|
HONG
KONG: A CASE OF SELF-DELUSION
By
Henry C K Liu
Part 1: From colonialism to confusion
Part
2: Missing the boat to renewal
The article
appeared in AToL
on May 22, 2003
By the late 1970s, British Hong Kong's colonial officials and business
leaders realized they could no longer put off the question of what
would happen to the New Territories, which makes up more than 90
percent of Hong Kong's land area. The New Territories had been leased
to Britain in 1898, for 99 years, so that lease was set to expire on
July 1, 1997.
In 1979, the British government initiated talks with China about Hong
Kong's future. Governor Murray MacLehose unexpectedly brought up the
subject during a private meeting in Beijing with Chinese leader Deng
Xiaoping, who made it clear that China intended to reclaim Hong Kong.
In 1982, on the heels of victory in the Falkland Islands, British prime
minister Margaret Thatcher made an ill-fated attempt to perpetuate
British colonial rule over Hong Kong. She proposed British
administration of Hong Kong after 1997, which Chinese officials
rejected outright. Thatcher not only insisted on British sovereignty in
Hong Kong, but also insisted that the unequal New Territories Treaty
signed in 1898 was legal. China is not Argentina, and Deng stated his
clear intent to take back Hong Kong in 1997. The bilateral talks over
Hong Kong quickly deadlocked. The British had hoped to extend their
control over their most valuable colony, but China refused to recognize
the validity of what it considered unequal treaties forced on it by the
British in 1841.
London finally conceded that there was no legal basis to force China to
renew the New Territories lease, and that modern-day Hong Kong could
not survive without that major portion of the colony, nor without
Chinese acquiescence. In 1984, after two years of lame posturing about
China's need to honor international treaties, Britain was left with
little choice but to agree to China's proposal for a Joint Declaration.
Hong Kong would be a Special Administrative Region (SAR), with its own
legal and economic systems until 2047, 50 years after its return to
China.
The Joint Declaration set a framework to handle bilateral issues
between Britain and China. Deng Xiaoping applied the "one country, two
systems" (OCTS) formula to the Joint Declaration for the return of Hong
Kong to Chinese sovereignty. That formula had been originally fashioned
as a solution to the Taiwan problem as a Chinese internal affair.
Subsequent to the Sino-British Joint Declaration, Deng approached
Washington directly for acceptance of the same formula for solving the
Taiwan problem. The administration of president Ronald Reagan summarily
turned the idea down as a non-starter. Nevertheless, the OCTS formula
became official Chinese policy for the reunification of Taiwan, with
wholesale Chinese political compromise on Hong Kong in deference to its
implication on Taiwan.
OCTS is a fundamental error of multi-level dimensions on the part of
China, not the least of which is Chinese acquiescence on the principle
of foreign meddling in Chinese internal affairs. Short-term, it
permitted the continuation of neo-colonialism on Chinese soil under
Chinese sovereignty for another half century. This was a significant
backsliding. Since the 1911 revolution, no colonialism had been allowed
to exist under Chinese sovereignty, even though it continued to exist
in occupied territories where Chinese sovereignty had been temporarily
suspended. One of the two systems referred to in the policy of OCTS is
in fact neo-colonialism disguised as capitalism. Furthermore, the
system in Taiwan is national capitalism, not colonialism. Thus the
policy of OCTS may apply to Taiwan, but not to Hong Kong. Because the
policy of OCTS was misapplied to Hong Kong, it gave Taiwan an opening
to say it did not apply to Taiwan because Taiwan is not a foreign
colony. Thus the policy's original purpose was negated while political
compromise on the return of Hong Kong was made for naught.
The reality today is one country: China; two governments: Beijing and
Taipei; and three systems: socialism (with Chinese characteristics) on
the mainland, national capitalism on Taiwan, and residual colonialism
in Hong Kong. The British are gone from Hong Kong administratively, but
Anglo-US neo-imperialism continues to rule Hong Kong by proxy through
its overwhelming economic prowess.
The events at Tiananmen Square in 1989 altered the geopolitical context
affecting Hong Kong. More ominously, Beijing's overture to gain US
acceptance of the policy of OCTS opened the way for US interference on
the future of Hong Kong. Up to that point, Washington had been
officially neutral in a bilateral problem between China and Britain
involving the redress of historical colonialism.
After Tiananmen, the issue of Hong Kong was abruptly transformed from
one of righteous termination of British colonialism on Chinese soil to
official Chinese acceptance of colonial institutions for 50 more years
in the name of democracy and free enterprise market fundamentalism.
Moreover, the issue of Hong Kong prompted the US Congress to adopt the
Hong Kong Policy Act, which provides a legal basis in US law for
self-righteous US monitoring on Chinese acceptance of Western democracy
and capitalism in Hong Kong and, by extension, within Chinese
territory.
US recognition of the People's Republic incurred the price of the
Taiwan Relations Act, which binds the US with the force of domestic law
to interfere in China's internal affair by helping Taiwan defend itself
militarily against reunification by force from China. Similarly, US
recognition of Hong Kong under Chinese sovereignty incurred the price
of the Hong Kong Policy Act, which also interferes in China's internal
affair by holding China to the observance of the OCTS policy with the
force of US domestic law. China rejects both these US domestic laws as
unacceptable interference in its internal affairs. Yet Chinese policies
on Hong Kong and Taiwan are operationally constrained by these two US
domestic laws.
Until Hong Kong and Taiwan are free of foreign intervention, China's
status as an independent power remains blemished. If the US could
unilaterally withdraw from the Anti-Ballistic Missile (ABM) Treaty on
the grounds that it no longer served US national interest, why
shouldn't China have the same option on OCTS when and if the policy no
longer serves Chinese national interest? Because there was nothing
Russia could do about US's unilateral withdrawal from the ABM Treaty,
while the US can cause economic pain to Hong Kong by denying the SAR
its special trade status with the US if the OCTS policy is not
observed. The US has no such power over Shanghai, or Shenzhen, or any
other city in China.
The British exploited to the maximum this new post-Tiananmen
geopolitical climate with the full backing of US moral imperialism.
Hong Kong's last colonial governor, Christopher Patten, an ambitious
Conservative politician who had earlier lost his seat in parliament,
arrived in 1992 to pursue the goal of setting Hong Kong up as an
anti-China base by 1997, in the name of democracy as the parting gift
of British colonialism. In direct violation of a bilateral
understanding of "50 years without change" for Hong Kong, Patten
embarked on a crash program of "democratic reforms" in Hong Kong now
that British colonial rule was ending by 1997.
This was coupled with the evacuation of century-old British monopolies
through inflated financial compensation from government funds. Even the
British military was paid handsomely (US$1 billion) for removal
expenses, for which the newly installed financial secretary, never
given the option to resist, was rewarded with a knighthood for being of
service to the British crown. Faithful collaborators with British
colonialism were hailed as democratic community leaders and defenders
of freedom. The lead member of the Executive Council that "advised" the
British colonial governor (Lydia Dunn) was made a baroness for
faithfully protecting British interests in the name of preserving
freedom for the people of Hong Kong.
In a crash localization program, Patten hand-picked key locals to lead
the civil service. Well-trained running dogs such as Anson Chan were
groomed to head the allegedly apolitical civil service, with a strategy
aggressively focused on insulating Hong Kong from any influence by
China. Key civil servants were sent to Harvard University's Kennedy
School of Government for special indoctrination in the basics of
neo-liberal governance, complete with sham degrees and diplomas.
Neo-liberalism replaced old-time colonialism, introducing a
neo-colonialism of US economic imperialism under the pretext of
preserving Hong Kong as an international city with the rule of law,
free enterprise, press freedom, small government - scripts written by
the Heritage Foundation and the American Enterprise Institute. This
fantasy is in direct contradiction to the historical fact that Hong
Kong was never more than a British colony structured to serve British
geopolitical and economic interests and to enrich British monopolies
through a British command colonial economy.
After the signing of the Joint Declaration in 1982, Hong Kong, still
under British rule, wasted 15 years prior to its return to China, with
no long-range plan to deal with the new geopolitical landscape. Hong
Kong hung on to fantasies created by Anglo-US propaganda, totally
intoxicated by a bubble economy created by its currency peg and a trade
regime heavily dependent on geopolitical preference. While in office,
Patten, working feverishly to cater to US ideological fixation, ran
what British career diplomats in Whitehall labeled a sideshow,
oblivious to British interest in, and need for, good long-term
Sino-British relations. While Britain had no power to resist Chinese
demands, the US had its trade card on both Hong Kong and China.
The agreement of "50 years without change" was surreptitiously rendered
meaningless by Patten's stealth change in the political structure of
Hong Kong to make the SAR ungovernable after 1997. A so-called
Democratic Party with only a handful of members was formed with open US
support to oppose China in the name of liberty. It was the latest
version of the British strategy of perpetuating "divide and rule" in
its involuntary decolonization program throughout the shrinking British
Empire. On the issue of the rule of law, British common law, which was
practiced only within former territories of the British Empire and not
in former territories under continental civil law of the Napoleonic
Code, was allowed to continue in Hong Kong under Chinese sovereignty.
Yet the arrangement of the highest judicial authority resting
previously in the Privy Council in London was not reciprocated by
transferring that authority to the People's Supreme Court in Beijing.
Hong Kong was allowed to set up its own Court of Final Appeal. This
bizarre arrangement promptly produced a constitutional crisis over the
issue of sovereignty in Hong Kong soon after its return to China.
As China adopted its "open to the outside" policy in 1979, Hong Kong
and China both soon reaped the immediate benefits of the colony's early
participation in the modernization of China. Hong Kong entrepreneurs
were able to provide expertise and capital for joint venture projects
on the mainland, beginning with tourism and hotels, and soon moving
into infrastructure and manufacturing. As a result of this
collaboration, China in return increased and changed the types of
investments it had made in Hong Kong up to then. For example, in the
1970s Chinese investments in Hong Kong were mainly centered on
transport, shipping, finance and distribution of Chinese export goods
beyond Hong Kong. These investments were targeted to serve the needs of
a still largely closed Chinese economy. By the early 1980s, investments
began to include a cigarette factory, real estate and related
businesses, department store chains selling mainland products, printing
presses, periodicals and gas stations. These investments were focused
on trading profits, beyond serving the needs of a closed economy on the
mainland. China Resources, which had organized Chinese export trade
through Hong Kong, evolved into a huge conglomerate. Chinese banks and
insurance companies formed joint ventures with Hong Kong investors.
Between 1976 and 1981, the value of Hong Kong's domestic exports to
China multiplied 120 times. The amount of Chinese goods re-exported
from Hong Kong - then acting as China's only "door to the world" -
comprised 31 percent of the colony's total in 1981. Today, Chinese
companies and financial institutions are major players in the Hong Kong
economy. Clearly, both sides enjoyed a significant increase in trade as
a result of Hong Kong's effort to profit from helping China reach its
goal of modernization through economic growth.
But the adverse effect on China has been the acceptance of Hong Kong's
colonial economy as a model of reform for the Chinese economy. By
learning about the modern world after five decades of near-total
isolation through the warped experience of colonial Hong Kong, China
modeled the first phase its modernization as a revival of a
semi-colonial regime that the nation had endured two political
revolutions to throw off. This key compromise poisoned Deng's "Four
Modernizations" program and sowed the seeds of corruption in all levels
of Chinese government and society and of ideological decay within the
Communist Party. The Chinese economy fell into the trap of excessive
dependence on exports to the West, primarily to US markets, by building
a sweatshop economy along the Hong Kong model, and on foreign capital,
along the path welcomed by Western imperialism. It would have been
arguably acceptable as a short-term compromise for the "take-off phase"
of economic development. But the export frenzy went on for 25 years at
the expense of balanced domestic development, in the process letting a
social services and health network and a regime of equitable
distribution of wealth that had been the envy of the world deteriorate
into chaos and decadence.
The adverse impact of compradore culture and associated corruption on
the ideological erosion of the Chinese Communist Party was allowed to
become structural. It is only recently that China has begun to refocus
on internal development, away from exports, to address the imbalance
between the coastal regions and the interior, to stimulate domestic
consumption and to correct the problem of extreme disparity of income
and polarization of wealth. On the issue of foreign capital, China has
yet to apply the principle of creditary economics based on the State
Theory of Money to free itself from dependence on foreign capital for
domestic development. On the ideological front, the noble aspiration of
serving the people has been replaced by the crass aim of serving
foreign capital for profit. Getting rich at the expense of the people
is not glorious, even under capitalism.
The Nazis came to power in 1933 in Germany at a time when its economy
was in total collapse, with ruinous war-reparation obligations, and
zero prospect for foreign investment or credit. Yet, through an
independent monetary policy of state credit and a full-employment
public-works program, the Third Reich was able to turn a bankrupt
Germany into the strongest economy in Europe within four years, even
before armament spending began. While this observation is not an
endorsement for Nazism, the effectiveness of German economic policy in
this period, some of which had been started during the last phase of
the Weimar Republic, is undeniable.
China's pace of growth in the past two-and-a-half decades has been much
touted by Western neo-liberals. Yet a case can be made that China's
growth rate had been unnecessarily slow, that despite
self-congratulatory complacency, China is still falling behind world
standards on many measures even by its own projections. And this
relative slow growth is not caused by the absence of liberal markets
but by China's mistaken view that a disadvantaged participation in
neo-liberal globalization is its only option.
It is time for China to realize that acceptance of this fate is not
ordained by nature. Furthermore, the economic growth came with the
price of unsustainable structural imbalance, malpractice in
human-resource utilization and environmental management, and continuing
transfer of the nation's wealth overseas through export under dollar
hegemony. This self-arresting sluggish growth rate is in large measure
the result of the undue influence on China's development strategy
exerted by the colonial-economy mentality of Hong Kong tycoons. Such a
mentality sees subservient support for economic neo-imperialism in the
form of neo-liberal globalization as the only option for growth,
instead of the game of voluntary perpetual indenture that it actually
is.
Hong Kong's balloon economy had boomed with its new China trade
beginning in 1978. By 1987, it recorded a 13.6 percent annual gain in
gross domestic product (GDP). On Black Monday, October 19, 1987, the
Hong Kong stock market, alone among the world's financial centers
facing contagious global collapse, closed for four days. The British
Hong Kong government had to use HK$4 billion (US$513 million) to rescue
the Hong Kong Futures Exchange from insolvency. The international press
called the Hong Kong stock market under British regulatory supervision
"a badly run casino".
On the other side of the globe, Alan Greenspan, newly appointed
chairman of the US Federal Reserve Board, built his reputation by
releasing a single sentence that said he would supply all the liquidity
the banking system needed to stay afloat after the 1987 crash. He
pumped tens of billions of US dollars, a fiat currency that he could
print at will, into US financial institutions by pushing down the
overnight lending rate aggressively. Greenspan's move flooded financial
markets with money, which helped preserve liquidity and restore
confidence in the US financial system, but it started the bubble
economy of the 1990s, which ended in Asia on July 2, 1997, one day
after Hong Kong was returned to China. Greenspan did in essence the
same thing in 1998 and again after September 11, 2001. Greenspan will
go down in history as the central banker who revived moral hazard.
When the Asian financial crises began in Thailand on July 2, 1997, the
new SAR government maintained with hubris that the fundamentals of Hong
Kong's economy were sound. It had US$112 billion in foreign reserves,
no external debt, a currency pegged to the US dollar, low taxes,
business-friendly government, rule of law, freedom of information, etc,
etc. Hong Kong was confident enough to contribute US$1 billion to the
International Monetary Fund to help contain the crisis within Thailand.
Government leaders were calmly announcing that all Hong Kong needed was
to stay the course and keep its "confidence" in what they mistook as a
passing storm. They were painfully oblivious to the fact that staying
the course would lead Hong Kong directly toward a whirlpool of economic
collapse in not a passing storm but a fundamental structural collapse
of the neo-liberal global financial architecture. They were also blind
to the fact that the Hong Kong economy's easy ride on the geopolitical
magic carpet was coming to an end.
The neo-liberal mantra began to sound like empty pitches of snake-oil
pushers on the Cross Harbor Ferry. No one could answer the embarrassing
question: with such good fundamentals, why are the factual data so
consistently bad and for such a protracted period?
By August 1998, the SAR government had to intervene in the Hong Kong
stock market, buying up more than US$15 billion in publicly traded
blue-chip stocks to fend off speculative attacks on the Hong Kong
dollar. Since 1997, Hong Kong has been locked in a downward spiral by
staying the course.
All kinds of harebrained schemes surfaced. The government used US$1.74
billion of public funds to lure the Disney Co to Hong Kong, at a time
when Disney has been facing financial problems worldwide, and the
potential of theme parks as a development stimulant having visibly
peaked. Hong Kong Disneyland Phase 1 will include a Disney theme park,
Disney-themed hotels and retail, dining and entertainment facilities.
It will occupy 126 hectares, and can be expanded to 180 hectares in the
future. Phase 1 is expected to open in 2005. The project involves a
total commitment of HK$22 billion (US$2.8 billion) in public funds
(infrastructure, loans and equity). In its first full year of
operation, Hong Kong Disneyland is expected to attract more than 5
million visitors, including 1.4 million new tourists, and stimulate
additional spending of HK$8.3 billion. The government claims that over
a 40-year period, the project is expected to generate economic benefits
amounting to HK$148 billion. Any Hong Kong entrepreneur would tell you
that a sixfold return over a 40-year period is hardly a financial gold
mine, notwithstanding that the estimated return is denominated in soft
"economic benefits", not hard cash.
In all, Hong Kong has proposed some US$77 billion in
government-supported infrastructure and other major projects over 15
years, intended to get the stagnant economy moving again. That is
massive by any standard - amounting to US$12,000 per resident, about 50
percent of 2001 per capita GDP. But many of these proposed projects
fail to coordinate with mainland development plans, let alone fully
integrate with them, if not in predatory competition with the Pearl
River Delta economy. Hong Kong's vision of itself as the front parlor
for entertaining foreign investors and the well-appointed sales office,
with the Pearl River Delta as the servants quarters and the factory
floor, has not been well received by mainland officials. Many of Hong
Kong's plans have to do with keeping the Pearl River Delta from
effectively competing with Hong Kong rather than true cooperation on an
equal basis for mutual benefit. This is because compradorism does not
thrive on equality. It is also the mentality behind Hong Kong's
insistence of not wanting to be a "Chinese" city, a view relentlessly
expressed by Patten protege chief secretary Anson Chan until her "early
retirement".
Such grand schemes have pushed public spending up to 24 percent of GDP,
producing a budget deficit while contributing little to constructive
restructuring of the Hong Kong economy, which requires full integration
with the mainland economy. In the manner that SAR government Requests
for Proposals are written, many of the construction and consulting
contracts will go to foreign firms in the name of an open market, at a
time when the local unemployment rate is over 7 percent, inching toward
9 percent by most forecasts. Also, the thinning demand for local
professionals further exacerbates the ongoing brain drain from Hong
Kong.
In 1997, when the British returned Hong Kong to Chinese sovereignty,
public expenditures accounted for just 17 percent of GDP, albeit
calculated on a substantially larger GDP. From 1998-99 to 2001-02,
government expenditure recorded a cumulative growth of 17 percent in
money terms, while GDP registered a cumulative fall of 5 percent.
Public expenditure in the economy averaged about 16 percent in the
mid-1980s, about 17 percent in the mid-1990s, but rose to 22 percent in
2001-02. In the face of economic downturn since 1997, the SAR
government has consciously adopted a counter-cyclical fiscal policy,
keeping expenditure growth above the projected growth trend of the
economy. But the government's fiscal stimulant has been focused on
ineffective spending, neglecting unemployment and public housing, and
integration with the mainland economy. The government has recently cut
social welfare payments by 11 percent and in effect reduced the minimum
wage for new contracts of foreign domestic helpers by about the same. A
recent deal with civil servants will cut their salaries by 6 percent in
two stages.
In addition, price rigidity in public-expenditure contracts causes
prices to continue to rise despite general deflation in the economy.
The government's stated target is to reduce public expenditure to 20
percent of GDP or below by 2006-07. Unless this reduction is achieved
through a rise in GDP rather than a cut in public expenditure, it will
further distress the economy.
Land premium, constituting 22.6 percent (HK$63.6 billion) of revenue in
1997-98, fell to 4.4 percent (HK$8.5 billion) in 2002. This is the
center of the problem. Hong Hong's export partners are mainland China
(34 percent), the United States (23 percent), Japan (6 percent),
Germany (4 percent), the United Kingdom (4 percent), Taiwan (3
percent), and Singapore (2 percent), with China trade expected to be
the leading growth potential. Yet a proportional share of public
expenditure has not been directed toward further integration with
China.
With the outbreak of the Asian financial crisis in the second half of
1997, the Hong Kong economy suffered severe setbacks, and for the first
time in recent memory it recorded negative growth on an annual basis in
1998. The economy rebounded temporarily and attained double-digit
growth in 2000 on naive and false expectation that what went down must
go back up. But along with the global economic downturn, the Hong Kong
economy slowed abruptly again in 2001. The Hong Kong economy yielded
growth averaging only about 2 percent per annum between 1998 and 2002.
Yet China, Hong Kong's largest trading partner, consistently registered
growth rates above 7 percent in the same periods. This disconnect is
largely the result of Hong Kong's failure to integrate its economy with
the mainland economy.
And there is serious talk of new taxes in Hong Kong, including one on
border crossing to the mainland and a new tax on goods and services.
New taxes are always unpopular, especially in a traditionally tax-shy
city with a maximum 15 percent tax rate on personal salary income and a
16 percent tax on business income. Most in Hong Kong pay no salary
income tax at all and only 13,000 people in a city of 7 million pay the
peak rate of 15 percent. But the real regressive impact is the obstacle
such border-crossing taxes erect against the needed integration of the
two economies.
Disparity in costs between Hong Kong and the Pearl Delta is about 10:1
at present. Integration with the Pearl Delta would require Hong Kong
costs, particularly wages and rent, to fall drastically even as Pearl
Delta costs rise. This cost disparity vastly exceeds that between West
Germany and East Germany or that between New York and New Jersey. Since
the opening up of the mainland in the 1980s, Hong Kong enterprises,
leveraging the low costs there, have expanded their production capacity
and enhanced Hong Kong's cost competitiveness globally. Hong Kong's
domestic economy has upgraded itself in tandem with its exploitation of
low labor and land cost on the mainland. But Hong Kong has been
siphoning off most of this profit, only a small portion of which has
been reinvested on the mainland. Even then, the reinvestment has been
concentrated in more sweatshop production for more export, rather than
in socio-economic development. The rest of this profit has been going
into bidding up real estate prices in Hong Kong and into money-losing
real-estate investment in the US, Britain, Canada and Australia in the
form of flight capital through most of the 1990s. In recent years,
profit from Hong Kong has been poured into wireless and
telecommunication ventures overseas, with unhappy results.
Support services for the Hong Kong trading sector and its mainland
factories replaced the local manufacturing sector as the
fastest-growing sector. The South China region has now evolved into one
of the world's prolific production bases. Since the mid-1990s, service
industries on the mainland have also been developing apace. During this
period, a bubble economy emerged in Hong Kong, giving rise to high
operating costs in the colony, pushing some Hong Kong service
industries to move northward as well. Moreover, after its return to
China, Hong Kong residents, in increasing numbers, travel across the
boundary to shop and vacation, adversely affecting Hong Kong's domestic
consumption and the retail sector and its real-estate base.
In the process of economic integration, the price differential between
Hong Kong and the mainland will inevitably narrow gradually through
factor price equalization. The price of tradable products should adjust
swiftly because of relatively free trade between the two economies. But
fixed rents in Hong Kong prevent this adjustment from taking shape
without widespread business failures and bankruptcies.
The adjustment of non-tradable factors such as land and labor will be
slow and painful. However, factor price equalization does not mean that
price levels between Hong Kong and the mainland will be the same, just
as New York, London and Tokyo have relatively higher prices than their
neighboring areas. Prices in Hong Kong will generally remain higher
than prices in the Pearl Delta for some time, but the exponential gap
cannot remain forever. The conventional wisdom is that the magnitude of
this price differential will hinge largely on Hong Kong's ability to
provide high-value-added services and goods. But God has not forbidden
the Pearl River Delta from developing high-value-added service and
goods production. Ironically, the high cost disparity gives more of a
boost to the Pearl River Delta's downhill effort to develop such
services and goods than to Hong Kong's uphill effort to maintain the
cost differential.
As the bursting of the bubble economy coincided with economic
restructuring, Hong Kong has experienced heavy deflationary pressure,
exacerbated by the linked-exchange-rate mechanism tied to a US dollar
that, despite its recent decline, is still overvalued. Hong Kong
property prices have dropped from their peak by more than half. And
because of the economy's disproportionate reliance on the real property
sector, this has magnified the economic crisis. High labor costs in
Hong Kong force pay cuts and layoffs, causing high unemployment and
underemployment, which in turn reduces domestic demand, particularly
consumer spending, as well as incentives for more education and
training, shrinking the economy further in a downward spiral.
China's growth so far is based on labor-cost advantage in the global
export market, coupled with low land costs and environmental
liabilities. Even then, the growth rate is unsustainable on exports
alone as the global economy stagnates and global trade shrinks. To keep
the growth rate above 7 percent, China would have to focus on domestic
development. Hong Kong's future rests on its role in China's domestic
development.
Shenzhen, the Special Economic Zone (SEZ) just north of Hong Kong, is
keeping a close watch on its cost structure to ensure that it does not
escalate to levels that have weakened Hong Kong's competitiveness.
Increasingly, other Chinese cities, including Shanghai, are using Hong
Kong as a model to avoid, rather than to emulate.
The Hong Kong government budget deficit at the end of the financial
year in March was a record amount that represents more than 5 percent
of projected 2003 GDP. It was far above the original estimate, mainly
because government revenue was 19.2 percent less than originally
estimated. Moody's, a major international rating agency, has estimated
the 2003 deficit to be as high as HK$90 billion. Government revenue
will continue to shrink, as the bulk of it comes from land revenue.
Since Hong Kong has no capital-gains tax, there will be an adverse
impact on revenue from salary income as Hong Kong shifts wage-earning
activities to the Pearl River Delta. The currency peg is a hindrance to
economic recovery and cannot hold, notwithstanding government
intransigence on the issue.
Local polls on top popular concerns repeatedly show democracy trailing
by wide margins major livelihood issues, such as rising unemployment,
small business bankruptcies, home mortgage foreclosures, education,
crime and public health. The chief executive has introduced a mild form
of industrial policy that will help the SAR compete in select,
strategic industries. Hong Kong is now solidly dependent on its ability
to integrate with the rest of China's economy.
The effect from exports on the domestic sector has been weakening in
the past 20 years. Less than 30 percent of the working population is
now in trade-related fields. Domestic demand is still very weak as the
local economy has yet to recover from the severe wounds of the economic
crisis and all disposal income has been soaked up by real estate costs,
depleting purchasing power even for the still employed.
China feels the need to support the stagnant Hong Kong economy to
prevent the link between Chinese sovereignty and economic depression,
but is rather helpless because Hong Kong's Basic Law, its
mini-constitution, specifically forbids Chinese interference in Hong
Kong. Yet the cause of Hong Kong's economic woes has little to do with
Chinese sovereignty. It has to do with Hong Kong's delusion about its
geopolitical free ride as a free market, made inoperative after 1997
when the United States abandoned preferred trade treatment for Hong
Kong for lack of geopolitical incentive now that it is part of China.
But the mainland economy is thriving. Hong Kong's economy is in trouble
not because it is now under Chinese sovereignty, but because Hong Kong
refuses to be Chinese. Why should China feel the need to defend
residual colonial compradorism in Hong Kong, which claims superiority
over socialism with Chinese characteristics on the mainland?
Hong Kong's self-styled central banker, Joseph Yam Chi-kwong, head of
the Hong Kong Monetary Authority, whose central bank function has in
effect been stripped by the peg, recently warned publicly in writing
that "a fiscal deficit carries the risk of leading to an interest-rate
shock if a budget package lacks credibility or community support".
Since the Monetary Authority operates under the direct control of the
Financial Secretary, one can assume that its head was speaking for the
government. The message is clear that the danger of a budget deficit is
directly related to the defense of the currency peg. In other words,
the peg is preventing Hong Kong from using a fiscal deficit to counter
the most difficult economic crisis, despite the fact that Hong Kong has
more than US$100 billion in reserves. Yam is an open admirer of Alan
Greenspan, whose style Yam tries hard to emulate, notwithstanding the
difference in background and training between the two. But Greenspan is
flooding the US, and by extension the world, with US dollars that he
can print at will, and in fact threatening to print more to fight
deflation and to support President George W Bush's $300 billion
deficit. But Yam, with US$120 billion in reserves, is unable to
tolerate an US$11 billion deficit because of the peg.
An interest-rate shock resulting from an attack on the peg in 1997-98
pushed Hong Kong dollar inter-bank rates far above their US dollar
equivalents and sent the Hong Kong economy into a tailspin. Hong Kong
is not Argentina, which has been done in with dollar debts and its
currency peg. But it is acting like Argentina with its budget crisis.
Yam also warned that the ability of Hong Kong's banks to absorb such an
interest-rate shock without adjusting their lending rates has been
eroded in recent years by greater competition and lower profitability.
Thus the government is acknowledging that a free credit market is
detrimental to Hong Kong's financial wellbeing.
On November 12, the Heritage Foundation and the Wall Street Journal
released the 2003 Index of Economic Freedom. The Index is an annual
survey of the world's economies, including country-by-country analyses
and the most up-to-date data available on foreign investment codes,
taxes, tariffs, banking regulations, monetary policy, black markets,
and more. For the ninth consecutive year, Hong Kong was named the
world's freest economy. The Heritage Foundation rates Hong Kong No 1 in
its index of economic freedom and the People's Republic of China No
127. Apparently, freedom is inversely related to growth rate.
In 2001, Hong Kong's GDP was US$162.6 billion with an export value of
$201.9 billion. The Pearl River Delta had a GDP of $258 billion with an
export value of $289.1 billion. The growth rate differential between
the two is 15:1 in favor of the Pearl River Delta. For Hong Kong to be
calling the shots for the future of the region would be the tail
wagging the dog.
Concerted efforts have been made by the government to promote and
position Hong Kong as Asia's world city. The Brand Hong Kong program,
launched in May 2001, is billed as a long-term undertaking to focus
greater international attention on Hong Kong's strengths and advantages
as the most free, open and cosmopolitan city in Asia. In July 2000, the
government established a dedicated department, Invest Hong Kong
(InvestHK), to spearhead efforts to attract inward investment. InvestHK
actively promotes Hong Kong as the premier business hub in the
Asia-Pacific region, and as the best location to access the enormous
potential of the mainland market. The government's message to the world
is that major reasons companies are attracted to Hong Kong are low and
simple taxes, the free flow of information, political stability and
security, corruption-free government and excellent communications,
transport and other infrastructure. But the real reason is the
potential of the China market.
Central to Hong Kong's long-term success is greater economic
cooperation and inter-dependence with the adjoining Pearl River Delta
hinterland, which has specific advantages and significant potential as
a consumer market, a trading hub, a manufacturing base, a services
market and as a destination for investment. An economy cannot be sold
like brands of cigarettes or diapers. If fundamentals behind prosperity
are missing, no amount of selling will make up for a delusion of
grandeur. Hong Kong will do better to spend its money where it counts,
such as a full-employment program.
The Pearl River Delta, which includes Hong Kong and Macau, is the
fastest-growing and most affluent region in China. It has a population
of about 48 million, which is more than the populations of Canada,
Taiwan or Malaysia. The Pearl River Delta has a GDP of US$258 billion -
more than Switzerland, Sweden or Austria - which would put it among the
world's top 20 economies. Hong Kong has helped fuel the Pearl River
Delta's rapid growth and development over the past two decades. Hong
Kong is the largest investor in the area, and there are more than
36,000 Hong Kong-linked companies employing more than 5 million people
in Guangdong province.
Despite the depth and breadth of these links, there is a need to boost
significantly cross-boundary cooperation and integration to build on
existing strengths and synergies and maximize the area's potential. The
emphasis is on free flows of people, goods and capital between the Hong
Kong SAR and the Pearl River Delta's major cities, which include
Guangzhou, Shenzhen, Zhuhai, Zhongshan, Dongguan, Foshan, Huizhou,
Huiyang, Huidong, Zhaoqing and Jiangmen as well as Macau. This cannot
be accomplished with Hong Kong setting itself apart as an autonomous
and non-Chinese entity.
Yet not until last July did Hong Kong's first Economic and Trade Office
in the mainland open in Guangzhou to promote economic cooperation and
to strengthen business and economic liaison between Hong Kong and the
Pearl River Delta.
The chief executive, Tung Chee-hwa, announced in his Policy Address in
October 2001 an ambitious infrastructure plan worth HK$600 billion
(US$77 billion). Of this, one-third would be spent on expanding the
railway network to make it the backbone of Hong Kong's public transport
system. From 2002 to 2007, six new rail projects costing US$13 billion
(HK$100 billion) will come on line at a rate of about one a year. The
existing railway network will be expanded by 40 percent to more than
200 kilometers. Urban areas will be connected with new towns in the
eastern and northwestern parts of the New Territories. Yet there were
no priority projects to improve linkage with the mainland until
recently. A second rail passenger boundary crossing at Lok Ma Chau will
be developed to handle the substantial growth in two-way travel and
commerce across the boundary, but no target date has been announced. By
contrast, a dedicated rail link will be built to Hong Kong Disneyland,
due to open in 2005.
Plans are being developed for another six new rail projects before
2016. These include a Port Rail line linking the container port at Kwai
Chung with the railway network in the Pearl River Delta and a
high-speed railway linking Hong Kong to Guangzhou via Shenzhen. The
year 2016 is 13 years in the future.
Over the next decade, more than 100 kilometers of major trunk roads
will be constructed and improved, including the Deep Bay Link and the
Shenzhen Western Corridor. Total investment on these projects will be
more than HK$100 billion. The proposed Shenzhen Western Corridor will
provide a strategic link between Hong Kong and Shenzhen across Deep
Bay. It is an integral part of the infrastructure being put in place to
provide more and faster cross-boundary links with the mainland to
expedite the flow of people, cargo and capital between Hong Kong and
the Pearl River Delta. Again, no target completion date has been
announced.
Hong Kong has one of the world's busiest boundary crossings. In 2001,
about 106 million people and 11.3 million vehicles crossed back and
forth between Hong Kong and the mainland. Every day, an average of
about 313,000 people and more than 31,300 vehicles cross back and forth
between the Hong Kong SAR and the mainland, with most people heading
into neighboring Guangdong province.
Container Terminal 9 (CT9), now being built on Tsing Yi Island by the
private sector, is aimed at consolidating Hong Kong's position as the
world's busiest and most efficient container port. The 68-hectare
project will have six berths and a design capacity to handle more than
2.6 million 20-foot-equivalent units (TEUs) a year. CT9 is expected to
be completed in 2004, and will bring annual total capacity at the Kwai
Chung Container Terminal Basin to more than 15 million TEUs. The new
marine basin will be able to handle the largest container ships
currently on the drawing boards. Yet the private interests behind these
projects have emerged as the most vocal and influential opposition to
logistic integration with the Pearl River Delta. A proposal for a 15
billion yuan (US$1.83 billion) bridge linking Hong Kong, Macau and the
mainland Chinese city of Zhuhai, which neighbors Macau, has sparked
bickering among Hong Kong tycoons over their special interests (see The New York of Asia: Port in a storm.
The container-terminal industry, speaking through the powerful
Hutchison Whampoa Group, opposes moves that may affect the current
governmental arrangement of privately developed container terminals.
The Hong Kong Container Terminal Operators' Association, which
represents private terminal operators, including Wharf's Modern
Terminals, CSX World Terminals and Hutchison Whampoa's Hongkong
International Terminals, while claiming not to be against the bridge
project, was quoted by the press as being opposed to "proposals that
changed the government's port development policy so as to create an
unfair situation for the existing players".
The proposed bridge would be a regional infrastructure that would be
key in integrating Hong Kong and the Pearl River Delta into one vibrant
regional economy. In that sense, would be vital to the economic
survival of Hong Kong and beneficial to Guangdong province and China in
general.
Shenzhen's port reported fast growth last year. The SEZ port handled
about 87.67 million tons of cargo and 7.62 million TEUs, representing a
32 percent increase in volume and a 50.1 percent growth in container
throughput. The figures elevated Shenzhen ahead of Los Angeles and
Rotterdam to become the world's sixth-busiest container port in 2002.
Hong Kong remained the world's busiest container port and handled an
estimated 19 million TEUs in 2002 - a 6.6 percent increase over 2001.
Shenzhen aims to increase its container-handling capacity to 11 million
TEUs by 2005 and 18 million TEUs by 2010.
Shenzhen airport's passenger and cargo traffic increased 20 percent and
35 percent year-on-year respectively in 2002. Passenger numbers jumped
to 9.35 million, while cargo volume leaped to 334,100 tons. By
comparison, Hong Kong International Airport's growth was slower -
passenger numbers grew 4.5 percent to 33.5 million in 2002, while cargo
traffic was up 19.5 percent to 2.5 million tons. Shenzhen airport
operated 120 domestic and nine international flight routes in the year,
whereas Hong Kong had 130, of which 40 were to and from the mainland.
The number of mobile-phone users in Shenzhen increased to 6.05 million
in 2002 from about 3.88 million in 2001. Some 174 fixed-line and mobile
phones are owned by every 100 residents in Shenzhen in 2002. During the
year, the SEZ's Internet user numbers surged to 1.88 million, from 1.06
million in 2001. Hong Kong had about 6.22 million mobile-phone users in
2002, up 82 percent over the previous year, representing a penetration
rate of about 91 percent. Registered Internet users in the SAR totaled
2.36 million in 2002. But Hong Kong's population is about 6.8 million
while Shenzhen's is about 4.7 million. Taking this into consideration,
Shenzhen had caught up with Hong Kong in telecommunications. Both Hong
Kong and Shenzhen have reached saturation in telecom market growth.
Future growth would come from other cities in the Pearl River Delta.
Shenzhen's gross domestic product grew 15 percent last year to 223.9
billion yuan, enabling per capita GDP to reach US$5,561 (HK$43,376),
the highest in the mainland.
Hong Kong government revenue has fluctuated wildly between 14 percent
and 21 percent of GDP in the past decade, largely affected by volatile
land lease revenue. The government's long-term fiscal strategy and tax
reform needs to address issues related to its excessive dependence on
land lease revenue and the narrow tax base.
The performance of companies involved in real estate in Asia has lagged
far behind those in non-real-estate sectors since 1997. In Hong Kong,
the five-year average return on capital employed for non-property
sectors since 1997 was 17.3 percent, compared with merely 6.7 percent
for diversified firms with both property and non-property businesses
and only 6.5 percent for real-estate companies. The listed companies in
Hong Kong that have done well since 1997 are the ones with heavy
investment in China.
Even the British-dominated Hong Kong General Chamber of Commerce has
been urging the SAR government to listen more to the business community
on economic integration with the Pearl River Delta. Chamber director
Eden Woon, a US citizen and a former US Air Force intelligence officer,
said he was pessimistic about the government's handling of issues
concerning integration with the Pearl River Delta. He complained that
businessmen generally did not have enough say in such issues as
cross-border infrastructure, environmental protection and immigration
policies. Woon called on the government to set up a "Greater PRD
Council", an unofficial forum like the Asia Pacific Economic
Cooperation (APEC) forum, in which council members would meet annually
to discuss business issues of delta integration. Under a proposal Woon
handed recently to the government, several committees would be set up
to deal with key issues. Michael Enright, co-author of The Hong
Kong Advantage and a professor at the School of Business at the
University of Hong Kong, notwithstanding the embarrassment of the
mysterious disappearance of the so-called Hong Kong advantage, echoed
Woon's views.
The proposal of Woon and Enright of an APEC-type forum, a loose
coordination body of private interests from different sovereign states,
would further reinforce the separation of the Hong Kong from the Pearl
River Delta by treating the two Chinese entities as de facto
sovereigns.
While Adam Smith realized the growing importance of capital in economic
progress, he also was apprehensive of the growing danger of its abuse.
His attitude of distrust toward the capitalist as an advisor of
government has been clearly stated: "The interest of the dealers in any
particular branch of trade or manufactures is always in some respects
different from and even opposite to that of the public. The proposal of
any new law or regulation of commerce which comes from this order of
men ought always to be listened to with the greatest precaution, and
ought never to be adopted till after having been long and carefully
examined, not only with the most scrupulous but with the most
suspicious attention."
The SARS crisis shows that far from wanting smaller government, the
public wants stronger government leadership and action, to improve
public hygiene and health services, to reduce unemployment, to help
small businesses in distress, to revitalize the economy with full
integration with the mainland.
Three things have been made clear by the severe acute respiratory
syndrome (SARS) crisis: 1) People when frightened look to the
government for help. People want more government, not less, in times of
crisis. 2) People are prepared to give up freedom for protection,
especially when they never enjoyed freedom under colonialism to begin
with. 3) Everyone wants government intervention to save the market; no
more laissez faire, which never existed under colonial command economy.
Bottom line: when things get tough, people want more socialism.
With 30,000 people lining up to apply for 3,600 openings, to call it a
crisis is an understatement. The "round up the usual suspects" approach
will not be enough.
The government has announced that US$128.2 million will be set aside to
promote Hong Kong and to encourage the return of exhibitions, to get
trade activities back to normal after the spread of the SARS crisis is
brought under control. The government has also announced it will create
21,500 training places and short-term jobs to strengthen service
training in the most SARS-affected areas. These jobs will provide
home-cleaning services for the elderly and boost environmental hygiene.
The program will cost about US$55.12 million. This public-health budget
is less than half of the government's public-relations budget. The
government will do well to reverse the priority. What is needed is a
full-employment program to improve environmental hygiene and other
community services (see On
offer: A full employment program for Hong Kong by Henry C K
Liu and L Randall Wray, March 30, 2002).
Chief Executive Tung Chee-hwa has been the target of political attack
by the so-called Democratic Party members in the Legislative Council,
blaming him for alleged incompetence and weak leadership in this period
of economic crisis. These individuals were noticeably docile and silent
during colonial rule. What kind of democratic party is it that has only
590 members, with a chairman who never faced even token elective
challenge from the party's founding in 1994 to his voluntary retirement
in 2002? And they have the nerve to accuse the chief executive, who has
faced two elections since 1997 in accordance with election procedures
stipulated by the Basic Law, of being not democratically elected? But
most hypocritical of all is that the loud opposition from this party of
590 to Hong Kong's integration with the mainland is one reason Hong
Kong is in such a state of economic paralysis.
Tung is an honest, hard-working, conscientious and patriotic leader
that any city would be lucky to have. If anything, he is excessively
democratic, trying to represent fairly all the diverse and often
opposing interests in the community and overseas. His constitutional
authority is much weaker than that of the British colonial governor,
who enjoyed total dictatorial power, unchecked by any Basic Law, and
with the colonial judiciary system in his pocket.
Hong Kong's economic woes are the result of a paradigm shift in
geopolitics, not poor leadership. Hong Kong's problems are not made by
Tung Chee-hwa, nor can he be expected to solve them without Hong Kong
waking up to the geopolitical reality that its fate is tied to its
willingness to be an integral part of the motherland. The people of
Hong Kong should unite behind Tung to let him lead Hong Kong into an
era of renewed national pride and prosperity.
|
|
|
|
|