numbered Red Army embarked on a
historic and
heroic Long March of 7,000 circuitous miles to finally reach its home
base in
Yenan in northern Shaanxi province in October 1935 with only 20,000
survivors.
At the bleakest point of the Long March, an enlarged meeting of the CPC
Politburo was held in January 1935 at Junyi at Guizhou to consider
desperate
options to breakout of the KMT encirclement to avoid total destruction. In the emergency meeting Mao proposed a shift
in strategy to rely not on the urban industrial worker but the
peasantry for
support of the revolution. On this populist platform, Mao was elected
as the
new leader of the CPC. This strategy, being responsive to Chinese
political
reality, eventually led to total communist victory over the whole
nation. Henceforth, the CPC has been a
majority party
of the Chinese peasantry. The term “proletariat class” has since been
interpreted in Chinese political lexicon as “property-less” class,
which in
Chinese culture has traditionally meant farmers without their own land,
not
just industrial workers.
While the factors behind the defeat of the Koumingtang by
the CPC have since been controversially debated among conservative
Western
historians, to most Chinese observers the key factor behind the failure
of KMT
was clearly its self-inflicted inability to cultivate and keep the
support of
the Chinese peasantry. It is the
unavoidable fate that awaits any political party in China should it
make the
same mistake, be it imperial, monarchist, fascist, capitalists or
communist. In
Chinese political culture, support from the peasantry is known commonly
as the
Mandate of Heaven (Tian-ming). Chinese communism has strong and
distinctive
historical and indigenous roots that 19th-century Marxism
and 20th-century
Leninism reenergized.
At the top of the list of obvious reasons why the KMT fell
was pervasive official corruption, which was related to inflation.
Prices rose
throughout KMT rule at more than 30% a year but the salary of
government
officials, already suffering from traditional institutional defect of
below-market pay for the bureaucracy, were not indexed, so bureaucrats
could
not survive financially without corrupt sources of extra income. Yet
the real
and fatal corruption was the super greed at the highest levels of
government
which set unsavory standards for the entire public sector. Perpetrators
could
feel safe from persecution as long as they did not steal more than
their
superiors. It was open secret that after the Nationalist Treasury ran
dry from
official corruption and war, the three top political families, the
Chiangs, the
Songs and the Kungs, related through marriages, were the exclusive
beneficiaries of massive US financial aid to China from 1942 to 1949.
Hyper-inflation in the last days of KMT rule, which was
caused in no small way by high-level corruption in large-scale monetary
fraud,
robbed the KMT of all popular support. On August 19, 1948, with US aid,
a new
gold-backed yuan was issued at an exchange rate of 4 yuan to a US
dollar. By
mid May 1949, the yuan fell to 23.3 million to a dollar. Less than five
months
later, on October 1, 1949 when the People’s Republic was proclaimed by
the CPC,
the KMT had already fled to Taiwan. The fact that the KMT fell from
power with
the free fall of its currency explains why China is hyper-sensitive
about the
danger of hyper-inflation associated with a free-floating and freely
convertible RMB yuan.
Another reason for the demise of the KMT was that, due
chiefly to its elitist outlook, the party suffered from a preference
for a
small number of elite cadres from the time of its very founding. The
shortage
of committed cadres was further exacerbated by the war with Japan in
which over
100,000 young officers became casualties, two thirds of the new
graduates of
the Central Military Academy, plus 19,000 of the 24,000 young civilian
cadres
trained for mass mobilization and development tasks.
Even before the war, the KMT had put low priority on social
and land reform, particularly the redistribution of land. The KMT
relied on the
conservative absentee landlord class living in luxury in cities for
support in
its half-hearted resistance against Japanese aggression. After the war,
US
anti-communist influence prevented the KMT from introducing critically
needed
social reform. KMT policies, hijacked by the national bourgeoisie and
conservative
landlords, neglected the interior countryside and its peasant
population in
favor of coastal cities artificially buoyant with foreign capital,
giving a
false impression of a growing economy while the nation was actually
falling
into socio-economic chaos.
Finally, the KMT, as a political amalgam of diverse special
interest groups and privileged social classes, exclusive of the peasant
masses,
the only class that really counts in Chinese politics, became paralyzed
by
internecine factional conflicts that prevented the natural emergence of
any
politics of self-preservation as it did in the US during the Great
Depression
through a general election.
Today, the 71-million-member Chinese Communist Party, to
various degree of seriousness, is faced with several similar if not
identical
shortcomings that brought down the KMT, such as a cadre corps
demoralized by a
social milieu that celebrates money ahead of revolutionary ideology, as
symbolized by the inclusion of capitalists into the membership of a
supposedly
proletariat revolutionary party; rampant official corruption that has
become
structural; and until recently, deliberate policy neglect of the rural
peasantry. While none of these have so
far reached crisis proportions, the experience of the KMT shows that
such
problems can accelerate to crisis proportions surprisingly quickly if
left
unattended under a rug of false prosperity.
US propaganda tries to create a false impression that
communism is popularly opposed in China by a majority of
freedom-starved people
who are congenitally antagonistic towards big government. This
propaganda
describes a China that exists only in the wishful Western mind. The
historical
fact is that in China, the masses always look to a strong central
government to
protect them from abuse of power at the local level.
Notwithstanding US propaganda, communism has
not been arbitrarily imposed on the vast nation by force by a
dictatorial
minority but has been welcomed by the peasant masses that constitute
over 80%
of the population because communism provides practical solutions to
their real
problems. Communism is opposed in China only by a minority bourgeoisie
and a
foreign-influenced comprador class. At long last, the newest generation
of
Chinese leadership is finally taking measures to reverse the
two-decade-long
policy neglect of the welfare of the peasant masses. History has shown
such
neglect to be politically cancerous without fail.
The Land Reform
Movement of 1950-53
The slogan: “Land to Every Tiller” (geng ze yu qi tien) came
from KMT leader Dr. Sun Yat-sun as a key revolutionary slogan of the
Nationalist revolution of 1911. It was adopted by the Communist Party
of China
(CPC) in the Chinese Soviet period in the early 1930s in South China
where the
CPC started to institute a program of equal distribution of land among
the
peasantry. This populist policy cemented
the backbone of popular support for the CPC. After the 1937 War Against
Japanese Aggression ended in 1946, the CPC began to rearrange the
pattern of
farm land ownership in the areas it controlled immediately after
Japanese
surrender, distributing all lands dispossessed from big landlords to
destitute
landless peasants, tenant farmers and rural workers. This land reform
program
won the overwhelming support of the land-hungry peasants and was
fundamental in
the CPC’s final victory in the pursuing civil war against the KMT.
With the establishment of the People’s Republic in 1949, the
CPC immediately set about a nation-wide, all-embracing redistribution
of
agricultural land with three aims: equality; permanent elimination of
counter-revolutionary opposition; and mobilization for mass movement
for
national reconstruction.
The Land Reform Law
decreed in 1949 by the provisional Central Government Administrative
Council
provided the legislative foundation by which the rural population was
classified into five categories: landlords, rich peasants, middle
peasants,
poor peasants, tenants and rural workers. The classification criteria
differed
from region to region in response to socio-economic traditions and
geographical
variations. There was considerable on-the-spot circumstantial
adjustment and
creative interpretation in sorting out the categories, as rigid class
distinction of social groups existed more in the Chinese cultural
consciousness
than reality. However, the
categorization, imperfect and unwittingly inequitable as it was in many
cases,
served the revolutionary purpose of identifying potential reactionary
forces of
political resistance.
Deng Zihui, the senior cadre in charge of the land reform
movement, who later became Minister of Agriculture, wrote on December
28, 1950
in the People’s Daily: “Land reform is the most fundamental struggle
against
the feudal system … … to regard it as a technical affair, namely the
redistribution
of land, would be a grave political mistake; for the feudal system can
be
removed only by the complete extermination of the landlord class
through a
number of military, intellectual and economic confrontations,”
The land reform of 1950 redistributed almost 50 million
hectares, about 40% of cultivated land of the nation at the time. It
solved the
inequality problem in society but it did not solve the technical
production
problems of China’s antiquated and inefficient agriculture in the
economy which
had reached its operative optimum when the population it supported was
not more
than 100 million. It soon became clear that land reform needed to be
accompanied by social reform to initiate agriculture collectivization
towards
“socialist transformation”.
Social reform began with a movement of marriage reform to
secure the emancipation of women, to prohibit marriages arranged by
parents to
liberate the young generation for modern life and to break down the
residual
feudal family clan system. The new Civil
Laws proclaimed by the KMT government after the 1911 bourgeois
revolution had
forbidden polygamy, but had continued to allow the feudal custom of
second
wives and concubines to remain. This feudal practice was terminated by
the new
Marriage Law of the People’s Republic.
To solve the agricultural production problem,
collectivization was necessary to assembly larger tracts of farmland
needed for
mechanization and to pool financial resources to buy farm machinery and
build
support facilities and related infrastructure. This practical necessity
was in
line with the aim of the transformation of the “national, bourgeois
democratic
revolution” of Dr. Sun Yatsen to the “socialist revolution led by the
dictatorship of the proletariat”, the property-less class.
On October 1, 1953, four years after the founding of the
People’s Republic and with initial success of the land and marriage
reform
programs behind it, a new “General Line of Socialist Transformation”
was
proclaimed after having been discussed democratically in two National
Work
Conferences on economic and organization issues three months earlier. By the summer of 1953, it became clear that
land reform alone could neither guarantee adequate food supply to the
nation,
particularly the heavily populated cities, nor to provide sufficient
savings
and investment for national industrialization, not even farm
mechanization.
Peasants understandably but thoughtlessly preferred to sell their
produce to
inflation-causing speculators in the open market at momentary higher
prices
rather than to price-stabilizing government farm administration, not
realizing
that volatile speculative high prices would cause a general collapse of
farm
prices in the long run because it drains wealth from the farming sector
into
the financial sector through the manipulation of market prices. Tax
evasion was
rampant through unreported transactions in the private markets.
Collectivization was not just a theoretical aim, it was a practical
necessity.
Land Reform in
Chinese History
Land reform has been a fundamental socio-political movement
throughout Chinese history. The 4th and 3rd centuries
BC
were a period of rapid economic development and technical innovation in
China
when the central and southwestern plains came under continuous
cultivation
through extensive land clearing encouraged by various political
regimes. A
proficient husbandry developed allowing the use of manure as
fertilizer,
differentiating of soil types for different crops, incorporating plough
and
sowing dates into the calendar, use of drainage to drying out marshy
regions
and detoxifying salty terrains and using irrigation to bring new arid
land into
cultivation. These collective undertakings were all deliberate policies
of
agricultural development promoted by rulers of petty kingdoms to
competitively
enhance the wealth and power of the state. State
control of agriculture, the
indispensable source of food supply,
has been the foundation of Chinese civilization, not markets.
Socialistic
statism is a founding principle of Chinese political culture, just as
Jeffersonian representative democracy is for US political culture.
Market fundamentalism, which even in the US has been a
creature of the state, is the very antithesis of four millennia of
recorded socio-economic
history in Chinese civilization. Even then, statism in agriculture is
operative
in all modern nations in the world today. US insistence on China to
adopt
market economy is nothing but cultural imperialism and US assertion
that market
fundamentalism is the most efficient economic arrangement is merely a
sign of
conceptual narrow-mindedness that comes from self deception and
ignorance of
history, if not disingenuous self-service. Market fundamentalism can
perform
efficiently only if the state sets rules to allow it to do so. Without
state
regulation, market fundamentalism degenerates into failed markets
quickly
through the natural concentration of market power.
Karl Polanyi’s Origins of
Our Time: The Great Transformation (1945) points out that the
modern
world’s market economy was of very recent origin and had emerged fully
formed
only as recently as the 19th century, in conjunction with capitalistic
industrialization which is also a development of state policy. The
current
globalization of markets following the fall of the Soviet bloc is also
of
recent post-Cold War origin, in conjunction with the advent of the
information
age and finance capitalism, all creatures of the state. Prior to the
coming of
capitalistic industrialization, the market played only a minor part in
the
economic life of societies. Even where market places could be seen to
be
operating, they were peripheral to the main economic organization and
activity
of society. Polanyi argued that in modern market economies, the needs
of the
market determined social behavior, whereas in pre-industrial and
primitive
economies the needs of society determined economic behavior. Polanyi
reintroduced social concepts of reciprocity and redistribution in human
relationships.
Reciprocity implies that people produce the goods and services they are
best at
producing, and share them with others with joy rather than for
financial
profit. This is reciprocated by others who are good at producing other
goods
and services. There is an unspoken agreement that all would produce
that which
they could do best and mutually share and share alike, not just sold to
the
highest bidder. All find their fulfillment in separate productive
livelihoods.
The motivation to produce and share is not personal profit, but
personal
fulfillment, and avoidance of social contempt, ostracism, and loss of
social
prestige and standing. This was the historical experience in China
until the
arrival of Western imperialism to proselytize mercantilism, a
controlled form
of trade imposed by a foreign state of superior power in the name of
free
market.
Shang Yang (died 338 BC) of the Kingdom of Qin in the Warring
States period (408-221 BC) built the state’s legal system based on the Book of Law, introduced a legalist
government in the midst of Confucian culture and propelled the Qin
state to
prosperity that enabled it to unite all of China, ushering in the Qin
Dynasty
(221-206 BC). He introduced a new, standardized system of land
allocation,
reformed taxation, encouraged the cultivation of new frontiers and
favored
agriculture over commerce, all implemented with state action. Shang
Yang burned
books by Confucians in an effort to curb the conservative philosophy’s
pervasive and undesirable influence against change. Shang Yang was
credited by
Han Fei-zi with putting forth two precepts: Ding Fa (fixing
legal
standards) and Yi Min (all people as one). Han Fei was a prince
of the
state of Han who joined the state of Qin, but eventually he became a
victim of
deductive conflict of loyalty and was granted the princely privilege of
committing
suicide in 233 BC by Qin Prime Minister, Li Si (died 208 BC), as
Socrates was
by an Athenian court for similar thought crimes. In
reaction to a Qin edict to deport
immigrants, Li Si wrote Advice Against Driving Away Guest Immigrants
(Jian Zhu Ke Shu) by arguing that the expulsion of immigrant only
enriches and
strengthens foreign countries. Members of the US Congress can benefit
from
reading Li Si’s treatise at this time of anti-immigrant hysteria.
In Chinese history, merchants have never been celebrated as
important figures of society, reflecting the social and cultural
distain
accorded to the market and its participants. In contrast to the US, in
Chinese
cultural awareness there is no equivalent to the likes of Morgan,
Rockefeller or
Mellon, robber barons of the market. To call a person a merchant is an
insult
in China even today. Hydraulic engineers who successfully controlled
flood and
improved irrigation, not rich merchants who gained wealth from trade,
were
national heroes and their names were recorded in official
historiography: such
as Xi Zi in the Wei Kingdom and Li Ping and his son Cheng Guo in the
Qin
Kingdom.
The primitive state of agriculture and transportation of the
Chun-Qiu/Jian-Guo (Spring-Autumn/Warring-States) period (770-226 BC)
could not
support large population centers of high density. The
3rd century text by Han Fei
referred to a large increase in population in the country that
continued during
the Han dynasty (206 BC-220 AD), which provided the earliest official
census in
Chinese history, recording 57,617,400 taxable individuals in the year 2
AD.
This population increase was directly related to improvements in
farming.
Sui and Tang Dynasties
Land Reform
In the 8th century, the height of
the Tang
dynasty (618-907), China’s population centroid shifted from the Wei
valley and
the central plains, where it had remained relatively fixed since
Neolithic
times, towards the plains of the lower Yangtse basin due to the
adoption of wet
rice cultivation in the south. The population south of the Yangtse
River
tripled from 3 million taxable individuals to 10 million between the
years 600
to 742 during the Sui dynasty (581-618) and the first part of the Tang
dynasty,
about one fifth of the total 50-million population.
The 900-kilometer-long Grand Canal was built
by the first Sui dynasty emperor linking Luoyang and Huai-an near the
sea coast
in modern-day Jiangsu province and connecting Huai-an with the Yangtze
River in
the south. An annual volume of 5 million bushels of rice was
transported by
barge to the north to overcome recurring food shortage previously
suffered by
the arid north. Luxury goods were also part of the freight traffic.
Song
dynasty conservative historian Sima Guang described in his famous work:
Integrated Political History (Zi Zhi
Tong Jian, 1066) that fresh abalones, a delicacy in Chinese haute
cuisine, were
captured alive from the Yellow Sea and sent up to Changan from Jiangdu
via the
Grand Canal. Five barrels of sea water had to be stored on board
transport
barges to keep just 500 abalones alive for the month-and-a-half journey.
Exploiting the prosperity created by 19 years of sagacious
rule of the first emperor, the second ruling Flaming Emperor (Yangdi)
of the
Sui dynasty that preceded Tang embarked on an ambitious program of
spectacular
construction and expeditionary military campaigns. The legendary
excesses of
the Flaming Emperor would be identified by future Confucian historians
as a
direct cause for his abrupt loss of the Mandate of Heaven (Tianming)
after only
a relatively brief reign of 12 years.
For example, the reconstruction and expansion of Luoyang and
its ancient palace had required two million conscript workers. Another million workers had been mobilized to
construct a 900-hundred-kilometer-long Grand Canal. The original aim
had been
to make it possible, upon completion of the canal, to ship grain from
the south
to the arid north. But the Flaming Emperor soon used the canal for him
and his
court to travel from Luoyang, his new capital 330 kilometers to the
east of ancient
Changan, to the then most prosperous commercial city in the land,
Jiangdu, 100
kilometers east of modern-day Nanjing. Newly
designed imperial dragon barges for this
purpose had been on order
from the southern provinces at great expense.
Along the 900-kilometer-long canal route, more than 40
luxurious palaces were built as resting places on route at points of
scenic
beauty. Known as departure palaces
(ligong), they were built according to the latest design trend, of
grand proportions
and fine material, and decorated by celebrated painters and master
sculptors of
wood and stone. Concurrent with these major projects, construction of
the famous
West Villa (Xiyuan) was ordered by the Flaming Emperor on the western
outskirts
of Luoyang,. West Villa occupied a site measuring 100 square kilometers. Within this large site, 5 square kilometers
were
devoted to a series of man-made lakes of artful shapes.
Artificial mountains were formed by the
excavated earth. On these miniature
mountains
were studded with delightfully-sited pavilions high above the
monotonous, flat
landscape of the plains of central China where Luoyang is situated.
A private canal connected the string of man-made lakes of
West Villa to the city of Luoyang via the Luo river from which Luoyang
received
its name and much of its charm since the beginning of civilization.
Along the
private canal, between West Villa and Luoyang Palace in the imperial
capital, 16
royal palaces were built, known as the Sixteen Estates (Shiliu Yuan). Each estate housed three hundred court
beauties in a network of exquisite pavilions, luxuriously furnished, as
a
mortal’s make-believe paradise.
Imperial outings were frequently organized by the Flaming
Emperor of the Sui dynasty on the private canal around West Villa
(Xiyuan),
with the imperial entourage numbering several thousands, often in the
evening
to enjoy the full moon, especially in autumn. The
peripheral ranked aristocrats rode along
both banks of the canal on
horseback and in open carriages, lit by hundreds of lanterns. Waving enthusiastically, they provided a
moving stage of choreographed excitement for the royal inner circle,
whose
members enjoyed the spectacles on shore from well-lit imperial barges
of dragon
motif. The royals themselves, in turn,
formed the centerpiece of a real-life opera, with music and incense
filling the
air, and with laughter, shouts of poetic riddle games and expressions
of sycophantic
flattery mingling joyously.
Occasionally, firework displays were presented, viewed by an
audience of up to 18,000 invited guests. The
sounds and lights were visible from
several kilometers away, to the
delight of the local populace.
To project an image of absolute imperial power, the Flaming
Emperor of the Sui dynasty took on the role of a vigorous patron of the
performing arts. He ordered the
construction
of grand facilities for circus performances, staged with hundreds of
exotic
animals from all parts of the immense empire. Theaters
with orchestras of 300 musicians were
built, presenting operas
using male singers dressed in women's costumes, a practice that would
survive
to the present time in traditional Chinese opera and Japanese Kabuki
theater.
Street festivals were periodically organized with performers
numbering over 30,000 parading a route two kilometers long, with the
audience
seated on viewing stands lining both sides of the parade route. To meet rising popular demand for public
entertainment, the court established a school for musicians, training
30,000
professionals to support frequent, court-sponsored ceremonial events
and
festivals in Luoyang, new imperial capital of the soon-to-fall Sui
dynasty.
With completion of the Grand Canal, the Flaming Emperor,
before his precipitous downfall, embarked frequently by barge from
Luoyang to
enjoy his tours of Jiangdong, a resort region in the Yangtze delta
located 1,000
kilometers southeast.
The main imperial dragon barge used by the Flaming Emperor consisted
of four attached sections totaling 2,000 feet in length, with a height
of 45
feet above water. The front section
consisted of the main imperial room, the inner imperial room, and the
east and
west rooms. The middle two sections
housed one hundred and twenty imperial cabins, all elaborately
decorated with
gold and jade. The back section housed
imperial household servants and support facilities. The empress
(huanghou)
traveled on her own phoenix barge, smaller than the Flaming Emperor's
imperial
dragon barge, but equally elegantly decorated, though appropriately
subdue.
The imperial dragon barge, surrounded by nine floating
scenery barges in three sections, formed the lead of a fleet of several
thousand other court barges, housing members of hougong
(rear palace), the sovereign's personal household, composed
of imperial concubines (huangfei) and palace eunuchs (huanguan). Still other barges followed, housing the
princes, the princesses, ministers, Buddhist monks (seng), Buddhist
nuns (nigu),
Daoist priests (daoshi), Daoist priestesses (nuguan) and distinguished
foreign
guests and envoys, including exhibition barges showcasing tribunal
gifts from
foreign lands.
On upstream return trips, the whole imperial flotilla was
towed by a force of 80,000 men dressed in special tow-gang uniforms, in
formations that were distributed with military precision and
engineering
balance along both banks of the Grand Canal.
Adding to the imperial flotilla were several thousands more
military barges for the Imperial Guards. The
whole imperial fleet routinely numbered
over 10,000 barges, stretching
over several kilometer, disrupting commercial barge traffic, the
accommodation
of which the costly Grand Canal construction program was originally
intended
morally and justified economically.
Cavalry formations in ceremonial armor galloped along both
banks of the Grand Canal, with imperial flags and regimental standards
fluttering in the wind for as far ahead as the eye could see. It was a most impressive sight, reinforced by
heart-pounding military drums and exhilarating imperial bugles
announcing in
advance the pending arrival of imperial presence.
Food and wine were provided to the imperial flotilla by
local administrative units within 100 kilometers on either side of the
Grand
Canal, each vying for imperial attention by providing the best of local
cuisine
and specialty produce to both the moving fleet and the 40 departure
palaces (li
gong) en route.
Such regal pleasure, described admiringly in detail in Song
dynasty neo-Confucian conservative historian Sima Guang’s famous work: Integrated Political History, was meant
to symbolized the absolute power of the state, personified in the
Emperor. To
Sima Guang, such glory justifies the bloody treachery of high politics
as
worthy of princely pursuit, self-restraint as ordained by Confucian
ethics notwithstanding,
not to mention the heavy burden of the peasant masses.
Two other major construction projects also contributed to
the dubious fame of the late Flaming Emperor (Yangdi) of the Sui
dynasty. The
first was a network of highways with a standard width of 50 feet to
accommodate
unobstructed two-way chariot traffic. Its
main arterial was a 4,000 kilometer route
running from Zhuojun,
modern-day Beijing, westward to the garrison town of Yulin in the west,
where
the construction of a new section of the Great Wall extension had taken
place. The highway ended at Yutian,
modern-day Hetian (Khotan), in the Tarim Basin in the far west. The
second
project involved a system of grain storing garrisons.
The garrisons, each with enclosure walls
running 100 kilometer in total length, and boasting 3,000 grain silos
guarded
by 1,000 troops, were designed to facilitate rapid deployment of troops
in war
and to provide food reserve for the populace in peace. The exorbitant
cost of
all these projects fell mostly on the peasants and the resultant
discontent
contributed to the abrupt fall of the Sui dynasty.
Land reform in the Tang dynasty aimed at correcting the wasteful
ways of the second Sui emperor to provide each family with enough land
to
support itself and to establish an empire-wide agricultural system that
would
ensure the regularity of tax revenue and social stability. The
provision of the
means of livelihood for every family, the equivalent of full employment
in the
modern market economy, was guaranteed by the government through equal
distribution
of public land. Unlike the modern market economy where structural
unemployment
was maintained by central bank monetary policy to combat inflation, the
traditional Chinese economy considered full employment an undeniable
responsibility of the state.
In Tang time, land was distributed equally as annuities to
be held only for the lifetime of the recipient. Taxes were levied not
according
to property size but to population count. For every able-body
individual, the
state imposed a tax called zu payable
in cereal. There was also a system of corvée called yung
and a tax paid in cloth named tiao.
The founding emperor
of the Tang dynasty adopted the populist policies that had begun by the
first
emperor of the preceding Sui dynasty. The Sui ruler upon gaining power
opened
state land reserves to the landless, distributed 5,000 buffalos from
government
lots free to impoverished farmers to restore production, forbade the
military
to draft men under the age of twenty-one, reduced the annual tax burden
on
farmers by as much as 80%, shared with the common people revenues from
state
monopolies on wine and salt, exempted the elderly, those over fifty,
from taxes
and reduced the state’s take from farm harvests by one third. A central bureaucracy was established and
staffed with literati selected on merit through public examinations. Within a few years of these populist policies,
the Sui economy recovered totally from three centuries of war and
destruction
and grew with unprecedented prosperity, with state grain reserve
sufficient for
feeding the nation for the next sixty years. Yet all this was frittered
away by
the second Sui emperor’s extravagance within two decades.
Cottage industries were always part of the Chinese
agricultural economy. Taxes on high population density regions with
small farm
plot were higher than that on larger farms with low population density. There was no financial incentive for the
average farmer to acquire more land than he could cultivate as he would
not be
able to find tenant farmers since every able-body farmer could claim
his own
land. The land pattern required regular meticulous census and
regulation on
personal mobility. In Tang China, the
Emperor held sovereign title to all land in the empire, and granted
land with
the population on it to meritorious aristocrats and approved clergies,
and also
directly to the general public individually who must cultivate it
himself.
Aristocrats were entitled to collect revenue from the farming
individuals
living on their lands. Aristocrats in turn must pay a commission on
their
revenue to the imperial house unless specifically exempt.
In areas of historically high population density, or even in
fringe areas that through the influx of immigrants experienced sharply
increased
population over relatively short periods, a continuous redistribution
of public
land has become operationally impracticable. Furthermore,
the Equal Field System (Juntian
Zhi) was tied to the Tax
Laws of Rent, Corvée and Cloth (Zu Yong Tiao Fa) of the 2nd year
the Reign of
Martial Virtue (Wu'de), proclaimed in 619. It
was principally a poll tax with no direct
relationship to land,
except the implicit equality in universal land-allotment to able-body
males.
Under the Tax Laws, taxes were regularly required of the
population in 3 forms: rent, paid in the form of grain (zu), labor or
corvée
(yong) in kind and cloth (tiao). Cloth
was frequently used as a form of common currency during Tang time. Each able-body male age 21 to 60 was required
to pay an annual rent of 2 piculs (266.6 lbs) of grain, 70 yards each
of
damask, brocade and silk, or 300 yards of cotton cloth, plus 20 days of
labor. If labor was not provided or not
required, an additional 1 yard of each type of cloth is taxed for each
day of
grace. Labor worked in excess of the
normal 20 days earned credit against other taxes: 5 days earning an
exemption
from cloth payments and 10 days earning exemptions from both payments
in grain
and cloth. A maximum credit of 50 days
of labor was permitted after which direct cash compensation must be
paid by the
government to the laborer.
A special tax called Miscellaneous Labor (Zayao) was levied
under exceptional circumstances, such as defense construction or major
public
projects. Generally, a sovereign who
decrees Miscellaneous Labor too frequently would run the risk of being
labeled
immoral by Confucians at his own peril. Such
a label would expose the sovereign to the
danger of having the
Mandate of Heaven (Tian-ming) taken from him forcibly by ambitious
aristocrats
poised to readily exploit the dissatisfaction of the people.
Taxes were collected from the family as a unit and not from
individuals, but the rate is applied to the number of able-body males
in the
household, excluding servants and slaves. Imperial
family members (huangshi) and
aristocrats (guizu) were exempted
from taxes on their private estate and on the income from their fengwu
(fief),
as were families of meritorious ministers (gongchen).
Commoners (sheren) beyond the age of 80 and
in poor health are granted 1 male helper at state expense, beyond age
90, 2
helpers and beyond 100, 3 helpers. There
are, unfortunately, not too many of those in Tang society, given a low
average
life expectancy in the 7th century.
Peasant families within a fengwu (fief) pay two thirds of
their taxes to their local lords, with one third of the payments
reserved for
the Emperor, the Son of Heaven, whose agents do all the collecting. Labor or corvée can be substituted by
grain
or cloth, and sometimes by coins, which were in constant short supply. Hereditary fiefs were called shifeng (solid
grants) and nonhereditary grants are called sifeng (consumable grants).
Despite increasingly uneven shifting of geographical
distribution of the population, the poll tax remains geared to the
ideal,
though increasingly fictitious, system of equal land allotment. As a result, many families over time fell
into dire circumstances, unable to pay their taxes because they had not
received their allotment of land at locations of their preference. As
the
population became more mobile due to structural changes in the economy
as well
as new socio-political developments, the resultant disorder in tax
collection
eventually reached the point where reform would become critically
necessary. It was in this agitating
climate for tax reform
that political pressure was created in mid-7th century Tang China for a
ruler
who had little connection to traditional, vested feudal interests. That ruler was Wu Ze-tian, a 53-year-old
woman of merchant roots, known as Heaven Empress (Tainhou), and later
became
the only female emperor in Chinese history.
In 780, 162 years after the founding of Tang dynasty, about
midway through its 289-year history, the Duo Tax system (Liang Shui Fa)
was
introduced which levied taxes twice a year in the 6th and the 11th
lunar
months. It would be a land tax,
proportional to acreage held by each land owner.
Henceforth, with replacement of the traditional poll tax by
a land tax, the imperial government would lose interest in limiting the
size of
land holdings. Fiscal incentive for
official opposition to formation of large estates would then evaporate. In fact, large estates would then be preferred
by the central imperial authority because such estates would allow more
efficient
collection of taxes.
The growth of a system of big non-aristocratic landlords
would be ensured when tax becomes based on land rather than on
population, and
state revenue would not be threatened by the concentration of large
land
holdings within any one family, provided the family did not enjoy tax
exemption.
Moreover, a land tax would place an indirect tax on
previously non-tax-paying servants and slaves, because of the direct
relationship between land productivity and manpower needs.
It would also provide financial incentives
for the efficient use of land. Under this
tax regime, the land-owning merchant class prospered and grew as a
political
force in Tang society, even if it continued to suffer traditional
social
stigma.
As government appetite for additional revenue increases,
state monopoly of production and sale of important commodities,
beginning with
salt, and later to include wine, iron and bronze, were re-instituted.
Tea
drinking became popular in Tang time and eventually tea also becomes a
state-monopolized commodity. The British had the same idea which led
them to
impose a salt monopoly on British India in 1929, against which Gandhi
organized
a satyagraha, a campaign of civil
disobedience expressed in the form of nonviolent, passive resistance to
unjust
laws. In France, high tax on salt emerged as one of the underlining
causes of
the French Revolution. The salt-works at
Arc-et-Senans and the custom barrières ringing Paris at which
tolls on salt and
other commodity were collected, became symbols of oppression. Even the architect of the salt-works and
custom barrières, Claude-Nicolas Ledoux (1735-1806), would be
imprisoned after
the revolution for his role in the design of the oppressive facilities.
Salt
had been used as currency in ancient societies and men had been known
to have sold
their family members into slavery for it.
Sung Dynasty
Socialism
The
11th century was a watershed of political and social reform
in
China. The reform movement of the Sung dynasty (960-1279), though
inseparable
from ideology and philosophy of its time, was motivated by historical
contingencies that presented themselves as clear and present danger to
the
state. The successes of northern barbarian invasions from the Liao and
Xia
tribes caused thinking men in Sung society to question and seek
remedies to the
deficiencies in the established national culture that had resulted in
an
ineffective defense system. They critically examined existing
institutions in
society and the organization of the state within the socio-economic and
political context of the time. While the Chinese state had always
drifted
towards centralism, the responsibility of national policy always
resided in a
State Council with decentralized representation. In the Sung dynasty,
the State
Council consisted of five to nine members chaired by the Emperor.
Councilors
are responsible for presenting the varied views of different
constituents of
society. On every policy issue, the
Council heard the opinion of every councilor representing diverse
interests,
with the Emperor only ratifying the majority council decision or
casting a
tie-breaking vote. The Emperor’s authority was moral rather than
political.
This State Council system continues today, chaired by the Prime
Minister,
reporting to the politburo chaired by the President of the Republic and
Chairman of the Communist Party.
The
emergence of a market economy during Sung time resulted in a widening
disparity
of income and wealth beginning around the 11th century. A
new class
of rentiers came into existence and
grew larger to overwhelm the ancient aristocracy whose privileged
station came
from past martial feats. The rentiers
lived handsomely off the rent from their land. The wealth and leisure
associated with unearned income gave rise to new generations of men who
were
learned of the classics and who delighted in philosophical musing,
wrote essays
on political theory and became active in the appreciation and making of
the
arts, but who were economic parasites whose estates increasingly
escaped taxes,
while the tax burden fell increasingly heavy on small farmers, tenant
farmers
and landless laborers. Sung culture flourished among the elite while
Sung
society slid into decline.
By mid-11th
century, a new meritocracy was changing the socio-political balance
within the Sung
ruling class away from the traditional hold of the ancient aristocracy.
Prior
to the Sung dynasty, from the Han to Tang dynasties, the aristocrats
formed a
close clique that jealously guarded their genealogies.
They could often preserve their social
privileges to survive the rise and fall of dynasties as long as they
were
willing to shift political loyalty to the new regime. But the ancient
aristocrats were frugal compared to the free-spending luxurious
life-style of
the new rentiers who began to siphon
off larger and larger shares of the national wealth for their own
conspicuous consumption.
Still, the new meritocracy inevitably produced reform-minded thinkers
among the
elite whose sense of moral propriety trumped the selfish interests of
their own
class. And the apprehension of external
threats to the state created a receptive climate for the social reform
movements.
The
gradual collapse of the system of allocating land only for life began
in the 8th
century at the height of the Tang dynasty, with the transfer of taxes
onto
cultivated land rather than on individuals of working age. This meant
that
land-use rights could be sold by a farmer’s estate or be forfeited from
failed
farmers or those who defaulted on their monetary debts, producing a new
group
of landless peasants amid an economy of rising land prices. Land
leaseholds
became a commodity that could be traded in the market and investors
could buy
land to be farmed by landless tenant farmers for profit and to
speculate on a
rising land market. By Sung time, this land market had created a
economy of
severe disparity.
The
increase in rice production also brought profound changes in the
economy
through the growth of commerce in surplus agricultural produce and arts
and
craft products. The profit became concentrated in the hands of large
land
owners rather the dispersed throughout the farming population. The
surplus farm
labor energized the arts and crafts with apprentices.
The production of porcelain reached
perfection in the 12th century and spilled over from
imperial kilns
that produced exclusively for the imperial household to quality
commercial
kilns that produced for the aristocrats and a wealthy urban
bourgeoisie. Big
commercial conglomerates were formed from dealing in surplus grain and
consolidating small crafts cottage industries into large factories in
specialized factory towns, such as Jingdezhen for porcleain.
The
mercenary army also siphoned off surplus labor from small farms as
large
estates and monastery compounds encroached on them. Absentee landlord
families
lived in luxury in the imperial capital or provincial capitals and
towns,
enjoying the wealth produced in their rural estates by tenant farmers
and wage
earners while the landlords escaped taxes. This led to a new kind of
urbanization where cities became good places to spend money rather than
to earn
it, except for the service sector which must follow where the money was
being
spent. Busy trading towns multiplied in all parts of the empire.
Foreign trade
with imports of exotic goods such as incense, rare gems, ivory, coral,
rhino
horns, ebony, sandalwood, etc, produced a deficit for the Sung treasury
which
had to be paid in copper, sliver or gold coins. Sung
copper coins were so abundant in Japan
that it was accepted as
local currency.
The
principal wealth of the economy came increasingly from craft
manufacturing and
commerce with agriculture as a supporting base. Printed books also
became a
major trade. With trade came a monetary economy with the rise of
credit. The
supply of metal coins could not keep up with the expansion of commerce
and the
world first paper money was issue by the Sung authorities in 1024 and
quickly
spread throughout the entire economy. Bills
of exchange, known as “flying money”
(fei-qian), were received by
merchants at points of sale some distance from home, with which they
could exchange
back into coins after a safe journey back home.
Intellectual
flowering in art and science, philosophy and ethics, literature and
poetry,
history and archaeology, astronomy and cosmology, came from this new
material
prosperity out of which a naturalist philosophy emerged to fuse into
unity
nature and humanity. It was a philosophy of optimism based on a belief
in
universal reason, in the promise of education, in the possibility to
improving
society and politics through the primacy of mind, while discounting
practical
knowledge and physical power. Some
historians identify this purist philosophy of anti-materialism as the
cause of
the decline of the Sung dynasty, and as the reason why China fell
behind the
West in science and technology after the 17th century.
Sung
dynasty was a bifurcated society with culture and philosophy
flourishing at the
wealthy top and misery and resentment simmering at the bottom. But the
unhappy
situation at the bottom was not well acknowledged by history as little
written
record of it survived compared to the voluminous record of high culture
and
art. The agricultural economy simply could not sustain indefinitely an
economy
in which 20% of the populations were unproductive officials and
literati, with
5% of population owning 90% of the land and wealth and living in luxury
while
the rest of the population drifting toward subsistence.
As
the Sung dynasty came under imminent external threat from the Northern
barbarians, the state began to look to reform as a survival strategy. The most celebrated reformer was
neo-Confucian Wang Anshi (1201-86) who has since been credited by
historians
with reintroducing state socialism beyond historical natural socialism
into
Chinese society.
Henry
A. Wallace, as US Secretary of Agriculture during the Roosevelt
administration,
adopted Wang’s idea of subsidized farm credit and price guarantee and
applied
them to New Deal programs during the great Depression of the 1930s.
Wallace, a
liberal Republican turned Democrat, later became Franklin D.
Roosevelt’s 3rd-term
Vice President but was replaced by Harry Truman in FDR’s 4th
term as
a result of conservative opposition domestic and foreign, including
Winston
Churchill who complained of Wallace’s being soft on communism. Had
Wallace been
still Vive President when FDR died in office in his fourth term, Henry
Wallace
would have been president in place of Harry Truman, and no atomic bombs
would
have been dropped on Japan and the Cold War might have been avoided.
Wang’s Green Sprout Money Law and Market Law were pioneer
programs of state farm credit and price subsidy that constituted
Chinese state
socialism which grew out of an ideology of equalitarianism and social
justice
beyond the utilitarian social hierarchy of Confucianism. Antagonistic
to
despotism and believing in the need for a regulatory regime to protect
social
justice for the weak and powerless, Wang saw heavy tax and
corvée burdens
concentrated on farmers as the structural weaknesses of the state’s
fiscal
difficulties. He believed that equalizing the tax burden on all
socio-economic
classes according to their ability to carry would strengthen the state
financially. Regulation against usury
and loan-sharking and trade monopolies would also strengthen the
economy which
in turn would increase tax revenue. Between
1069 and 1076, Wang initiated major
economic reforms in the
interest of small farmers, artisans and tradesmen, including reduced
interest
rates, commutation of labor services to the state, price stabilizing
measures
and land taxes. He also set up state financial planning, reduced the
professional army, built up a cavalry militia, and carried out a wide
range of
educational reforms to equalized opportunities for the rural poor.
By giving low-interest government loans to farmers to reduce
their debt burden, Wang reduced the number of destitute families who
would
otherwise become a threat to society and a burden for the state.
Farmers would
continue to pay their taxes and to make improvements in productivity if
they
were not constantly in fear of losing everything to their creditors. An
updating of the tax registers to increase revenue prevented corrupt
officials
from pocketing unregistered taxes they collected. Population was rising
but not
all were duly recorded on the registers to be officially liable for
taxes. The
Treasury profited from a new census that allowed collection of taxes
from all
to prevent corrupt officials from only passing on the amount stipulated
in the
out-of-date registers while keeping the surplus collection from
non-registered
farmers for themselves. Taxes in kind were translated into money taxes.
This
encouraged trade because farmers needed to sell some of what they
produced to
get cash to pay their dues. Trade was also taxed so government revenue
benefited twice over.
Wang’s reforms were opposed
by conservative Neo-Confucian Sima Guang (1019-86) who represented the
interests of big land owners
and their entourage of sponsored conservative historians, literati and
social
philosophers. Wang Anshi and Sima Guang, personal
friends, were
supported by opposing factions within the bureaucracy that competed for
the
emperor’s attention. Factional politics were conducted by means of
writing memoranda
to the throne, presenting arguments for and against particular ideas,
policies
and people. The officials in charge of presenting a summary of all key
memoranda were accordingly very powerful in policy formation. This
method of
conducting politics is ironically indispensably valuable to historians
because
many of the memoranda survive to posterity, preserving a written record
of the
policy debates.
Opposed by the big landowners, Wang’s reforms were rescinded
after Sung Emperor Shenzhong’s death in 1076. Sung society thereafter
embarked
on a gradual decline with its anti-materialist optimism.
Another problem that beset the Sung economy
was the uneven development between the north and south regions with the
center
of economic activities shifting from the Yellow River (Huang He)
valley, the
cradle of Chinese civilization, towards the Yangtse River valley and
the
coastal regions. Still, the three great
inventions of Chinese civilization: printing, the compass and gunpowder
were
invented during the Sung dynasty.
Mongol Rule
During the time of Genghis Khan’s rule (1210-27), the
Mongols had no administrative institutions for ruling an empire. Unlike
the
Khitans and the Jurchens earlier, the Mongols did not benefit from
adopting
Chinese administrative art and institutions before they started their
territorial conquest although Genghis Khan benefited from Chinese
artillery
science in his military exploits. It was
only in the reign of Ogodei (1229-41) that the occupation of China was
completed and Chinese wealth and culture were exploited to solidify
Mongol rule
by Kublai Khan as the first emperor of the Yuan dynasty (1279-1363).
The
conquest of South China, the expedition against Japan, Burma, Vietnam
and Java
were organized by the Mongols with troops and resources raised in China
and
with Chinese fleets.
Yelu Zhuzai (1190-1244), a descendant of the Khitan Liao
dynasty (907-1125) and a minister of the Jurchen Jin dynasty that fell
to
Genghis Khan, demonstrated to Ogodei the benefits of an annual fiscal
system
and estimated that tax revenue could yield annually 500,000 ounces of
silver,
80,000 rolls of silk and over 20,000 tons of cereals in North China
alone. In 1229, an empire-wide postal
relay system
of pony express that had been established 6 centuries earlier during
the Tang
dynasty (618-907) was restored, a system of property taxes revived and
public
granaries rebuilt. An unfrocked Zen
Buddhist monk, Liu Ping-zhong (1216-74) advised Kublai Khan at
Karakorum in 1249
with famous Han dynasty adage: “One can conquer the world on horseback;
one
cannot govern it on horseback.”
The Mongol rulers adopted many of the institutions of Sung
state socialism which produced the prosperity that Marco Polo
(1254-1324) wrote
about glowingly. Unfortunately for the
Mongol imperial house, the socialist reforms of Wang Anshi adopted by
the first
Yuan emperor was reversed by the conservative neoclassical Confucians
ministers
and the Yuan dynasty fell after only 89 years of rule as a result while
the
Sung dynasty, benefiting from the residual effects of the reform
measures of
Wang Anshi, lasted 320 years.
Ming dynasty Land
Reform
The effort on land reform by the early rulers of the Ming
dynasty (1368-1644) which liberated China from Mongol rule was in many
ways
comparable to that of the People’s Republic in the 1950’s. In two
decades, Ming
reform achieved impressive targets in irrigation, land restoration,
reforestation and flood control. In 1395 alone, 40,987 reservoirs were
repaired
or built. Large areas were restored for cultivation and resettled by a
massive
transfer of population. In 1371, some 576,000 acres were reclaimed for
cultivation and in the next three years, a whooping additional 6
million acres
were restored, with 5 million acres alone in 1374.
Taxes in the form of grain tripled to one
million tons in 1393 compared to a third of a ton under Mongol
occupation. The most impressive
achievement was in
reforestation. Over 50 million sterculia trees, palm trees and vanish
trees
were planted in the Nanking region with a view of constructing a
high-seas
fleet that carried Moslem sailor Cheng He (1371-1433) in his famous
ocean expeditions. In 1392, each household
in Anhui province
were obliged to plant 200 mulberry trees to support the silk industry
and 200
persimmon trees. This obligation was
extended to the whole empire two years later. In 1396, over 84 million
fruit
trees were planted.
But the prosperity soon led to fiscal abuse. By the end of
the Wan-li reign in 1619 more than half of state revenue was devoted to
supporting the imperial court and its aristocratic entourage. The
rising state
deficit led to a sharp rise in taxation on the peasantry. By 1627, a
series of
bad harvest due to drought caused a serious famine and peasant revolts
were
setting the stage for recurring Jurchen attacks from Manchuria which
ended the
Ming dynasty in 1644 and ushered in the Qing dynasty (1644-1911).
Agricultural Policies
of the Qing Dynasty
Qing early policy of low taxes on peasants cemented popular
support among the majority Han Chinese for the new minority Manchu
dynasty and
disarmed residual Ming resistance fanned by early Qing atrocity and
wholesale
appropriation of peasant land after 1644. Beginning with the reign of
Kang-xi
(1661-1722), an agricultural policy favoring small farmers was
instituted.
Adequate salaries for officials reduced corruption in government.
Chinese agriculture
reached a high point of pre-industrial development in the 18th
century. Along with traditional crops such as wheat, barley, millet and
rise,
new crops such as sorghum (gao-liang), maize, sweet potato and ground
nut
allowed year-round harvest and bridged the winter gap as well as making
drier
soils productive. Vegetables and fruits became a regular part of the
national
diet and the rearing of pigs and poultry as well as advances in fish
farming
increased the protein intake in the population. Commercial crops such
as
cotton, tea, sugar cane expanded rapidly. Historian Jacque Gernet noted
in his A History of Chinese Civilization that
the Chinese peasant of the founding Yung-zheng reign (1723-36) and the
early
Qian-lung reign (1736-96) of the Qing dynasty were much better off and
more
content than their counterparts in the France of Louis XV, even better
educated
due to the proliferation of public and private schools that many
farmers could
afford for their children. Some great
Chinese literati of the 18th century came from humble farm
origins.
This was because Qing agricultural policy favored small farmers who
were
moderately taxed. A 1711 ordinance forbade any increases in tax quota
even as
population rose.
It was only in the final two decade of the Qian-lung reign
in the mid 1770s that the burden of an extravagant court and its
unproductive
aristocratic entourage re-imposed high taxes on the peasants and
rekindled
peasant rebellions. But while the Chinese peasant gradually fell into
aggregate
poverty, the finally collapse of the Qing economy was caused by the
advance of
Western imperialism through the illegal smuggle of opium into China,
paid for
by an outflow of silver. What is yet to be fully recognized by economic
historians is the adverse effect on the Chinese economy from the
massive
outward drain of silver from the illegal opium trade Britain and the US
imposed
on China as a result of the inability of the Qing state to regulate
illicit
trade in opium and, more importantly, free trade in silver. The
collapse of the
Qing economy in the 19th century was largely a monetary
event.
Silver had been used widely as currency in China since the
15th and 16th century with imports from the
Americas as a
result of Chinese trade surplus. Around 1564, Mexican silver coins
began
circulating widely in Chinese coastal trade towns such as Guangzhou and
Fuzhou
as payment for Chinese exports. The 19th
century reversal of China’s trade to deficit was due to Western opium
smuggling
between 1820 and 1825. This trade was
denominated in silver until China ran out of silver after which point
the
illicit trade was denominated in porcelain that steadily fell in price.
The outflow of sliver from China coincided with the collapse
of silver prices in the international market as Western economies
adopted the
gold standard. Silver was leaving China
in huge quantity while the price of silver was falling in the
international
market. Yet while the price of silver fell in the international market,
its
price rose in the Chinese domestic market, accelerating and
exacerbating real
trade inflation in the Chinese economy through domestic price deflation.
This monetary collapse inflicted great financial damage on
China’s poorest peasants. While peasant income was denominated in
copper coins,
their tax obligation to the state was denominated in silver coins
because the
state’s trade deficit was denominated in silver. The scarcity of sliver
created
by the massive outflow pushed domestic silver price sky-high in terms
of copper
coins. International bi-metalism greatly disadvantaged the Chinese
silver-based
export economy and domestic bi-metalism greatly disadvantaged the
copper-based
finances of the Chinese peasantry. China
suffered protracted economic recession all through the 19th
and 20th
centuries as it came into commercial contact with the Western
economies. This
two-century-long recession was the result of the structural monetary
disadvantage dual bi-metalism imposed on the Chinese silver-based
monetary
system and fatally wounded the Chinese economy. The
bankrupt economy reduced China to a
failing state unable to defend
itself from aggressive Western powers until the founding of the
People’s
Republic.
Next: Land Reform in
the People’s Republic |
|
|
|
|