Part III: The Fed’s
No-Exit Strategy This article appeared in AToL
on April 21, 2010
In Testimony before the Committee on Financial Services of
the House of Representatives in Washington, DC on February 10, 2010
regarding “Federal
Reserve’s Exit Strategy” from the extraordinary lending and monetary
policies
that it implemented to combat the financial crisis and support economic
activity, Chairman Ben S. Bernanke said that the Federal Reserve’s
response to
the crisis and the recession can be divided into two parts.
First, the financial system during the past two and a half
years has experienced periods of intense panic and dysfunction, during
which
private short-term funding became difficult or impossible to obtain for
many borrowers,
even those with good credit standing in normal times. The pulling back
of
private liquidity at times threatened the stability of major financial
institutions and markets and severely disrupted normal channels of
credit.
Yet Bernanke skirted over the fact that for several large
institutions, the liquidity crunch was inseparable from an insolvency
problem.
What these distressed institutions needed was more than a liquidity tie
over,
but an injection of capital.
In response, performing its role as liquidity provider of
last resort, the Federal Reserve developed a number of programs to
provide
supposedly well-secured, mostly short-term credit directly to the
financial
system. These programs, which Fed Chairman Bernanke alleged rather
simplistically
as imposing no cost on the taxpayer, were a critical part of the
government’s
efforts to stabilize the financial system and restart the flow of
credit.
As noted in Part II of this series, the tax exemption
granted distressed institutions had cost the Internal Revenue Service
tax
revenue in amounts that exceeded the estimated positive returns from
disposing
distress assets that the Treasury had acquired. Yet, the true cost of
Fed
intervention to the integrity of the market system cannot be fully
evaluated
until the unintended consequences surface years later. Free market
capitalism
may well be history after government intervention in this crisis as Fed
exit
strategy may never be completely carried out or Fed direct intervention
will be
expected in all future crises.
What Bernanke did not say in his testimony was that these
programs were not macro monetary measures addressed at the overall
capitalist
financial market system, but direct micro intervention into selected
wayward
distressed financial firms deemed to big to fail. The approach has set
a
pattern of fearlessness among gigantic financial institutions. Yet the
net
result of the government approach to the banking crisis is to impose of
the
market an oligarchy of a small number of large surviving banks.
The Fed was providing more than liquidity to the financial
system. It took over toxic assets from distress banks and bank-holding
companies which had ventured into the non-bank financial sector and the
shadow
banking sector. The Fed acted as the White Knight to save a market
failure in
the entire global debt securitization arena. The Fed took on the role
of
protector of miscreants from market disciplinary penalties, straying
from its
official mandate as protector of the faith on financial market
fundamentalism.
Economist Randall Wray wrote in the website of Roosevelt
Institute’s New Deal 2.0
Project:
But in those areas in
which the
government believes markets do work, there should never be any
intervention to
subvert market forces that want to punish miscreants. Treasury
Secretaries
Rubin, Paulson, and Geithner’s repeated claim that we cannot allow
market
forces to operate on the downside is logically nonsensical. Markets
cannot
work if downside risks are removed. In any area in which the
downside is
going to be socialized, the upside MUST also be socialized — that is,
removed
from the market. If the market is to work on the upside, it must be
allowed to
operate also on the downside.
What about systemic risk? Yes, if
government had allowed markets to operate as Bear and Lehman went down,
all of
the big financial institutions would also have been brought down. As
Bernanke
now apparently realizes, that would have been a good thing. The market
would
have accomplished what Bernanke now professes to desire: resolving the
problem
of “too big to fail”. We would have been left only with smallish
institutions —
those not too big to fail. And as [Roger] Lowenstein forcefully argues,
those
big financial institutions do very little that is desirable from a
public
purpose perspective. Whatever good they do accomplish can just as
easily be
done by small institutions or directly by government where the market
fails.
After all, this ain’t rocket
science. It is just finance: determine who is credit-worthy, provide a
loan
financed by issuing insured deposits, and then hold the loan to
maturity. If
the underwriting is poor, the institution will fail and the government
will
protect only the insured depositors. No individual institution will
have an
incentive to grow quickly (rapid growth is almost always associated
with
reducing underwriting standards, and fraud) since once it reaches a one
percent
share of deposits its access to more insured and cheap deposits is
cut-off.
Small institutions would not have to compete against the large
“systemically
dangerous” institutions that now enjoy a huge advantage because even
their
uninsured liabilities are thought to have the Treasury standing behind
them.
With a level playing field, even “average skill and average good
fortune will
be enough”, as J.M. Keynes put it. (End of Except)
Bernanke asserted that as financial conditions have
improved, the Fed has substantially phased out these lending programs.
What
Bernanke failed to tell Congress was that while the phasing out in this
case
meant only that the transfer of troubled debt from the private sector
into the
public sector had been a one time measure that was not expected to be
repeated
with more Fed funds, the return of the troubled debt from the public
sector
back to the private sector remains on an open schedule. No matter how
carefully
the Fed intends to carry out this return of liabilities from the public
sector
to the private sector, it will unavoidably cause head wind for the
seriously impaired
economy.
Bernanke said the second part of the Fed’s response, after
reducing short-term interest rate target nearly to zero, involved the
Federal
Open Market Committee (FOMC) providing additional monetary policy
stimulus
through large-scale purchases of Treasury and government sponsored
enterprise
securities.
Bernanke claimed correctly that these asset purchases had
the additional effect of substantially increasing the reserves that
depository
institutions hold with the Federal Reserve Banks, and had helped lower
interest
rates and spreads in the mortgage market and other key credit markets.
But his
claim that, thereby these purchases promoted economic growth is subject
to
debate and not supported by actual data. What Bernanke did not
acknowledge to
Congress was that the effect of Fed purchase of government debt
instruments had
not alleviated the rise of unemployment or foreclosures, much less
promoting
economic growth.
While admitting that at present the US
economy continues to require the support of highly accommodative
monetary
policies, Bernanke warned Congress that at some point the Fed will need
to
tighten financial conditions by raising short-term interest rates and
reducing
the quantity of bank reserves outstanding. “We have spent considerable
effort
in developing the tools we will need to remove policy accommodation,
and we are
fully confident that at the appropriate time we will be able to do so
effectively,” said Bernanke. He only glossed over the details on these
tools
and gave no indication on when the appropriate time might be. The fact
remains
the Fed’s tool box is very limited as monetary policy is generally
understood
as a very blunt instrument for affecting economic trends.
Yet the market is keenly aware that the date of a Fed exit
from the financial markets may well be followed by the date for a
double dip in
the nervous market that would add more weight to the already impaired
economy.
Meanwhile the exchange value of the dollar is kept up only by other
currencies
falling faster as the result of looming sovereign debt crises world
wide, not
by the strength of the dollar’s purchasing power. The Fed’s Liquidity Programs
Bernanke told Congress that with the onset of the crisis in
the late summer and fall of 2007, the Fed aimed tactically to ensure
that sound
financial institutions had sufficient access to short-term credit to
remain
sufficiently liquid and able to lend to creditworthy customers, even as
private
sources of liquidity began to dry up.
Yet what the Fed actually did was to ensure the survival of
unsound institutions on the verge of insolvency that were deemed too
big to
fail. The funds that went to these institutions actually failed to
reach even
the dwindling number of creditworthy borrowers. Instead of lending
more, much
of the bailout money was used by recipient financial institutions for
de-leveraging to shrink their liabilities.
Bernanke said to improve the access of banks to backup
liquidity, the Fed reduced the spread the target federal funds rate
over the
discount rate--the rate at which the Fed lends to depository
institutions
through its discount window--from 100 basis points to 25 basis points,
and
extended the maximum maturity of discount window loans, which had
generally
been limited to overnight, to 90 days.
Many banks, however, were evidently concerned that if they
borrowed from the discount window, they would be perceived in the
market as
weak, and consequently, might come under further pressure from
creditors.
To address this so-called stigma problem, the Fed created a
new discount window program: the Term Auction Facility (TAF). Under the
TAF,
the Fed regularly auctioned large blocks of credit to depository
institutions.
For many reasons, including the competitive format of the auctions and
the fact
that practically all institutions were in distress, albeit at different
degrees, the TAF has not suffered the stigma of conventional discount
window
lending and has proved effective for injecting liquidity into the
financial
system.Another possible reason that the
TAF did not suffered from stigma was that auctions were not settled for
several
days, which signaled to the market that auction participants did not
face an
imminent shortage of funds. On the other hand, it
showed
that serious market failure could still emerge in a matter of days, a
possibility that Bernanke did not mention.
Liquidity pressures in financial markets were not limited to
the United States,
and intense strains in the global dollar funding markets began to spill
over
back on US markets. In response, the Fed had to enter into temporary
currency
swap agreements with major foreign central banks. Under these
agreements, the
Fed provided dollars to foreign central banks in exchange for an
equally valued
quantity of foreign currency.The foreign
central banks, in turn, lent the dollars to banks in their own national
jurisdictions.
The currency swaps helped reduce stresses in global dollar
funding markets, which in turn helped to stabilize US markets. Bernanke
said,
importantly, the swaps were structured so that the Fed bore no foreign
exchange
risk or credit risk due to dollar hegemony. In particular, foreign
central
banks, not the Fed, bore the credit risk associated with the foreign
central
banks’ dollar-denominated loans to financial institutions in their
respective
financial system. Left
unspoken was that in protecting the Fed from exchange rate risks, the
Fed in
effect neutralized the equilibrium function of the exchange markets by
manipulating the global supply of dollars. Thus it is ironic that some US
politicians, unwashed in monetary economics, urged on
by economist-turned-propagandist Paul Krugman, accused China
of manipulating the exchange value of its currency by
keeping its peg to the dollar. When one currency is pegged by policy to
another
over a long period, the manipulator can only be the issuer of the
currency to
which the peg has been set for a decade. The only way to maintain
stability in the exchange rate market is for the US Treasury, supported
by the
Fed, to give weight to the slogan that a strong dollar is in the US
national interest. Unfortunately, the strong dollar
slogan will remain an empty one for a long time to come, as the
prospect of US
economic policy giving the dollar strong support is highly unlikely. On
the
positive side, the Obama administration is at least soft peddling the
irrational push toward a destructive trade war with China
over the yuan exchange rate issue. A trade war is the
last thing the impaired US
economy needs at this precarious juncture.
As the financial crisis spread, the continuing pullback of
private funding contributed to illiquid and even chaotic conditions in
wholesale financial markets and prompted runs on various types of
financial
institutions, including primary dealers and money market
mutual
funds. To arrest these runs and help stabilize the broader
financial
system, the Fed had to invoke a seldom used emergency lending authority
under
Section 13 (3) of the 1932 Federal Reserve Act, as amended by the
Banking Act
of 1935 and the FDIC Improvement Act of 1991, not used since the Great
Depression, to provide short-term backup funding to select
non-depository
institutions through a number of temporary facilities.
In March 2008, invoking Section 13 (3), the Fed created the
Primary Dealer Credit Facility (PDCF), which lent to primary dealers on
an
overnight, over-collateralized basis. Subsequently, the Fed created
facilities
to help to stabilize other key institutions and markets, including
money market
mutual funds, the commercial paper market, and the asset-backed
securities
market.
The Fed reports that use of many of its lending facilities
has declined sharply as financial conditions stabilized. In designing
its
facilities, the Fed in many cases incorporated features such as pricing
that
was unattractive under normal financial conditions, aimed at
encouraging
borrowers to reduce their use of the facilities as financial conditions
returned to normal. In the case of other facilities, particularly those
that
made available fixed amounts of credit through auctions, the Fed has
gradually
reduced offered amounts.
Some facilities were closed over the course of 2009, and
most other facilities expired at the beginning of February 2010. At the
time of
this writing, the only facilities still in operation that offer credit
to
multiple institutions, other than the regular discount window, are the
Term
Auction Facility (TAF - the auction facility for depository
institutions) and
the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility (TALF), which has
supported the
market for asset-backed securities, such as those that are backed by
auto
loans, credit card loans, small business loans, and student loans.
Bernanke
told Congress that these two facilities are expected to be phased out
soon. The
final TAF auction was conducted on March 8, and the TALF was closed on March 31, 2010 for loans
backed by
all types of collateral except newly issued commercial mortgage-backed
securities (CMBS) and scheduled for June 30, 2010 for loans backed by
newly issued CMBS. The TALF extends three- and
five-year loans, which will remain outstanding after the facility
closes for
new loans. The extension of the CMBS portion of the facility reflects
the Fed’s
assessment that conditions in that sector will remain highly stressed,
as well
as the fact that CMBS securitizations are more complex and take longer
to
arrange than other types. Many in the market expect commercial real
estate loan
default to be the next crisis faced by banks. Some are describing it as
a slow
train wreck.
In addition, Bernanke told Congress that the Fed was in the
process of normalizing the terms of regular discount window loans. It
has
reduced the maximum maturity of discount window loans to 28 days, from
90 days
set in the fall of 2007, and is considering whether further reductions
in the
maximum loan maturity are warranted.
Also, Bernanke told Congress that the Fed expected to
consider a modest increase in the spread between the discount rate and
the
target federal funds rate. These changes, like the closure of a number
of
lending facilities earlier in February, 2010, should be viewed as
further
normalization of the Fed’s lending facilities, in light of the
improving
conditions in financial markets; they are not expected to lead to
tighter
financial conditions for households and businesses and should not be
interpreted as signaling any change in the outlook for monetary policy,
which
remains about as it was at the time of the January 2010 meeting of the
FOMC.
Bernanke maintained that to help stabilize financial markets
and to mitigate the effects of the crisis on the economy, the Fed
established a
number of temporary lending programs. Under nearly all of the programs,
only
short-term credit, with maturities of 90 days or less, was extended,
and under
all of the programs credit was over-collateralized or otherwise secured
as
required by law. Bernanke told Congress that the Fed believes that
these
programs were effective in supporting the functioning of financial
markets and
in helping to promote a resumption of economic growth. The Fed has
borne no
loss on these operations thus far and anticipates no loss in the
future. The
exit from these programs is substantially complete: Total credit
outstanding
under all programs, including the regular discount window, has fallen
sharply
from a peak of $1.5 trillion around year-end 2008 to about $110 billion
by
February 2010.
Separately, Bernanke told Congress that to prevent
potentially catastrophic effects on the US financial system and
economy, and
with the support of the Treasury Department, the Fed also used its
emergency
lending powers to help avoid the disorderly failure of two
“systemically
important” financial institutions, Bear Stearns and American
International
Group, which economist Bill Black suggests “systemically dangerous” as
a more
appropriate description. Why Lehman was allowed to go bankrupt was
conveniently
skirted over by Bernanke.
Credit extended under these arrangements currently totals
about $116 billion, or about 5% of the Fed’s balance sheet. The Fed
expects
these exposures to decline gradually over time. The Federal Reserve
Board
continues to anticipate that the Fed will ultimately incur no loss on
these
loans as well. Bernanke admitted to Congress that these loans were made
with
great reluctance under extreme conditions and in the absence of an
appropriate
alternative legal framework. To preclude any future need for the
Federal
Reserve to lend in similar circumstances, Bernanke said that the Fed
strongly
supports the establishment of a statutory regime for the safe
resolution of
failing, systemically important non-bank financial institutions. Fed Monetary Policy and Trouble Asset
Purchases
In addition to supporting the smooth functioning of
financial markets, the Fed also applied an extraordinary degree of
monetary
policy stimulus to help counter the adverse effects of the financial
crisis on
the economy. In September 2007, the Fed began in a number of steps to
reduce
the target for federal funds rate from an initial level of 5-1/4% to
near zero.
By late 2008, this target reached a range of 0 to 0.25%,
essentially the lowest feasible level, since that rate cannot go below
zero.
With its conventional policy arsenal depleted and the economy remaining
under
severe stress, the Fed decided to override the limits of monetary
measures to
provide additional stimulus through large-scale purchases of federal
agency
debt and mortgage-backed securities (MBS) that are supposed to be fully
guaranteed by federal agencies, though not by the Treasury. In March
2009, the
Fed vastly expanded its purchases of agency securities and began to
purchase
longer-term Treasury securities as well. All told, the Fed purchased
$300
billion of Treasury securities and purchased $1.25 trillion of agency
MBS and
$175 billion of agency debt securities at the end of March 2010.
The Fed’s purchases have had the effect of leaving the
banking system in a highly liquid condition, with US
banks now holding more than $1.1 trillion of reserves with Federal
Reserve
Banks. Bernanke claimed that a range of evidence suggests that these
purchases
and the associated creation of bank reserves have helped improve
conditions in
private credit markets and put downward pressure on longer-term private
borrowing rates and spreads.
As part of its quantitative easing (QE), the Fed first
announced in November 2008 “Large-Scale Asset Purchases” (LSAPs) of GSE
debt,
mortgage-backed securities (MBS) and US Treasuries, expanded it in
March 2009
and concluded it in March 2010.
The objective behind the purchases of Mortgage Backed Securities (MBS),
$1.25
trillion and Government Sponsored Enterprises (GSE) debt, $200 billion,
was
clearly stated at the November 2008 Fed statement: “to reduce the cost
and
increase the availability of credit for the purchase of houses, which
in turn
should support housing markets”
The Fed in effect provided massive support to the collapsed housing
sector, deemed
important in its effort to “improve conditions in financial markets
more
generally.” This approach distorted the market’s normal function in
credit allocation.
The Fed’s purchase of MBS bid up prices and lowered yields at a time
when price
should fall and yield rise not only to attract buyers but to reflect
true
values. Similarly, houses continue to face slow sales despite low
mortgage
rates because house prices are still artificially held up by Fed
subsidy while
potential buyers know prices are still at bubble levels. As a result,
the
housing market has remained lifeless while foreclosures continued
nationwide.
In some regions, such as California
and Florida, the housing
market
stay in deep depression .
But the Fed’s QE has also been design with the systemic objective of
combating
general price deflation. It hoped to achieve that systemic objective by
intervening in the housing credit market and boost equity and bond
prices
through the portfolio balance effect. New York Fed Executive Vice
President Brian
Sack explained in a speech on The Fed's
Expanded Balance Sheet, at New YorkUniversity
on December 2, 2009:
“The [Fed] purchases bid up the
price of the [housing credit] asset and hence lower its yield. These effects [of the purchases] would be
expected to spill over into other [non-housing] assets that are similar
in
nature, to the extent that investors are willing to substitute between
the
assets. … With lower prospective returns on Treasury securities
and
mortgage-backed securities, investors
would naturally bid up the prices of other investments, including
riskier
assets such as corporate bonds and equities. These effects are
all part
of the portfolio balance channel.”
But the problem with the above statement is that Agency MBS and
Treasuries are
not assets that are “similar in nature” with corporate bonds and
equities, as a
2004 paper (Quantitative
Monetary Easing and Risk in
Financial Asset Markets) by Takeshi Kimura of the
Bank of
Japan and David Small of the Federal Reserve Board, showed:
“… the
portfolio-rebalancing
effects were beneficial in that they reduced risk premiums on assets
with
counter-cyclical returns, such as government and high-grade corporate
bonds.
But, they may have generated the adverse effects of increasing risk
premiums on
assets with pro-cyclical returns, such as equities and low-grade
corporate
bonds.”
QE operations that withdraw “safer” assets such as Treasuries or Agency
MBS
from the market turn optimally-balanced portfolios into ones heavily
“overweighted” with pro-cyclical assets such as equities and high-yield
corporate bonds, the market values of which depend on a strong economic
recovery. In a protracted recession, portfolio managers will respond by
shedding
pro-cyclical assets to rebalance and raise their
risk premium. The Fed’s LSAPs during
2008-2010 actually produced the oppositespillover
effects from what the Fed had wanted to achieve, which was “to reduce
the cost
and increase the availability of credit for the purchase of houses,
which in
turn should support housing markets”. Low Interest Rates
and Inflationary Pressures
The Fed Open Market Committee (FOMC), which sets the Fed
funds rate target, anticipates that economic conditions, including low
rates of
resource utilization, subdued inflation trends, and stable inflation
expectations, are likely to warrant exceptionally low levels of the
federal
funds rate for an extended period going forward from 2010. In due
course,
however, as the expansion matures, the Fed will need to begin to
tighten
monetary conditions to prevent the development of inflationary
pressures and
expectations. Bernanke, as the nation’s central banker, assured
Congress that
the Fed has a number of tools that will enable it to firm the stance of
policy
at the appropriate time. Yet Bernanke, as an economist, must know that
the Fed
does not have a reliable way to predetermine when it is the appropriate
time to
firm policy stance.
More importantly, in October 2008 the Congress gave the
Federal Reserve statutory authority to pay interest on banks’ holdings
of
reserve balances at Federal Reserve Banks. By increasing the interest
rate on
reserves, the Fed will be able to put significant upward pressure on
all
short-term interest rates, as banks will not supply short-term funds to
the
money markets at rates significantly below what they can earn by
holding
reserves at the Federal Reserve Banks. Actual and prospective increases
in
short-term interest rates will be reflected in turn in longer-term
interest
rates and in financial conditions more generally.
While this is the accepted theoretical correlation, in
recent years Alan Greenspan had been baffled by what he called the
“Interest
Rate Conundrum”.Greenspan’s February
2005 testimony
to Congress referred to the behavior of low long term rates as a
“conundrum”:
“In
this environment, long-term
interest rates have trended lower in
recent months even as the Federal Reserve has raised the level of the
target
federal funds rate by 150 basis points. This development contrasts with
most
experience, which suggests that, other things being equal, increasing
short-term interest rates are normally accompanied by a rise in
longer-term
yields. The simple mathematics of the yield curve governs the
relationship
between short- and long-term interest rates. Ten-year yields, for
example, can
be thought of as an average of ten consecutive one-year forward rates.
A rise
in the first-year forward rate, which correlates closely with the
federal funds
rate, would increase the yield on ten-year U.S. Treasury notes even if
the
more-distant forward rates remain unchanged. Historically, though, even
these
distant forward rates have tended to rise in association with monetary
policy
tightening.”
Greenspan was referring to the expectations theory of interest rates
where long
rates are the geometric average of expected future short rates plus a
risk
premium that would usually increase with duration of the instrument.
This
theory assumes that arbitrage between instruments of different
durations will
set the price. It is also possible for the risk premium to change over
time. As
an example, changes in the perceptions of the Fed’s credibility on
fighting
inflation will change the risk premium.
Increases in the interest rate paid on reserves are unlikely
to prove a net subsidy to banks, as the higher return on reserve
balances will
be offset by similar increases in banks’ funding costs. On balance,
banks’ net
interest margins will likely continue to decline when short-term rates
rise. Reverse Repos as
Addition Tool to Reduce Bank Reserves
Bernanke told Congress the Fed has also been developing a
number of additional tools it will be able to use to reduce the large
quantity
of reserves held by the banking system when needed. Reducing the
quantity of
reserves will lower the net supply of funds to the money markets, which
will
improve the Fed’s control of financial conditions by leading to a
tighter
relationship between the interest rate on reserves and other short-term
interest rates.
One such tool is reverse repurchase agreements (reverse
repos), a method that the Fed has used historically as a means of
absorbing
reserves from the banking system. In reverse repos, the Fed sells
securities to
counterparties with an agreement to repurchase the security at some
date in the
future. The counterparties’ payments to the Fed have the effect of
draining an
equal quantity of reserves from the banking system.
Recently, by developing the capacity to conduct such reverse
repos transactions in the tri-party repo market, the Fed has enhanced
its
ability to use reverse repos to absorb very large quantities of
reserves. The
capability to carry out these transactions with primary dealers, using
the
Fed’s large holdings of Treasury and agency debt securities, has
already been
tested and is currently available, according to Bernanke. To further
increase
its capacity to drain reserves through reverse repos, the Fed is
reportedly
also in the process of expanding the set of counterparties with which
it can
transact and developing the infrastructure necessary to use its MBS
holdings as
collateral in these transactions.
As a second means of draining reserves, Bernanke said the
Fed is also developing plans to offer to depository institutions term
deposits,
which are roughly analogous to certificates of deposit that the
institutions
offer to their customers. The Fed would likely auction large blocks of
such
deposits, thus converting a portion of depository institutions’ reserve
balances into deposits that could not be used to meet their very
short-term
liquidity needs and could not be counted as reserves. A proposal
describing a
term deposit facility was recently published in the Federal
Register,
and the Fed is currently analyzing the public comments that have been
received.
After a revised proposal is reviewed by the Board, the Fed expects to
be able
to conduct test transactions in the spring of 2010 and to have the
facility
available if necessary shortly thereafter.
Bernanke said reverse repos and the deposit facility would
together allow the Fed to drain hundreds of billions of dollars of
reserves
from the banking system quite quickly, should it choose to do so. The
question
has been left unanswered as to under what economic conditions would the
Fed
choose to do so. If the conditions include good employment figures, the
Fed’s
need to use this new option to drain reserves from the banking system
may not
arise for a long time.
In the mean time, the scars of the financial crisis remain
highly visible in a key part of the US fixed income universe – the repo
market.
As a barometer of borrowing by the financial sector, the size of the
repo
market peaked in early 2008 at nearly $4.3 trillion, before the demise
of Bear
Stearns revealed how much major investment banks had depended on this
short-term funding market to finance their balance sheets.
In April, 2010, the overall use of repo at about $2.5
trillion remains more than 40% below its peak. This is evidence showing
how, in
the wake of the Lehman failure in September 2008, large dealers have
cut back
their balance sheets and are now less reliant on short-term leverage.
Instead,
they are funding themselves with long-term debt outside the repo
sector. A
reluctance by repo lenders to accept lower-quality assets as collateral
has
also hit the market.
At the peak of repo activity in 2007 and early 2008, a
sizeable portion of collateral involved securitized mortgages and
structured credit
securities, which subsequently collapsed in marked-to-market value as
the
mortgage and credit bubble burst and credit markets imploded. The
subsequent
large drop in repo usage partly reflects how credit standards have
tightened,
with only super good-quality collateral being accepted by short-term
lenders of
cash.
The current lack of appetite for extending money to
lower-quality collateral via repo helps explain why the use of
securitization
among banks has not come roaring back. Another factor limiting the use
of repo
financing is the current low level of interest rates, which has
resulted in
some investors not lending their holdings of bonds as the potential
returns are
too low.(Please see my December 4, 2009 article: The Repo Time Bomb Redux)
Aside from the uncertainty of potential regulatory, the repo
market faces new challenges.
Before the financial crisis, US investment banks ended their
financial years in November. That meant that the big repo dealers were
divided
into two groups, with primary dealers reporting quarterly results one
month
behind the big US
investment banks. This split in reporting periods meant that quarterly
window
dressing by financial institutions, whereby banks cut borrowings and
often buy
Treasury bills and notes to shore up their balance sheets, was spread
out over
several weeks.
Now, with all banks reporting on the same quarterly
schedule, uniform window dressing by financial institutions has led to
a
pronounced and coordinated drop in the use of repo during these
periods.
This potentially has big implications for financial markets
and institutions in the future as the financial crisis subsides. As all
large
banks now operate on the same reporting schedule, it could leave
investors
withholding funds and institutions scrambling for funds, as liquidity
declines
at the end of each quarter. This may result in a mini liquidity crunch
every
three months. The Fed’s other tools
The Fed also has the option of redeeming or selling
securities as a means of applying monetary restraint. A reduction in
securities
holdings would have the effect of further reducing the quantity of
reserves in
the banking system as well as reducing the overall size of the Fed’s
balance
sheet. But that would reduce the money supply through quantitative
tightening
and drain liquidity.
Bernanke admitted that the sequencing of steps and the
combination of tools that the Fed uses as it exits from its currently
very
accommodative policy stance will depend on economic and financial
developments.
One possible sequence would involve the Fed continuing to test its
tools for
draining reserves on a limited basis, in order to further ensure
preparedness
and to give market participants a period of time to become familiar
with their
operation. As the time for the removal of policy accommodation draws
near,
those operations could be scaled up to drain more significant volumes
of
reserve balances to provide tighter control over short-term interest
rates. The
actual firming of policy would then be implemented through an increase
in the
interest rate paid on reserves. If economic and financial developments,
such as
rising inflation expectation, were to require a more rapid exit from
the
current highly accommodative policy, however, the Fed could increase
the
interest rate paid on reserves at about the same time it commences
significant
draining operations. But Bernanke did not sketch out to Congress a
scenario
that covered how the Fed would handle stagflation, a very likely
prospect in a
jobless recovery.
Bernanke told Congress he currently did not anticipate that
the Fed will sell any of its security holdings in the near term, at
least until
after policy tightening has gotten under way and he claimed
optimistically that
the economy is clearly in a sustainable recovery. However, to help
reduce the
size of the Fed’s balance sheet and the quantity of reserves, Bernanke
said the
Fed is allowing agency debt and MBS to run off as these instruments
mature or
are prepaid over time. The Fed is currently rolling over all maturing
Treasury
securities, but in the future it may choose not to do so in all cases.
Left
unsaid is that while this policy will reduce the Fed’s balance sheet,
it does
this by adding to the national debt.
Bernanke said in the long run, the Fed anticipates that its
balance sheet will shrink toward more historically normal levels and
that most
or all of its security holdings will be Treasury securities. Although
passively
redeeming agency debt and MBS as they mature or are prepaid will move
the Fed
in that direction, Bernanke said he may also choose to sell securities
in the
future when the economic recovery is sufficiently advanced and the FOMC
has
determined that the associated financial tightening is warranted. Any
such
sales would be at a gradual pace, would be clearly communicated to
market
participants, and would entail appropriate consideration of economic
conditions. All things considered, the fragile economy is expected to
be under
the intensive care of the Fed for a long time.
Bernanke reported to Congress that as a result of the very
large volume of reserves in the banking system, the level of activity
and
liquidity in the federal funds market has declined considerably,
raising the
possibility that the federal funds rate could for a time become a less
reliable
indicator than usual of conditions in short-term money markets.
Accordingly, the Fed is reported to be considering the
utility, during the transition to a more normal policy configuration,
of communicating
the stance of policy in terms of another operating target, such as an
alternative short-term interest rate. In particular, it is possible
that the
Federal Reserve could for a time use the interest rate paid on
reserves, in
combination with targets for reserve quantities, as a guide to its
policy
stance, while simultaneously monitoring a range of market rates.
The Fed has long advocated the payment of interest on the
reserves that banks maintain at Federal Reserve Banks. But such a step
would have
to be approved by Congress, which traditionally has been opposed to the
idea because
of the revenue loss that would result to the US Treasury. Each year the
Treasury receives the Fed’s revenue that is in excess of its expenses.
The
payment of interest on bank reserves would, of course, be an additional
expense
to the Fed and less revenue for the Treasury.
No decision has been made on this issue; the Fed says it
will be guided in part by the evolution of the federal funds market as
policy
accommodation is withdrawn. The Fed anticipates that it will eventually
return
to an operating framework with much lower reserve balances than at
present and
with the federal funds rate as the operating target for policy.
Yet the structural echo of a long duration of high reserve
balance coupled with zero interest rate will so conditioned the
dependency of
the economy on monetary accommodation that real recovery may not emerge
for
decades.
Bernanke told Congress that the authority to pay interest on
reserves is likely to be an important component of the future operating
framework for monetary policy. For example, one approach is for the Fed
to
bracket its target for the federal funds rate with the discount rate
above and
the interest rate on excess reserves below. Under this so-called
corridor
system, the ability of banks to borrow at the discount rate would tend
to limit
upward spikes in the federal funds rate, and the ability of banks to
earn
interest at the excess reserves rate would tend to contain downward
movements.
Other approaches are also possible. Given the very high
level of reserve balances currently in the banking system, the Fed has
ample
time to consider the best long-run framework for policy implementation.
The Fed
believes it is possible that, ultimately, its operating framework will
allow
the elimination of minimum reserve requirements, which impose costs and
distortions on the banking system.
As market conditions and the economic outlook improve, the
series of special lending facilities to stabilize the financial system
and
encourage the resumption of private credit flows have been terminated
or are
being phased out. The Fed also aimed to promote economic recovery
through sharp
reductions in its target for the federal funds rate and through
purchases of
distressed securities. Yet the economy continues to require the support
of
accommodative monetary policies after 30 months of recession. The Fed
claims it
has the tools to reverse, at the appropriate time, the currently very
high
degree of monetary stimulus. Sounds a bit like Samuel Beckett’s Waiting for Godot. April 14,
2010