The Coming
Trade War
By
Henry C.K. Liu
Part I: The Coming Trade War and Global Depression
Part II: Dollar Hegemony Against Sovereign Credit
Part III: Trade in the Age of Overcapacity
Part IV: Scarcity Economics and
Overcapacity
Part V: Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual
Property Rights (TRIPS)
Part VI: Trade Wars Can Lead to Shooting Wars
This article appeared in AToL
on August 20, 2005
Within US policy circles, the rapid rise of China as a major
force in the global economy is provoking a reconsideration of whether
free
trade is still in the US national interest. The prospect that China can
be a
major economic power is feeding wide-spread paranoia in the US. The fear is that developing nations led by
China and India may out-compete the advanced nations for high-tech jobs
while keeping
the low-skill, labor-intensive manufacturing jobs they already won.
China
already is the world's biggest producer and exporter of consumer
electronics
and it is a matter of time before it becomes a major player in auto
exports. Shipbuilding
is now dominated by China and aircraft manufacturing will follow. The
US Navy
is now dependant on Asia, and eventually China, to build its new ships
and
eventually the economics of trade will force the US Air Force to
procure planes
made in Asia and assembled in China.
The fear of China by the US dates back to almost two centuries
of racial prejudice, ever since Western imperialism invaded Asia
beginning in
early 19th century. Notwithstanding
that it is natural, ceteris paribus, that the country with the world’s
largest
population, an ancient culture and long history would again be a big
player in
the world economy as it modernizes, the fear that China might soon gain
advantages of labor, capital and even technology that would allow it to
dominate the world economy and gain the strategic advantages that go
along with
such domination, is enough to push the world’s only superpower to
openly contemplate
preemptive strikes against it. Furthermore, Chinese culture commands
close
affinity with the population in Asia, the main concentration of the
world’s
population and a revived focal point of global geopolitics. Suddenly,
socio-economic Darwinism of survival of the fittest, celebrated in the
US since
its founding, is no longer welcome by US policymakers when the US is no
longer
the fittest and the survival of US hegemony is at stake.
To many in the US, particularly the militant
neo-conservatives, international trends of socio-economic Darwinism now
need to
be stopped by war.
China has more than 1.3 billion people, a fifth of the
world’s population, and a work force of 700 million as against a US
work force
of 147 million. To avoid being over taken by China in aggregate
national income,
US wages would have to maintain a gap of five times over Chinese wages.
Historically-based technological and economic advantages currently give
US
workers a nominal wage gap of over 35 to 1 over Chinese workers, or 9
to 1 on
purchasing power parity (PPP) basis. This comfortable gap is not based
on current
productive differentials but rather on unbalanced terms of trade and
geopolitical incongruity left by history. Yet until wage parity is
attained,
free trade will continue to be driven by cross-border wage arbitrage in
favor
of China. But with wage parity, the
Chinese economy will be five times the size of the US economy, a
prospect not
welcomed by the US geopolitical calculations. It was the superior US
economy
that enabled the US to emerge as victor in the two world wars and to
prevail in
the Cold War.
The US is
waking up from its self delusion about free trade to
the reality that free trade never leads to balanced trade.
Free trade always works against the weaker
trading partner even with the principle of comparative advantage. The
British
promoted free trade when it’s economy was the strongest in the world. Friedrich List, in his National System of
Political Econ (1841), asserts that political economy as
espoused in
England, far from being a valid science universally, was merely British
national opinion, suited only to English historical conditions. List’s
institutional school of economics asserts that the doctrine of free
trade was
devised to keep England rich and powerful at the expense of its trading
partners and it must be fought with protective tariffs and other
protective devises
of economic nationalism by the weaker countries. Henry Clay’s "American
system" was a national system of political economy.
The US was happy to promote free trade when unbalanced trade
was in favor of the stronger US economy. Balanced trade between unequal
partners requires managed trade at the expense of the stronger partner,
which
is achieved by the weaker economy resorting to government interference
on free
trade for more favorable terms of trade.
Such government interference is driven by the
politics of trade. When managed trade is
conducted against the
weaker partner, it is economic imperialism.
When it is conducted against the stronger
partner, it is known as
leveling the playing field. Yet some in
the US are engaging in New Speak when they seek the perpetuation of
economic
imperialism by demanding a leveling of the playing field in trade with
weak,
less-developed economies.
As poor nations press the WTO to stop unfair US farm subsidy,
US cotton growers try to defuse the mounting pressure by offering help
to
growers in poor nations. The US government spends $4.5 billion annually
in
subsidy on a cotton crop with a market price of $5.9 billion, which
otherwise must
be priced more than double in the world market. This subsidy enables US
growers
to profitably export three quarters of their output and control 40% of
world
trade in cotton. What the US lost in textile manufacturing, it gains
back in subsidized
cotton export, high returns on investment in overseas textile mills and
low
consumer prices in cotton goods. Thus the current tariff war against
Chinese
textile is merely the US wanting its cake and eating it too. While $4.5
billion
is a merely pittance in the $2.4 trillion 2005 US fiscal budget, the
subsidy
has the effect of ruining the economy of the world’s poorest nations.
The National Cotton Council, a powerful trade group in US
domestic politics, while basking in the happy situation of seeing US
cotton
export increase by 350% between 1999 and 2004, from 4 million 480-pound
bales
to 14 million bales, explains that the goal of helping African growers
is “not
to make Africa a big cotton producer,” only to make the miserable lives
of poor
Africans “a little better.” It is a
strategy of protecting managed trade with welfare trade. On
the other hand, simply doubling the market
price of cotton will not help African growers, whose competitive
disadvantages
go beyond market price, and cannot be eliminated without fundamental
changes in
the terms of global agriculture trade.
While China’s economy has grown by over 9% annually for the
last couple of decades and its GDP had soared from $147 billion in 1978
to $1.6
trillion in 2004, the US GDP, $11.75 trillion in 2004, was still far
ahead by
7.4 times over that of China. Because of
the difference in population size, US 2005 per capita GDP is $41,917
while that
of China is only $1,411, a gap of almost 30 times. The US ranks 8th
in the world in per capita GDP while China ranks 111th. In 2004, US per capita income was $35,400
while that of China was $960, a 36.8 times gap.
The per capita income gap between the two
economies, while closing at a
dramatic rate, is still substantial. Despite such wide per capita
income disparity,
the US is apprehensive because it is this disparity that drains jobs
from the
US. While the narrowing of the wage disparity will slow the job drain
to China,
the resultant rise in Chinese aggregate national wealth will threaten
US
economic dominance in the world. In a neo-liberal free trade regime,
the US has
a choice of losing jobs or losing economic dominance and geopolitical
power to
China. That is the key dilemma in US
economic
policy towards China.
There is an economic basis behind US antagonistic militancy
towards China. The US won both previous world wars primarily by its
war-time
productive power. This fact has not been
forgotten by US policy-planners. While US manufacturing base has been
seriously
eroded by neo-liberal global trade in the last two decades, the
prospect of a
shooting war with China will relocate much of the lost manufacturing
back to
the US in short order. In 1942, only weeks
after Japanese attack on Pearl Harbor, President Roosevelt called for
an annual
production of 60,000 military planes, a near impossible demand
considering that
prewar annual production was only 6,000. But in 1943, some 86,000
planes were produced,
exceeding the president’s call by a third. In World War II, the US
produced
31,000 B17 and B24 long-range bombers to support strategic bombing,
reaching a
peak production rate of 50 per day. In
1941, 55,000 individual work hours were needed to turn out a B-17, and
by 1944,
this had dropped to 19,000 hours. Strategic bombing crippled German war
production
from ball bearings production to oil refineries for critically needed
gasoline.
The shortage of gasoline stalled German resistance in both the Eastern
and
Western fronts and crippled the Luftwaffe. Also, the time it took for
an
aircraft carrier to be built in the US dropped from 36 months in 1941,
to 15
months in 1945. In all, 300,000 military planes were produced in four
years of
war. Because of the production prowess of the US, Germany and Japan
simply
could not produce enough weaponry fast enough to keep up with battle
attrition
the way the Allies could. It was only a matter of time before the Axis
powers
would be defeated. A market economy is a
feeble weakling compared to a war command economy. That a war in Asia
will
relocate manufacturing jobs back to the US in large scale to get the US
economy
moving again must have occurred to the neo-con warriors who have been
controlling US policy since 2000. The
hawks in this group are betting on the gamble that China’s nuclear
deterrence
against attacks from the US can be neutralized by US strategic defense
initiative (SDI), and that the US mainland will again be safe from
attack.
Notwithstanding irrational paranoia from US militarists, the
fear of China by the US is not fundamentally based on military threat,
albeit
it has a military dimension. Henry Kissinger, arguably the greatest
living master
of geo-realpolitik, wrote on June 13
in the Washington Post: “Military imperialism is not the Chinese style.
Clausewitz, the leading Western strategic theoretician, addresses the
preparation and conduct of a central battle. Sun Tzu, his Chinese
counterpart,
focuses on the psychological weakening of the adversary. China seeks
its
objectives by careful study, patience and the accumulation of nuances
-- only
rarely does China risk a winner-take-all showdown.”
US fear of China is a reaction to the destabilizing effect on
existing, established geo-economics from the natural rise in economic
power of
a modernizing nation with a large population. It was this natural
advantage of a
large population that permitted the US and the USSR to exploit
geopolitical opportunities
to capitulate themselves into superpowers status after WWII. The
British Empire
was first and foremost a quest for population, and the wealth
associated with
it, albeit without the benefit of equality, the lack of which became
the
central weakness that deprived the empire of longevity. The lack of
equality
within the USSR was the main cause of its dissolution, not perverted
communist
doctrine. The large aggregate population of the EU is now driving its
new economic
aspirations. Japan will never be a contender for superpower status
because of
its small population and its exclusionary national culture.
Immigration is the fountainhead of economic development and sustained
prosperity. The developmental history of
the US is one of immigration. The US owed its economic rise to
immigration. Throughout
Chinese history, immigration from distant lands and foreign cultures
enriched
Chinese civilization and contributed to long periods of prosperity.
Germany benefited
greatly from the immigration of Jews and lost much from Nazi
prosecution of its
Jewish citizens. The current
anti-immigration phobia in the US and in the EU will put self-inflicted
roadblocks
in the path of these economies toward a new age of prosperity.
But the history of the US in its process in becoming an
economic superpower is instructive. As a
prosperous, internationally-engaged US evolved into a huge open market
for the
world’s developing economies, so will a prosperous, internationally
engaged
China. China, similar to historical US experience, will go through
several series
of historic policy debates over the choice between isolationism and
international engagement as its economy develops. Developing countries
should
not misconstrue isolationism as an effective strategy of
anti-imperialism. Quarantine
is a strategy that deprives the subject of any chance of developing
effective immunity
against invading viruses that eventually exposes it to more serious
vulnerability. Yet US policy on China will
impact the outcome of China’s policy debates with serious consequences. Hostility breeds counter hostility and
protectionism breeds counter protectionism. Isolation between hostile
nations
leads inevitably to war.
Kissinger went on in the same article: “With respect to the
overall balance, China’s large and educated population, its vast
markets, its
growing role in the world economy and global financial system
foreshadow an
increasing capacity to pose an array of incentives and risks, the
currency of
international influence. Short of seeking to destroy China as a
functioning
entity, however, this capacity is inherent in the global economic and
financial
processes that the United States has been preeminent in fostering.”
A China forced defensively by hostile US policy into
isolationism, a recurring tendency throughout its long history,
ironically
would lead to regional decline and instability that would quickly turn
global
in this interconnected world. The
decline of China that began in early 19th century was traceable in
part to Chinese self-imposed isolationism, in contrast to Japan’s
forced opening
to the then more technologically advanced West that led to the Meiji
Reformation. The modern history of China might have been totally
different if
Chinese isolationism had not prevailed in Chinese politics in the early
1800s,
and modernization had been allowed to proceed with needed stimulation
from mutually
beneficial contacts with the West before Western imperialism had a
chance to
take shape.
An
internationally-engaged
China will be a positive force for world peace and prosperity. As the
enormous
China market becomes reality from rising income, it will impact
traditional
international economic relations to restructure residual prejudicial
racial
enmity and Cold War geopolitical alliances and give rise to a new mode
of world
order free of residual racial phobia and obsolete ideological conflicts.
US hostility and pre-emptive strategy toward a peacefully-rising
China may be forced to fall back on ineffective US unilateralism,
devoid of
willing partners even from among its residual Cold War allies. Trade protectionism will lead to US
isolationism, a movement with a significant past in US history. Yet, as
a
superpower, the US cannot isolate itself from the rest of the world
without
severe penalties. Or to put it another way, the cost of US isolationism
is the
forfeiture of US superpower status.
Kissinger observed correctly in the same recent article that
“in a US confrontation with China, the vast majority of nations will
seek to
avoid choosing sides.” Already, normally dependable US allies such as
the UK,
the EU (particularly France and Germany), Japan, Australia and even
Israel, are
experiencing rising conflicts with US policy on China.
These nations are beginning to see US demands
for unquestioning support of its hostile policy on China as not being
congruent
with their separate national interests. Everywhere else in the world,
from Asia
to Latin America, from the Middle East to Africa, sympathy for China’s
effort
to regain its natural prominence in the world and positive response to
its effective
development strategy are mounting while appreciation for unilateral US
security
and economic policies is falling. While
the US is still a juggernaut in its coercive ability to commandeer much
of the
world’s wealth, its ability to produce wealth appears to have visibly
declined.
It is becoming increasingly obvious to some in Washington that a
military
option is the answer to arresting US economic decline that threatens US
superpower status.
Eleven of the 16 countries surveyed in June 2005 by the US-based
Pew Research Center: Britain, France, Germany, Spain, the Netherlands,
Russia,
Turkey, Pakistan, Lebanon, Jordan and Indonesia, had a more favorable
view of
China than of the US. The survey on global attitude finds that while
China is
well-regarded in both Europe and Asia, its burgeoning economic power
elicits
mixed reactions. Majorities or pluralities in France and Spain believe
that
China's growing economy has a negative impact on their own economies.
Respondents
in the Netherlands and Great Britain, traditionally free trade nations,
have
much more positive reactions to China's economic growth. Public opinion
in the
US on this issue is divided; 49% view China’s economic emergence
as a good
thing, while 40% say it has a negative impact on the US. Whatever their
views
on China's increasing economic power, European publics are opposed to
the idea
of China becoming a military rival to the US, despite their deep
reservations
over US policies and hegemony. Solid majorities in every European
nation
except Turkey regard China’s emergence as a military superpower as
undesirable.
In Turkey and most other predominantly Muslim countries, where
antagonism
toward the US runs much deeper at this time in history, most people
think a
Chinese challenge to US military power would be a good thing.
Nonetheless, there is considerable support across every
country surveyed, other than the US, for some other country or group of
countries to rival the US militarily. In France, 85% of respondents
believe it
would be good if the EU or another country emerged as a military rival
to the
US. Most Western Europeans want their countries to take a more
independent
approach from the US on diplomatic and security affairs than it has in
the past.
The European desire for greater autonomy from the US is increasingly
shared by
the Canadian public; 57% of Canadians favor Canada taking a more
independent
approach from the US, up from 43% two years ago. The US public, by
contrast,
increasingly favors closer ties with US allies in Western Europe, a
continuation of traditional US Eurocentric attitude, while the center
of world
affairs is shifting toward Asia.
China’s Dilemma:
Growth and Equality
Chinese President Hu Jintao laid out China’s economic goals
through 2020 in a May 16, 2005 address in Beijing. He vowed to
quadruple to $4
trillion the nation’s 2000 GDP of $1 trillion.
This would still be only about one-third the
size of the US economy in
2005, which itself will surely grow significantly by 2020.
Even if China’s economy quadruples, the
average Chinese will remain poor. If China succeeds in her goal, per
capita
income would rise only to $3,000. In contrast, US per capita income was
$40,100
in 2004. Thus all the talk of China overtaking the US in the near
future is
misleading.
Yet China is paying a heavy social price for fast GDP
growth. A recent survey by China’s National Bureau of Statistics found
that
earners in the highest-income bracket in cities earned 11.8 times more
than
those at the low end of the scale in the first quarter of 2005. The figures were 4.16 times in 1996 and 5.7
times
in 2000. Statistics from the Ministry of Labor and Social Security also
indicate that the richest 10% of households own 45% of private urban
wealth.
The poorest 10% of urban households have less than 1.4% of the private
wealth
in Chinese cities. Urban poverty has been increasing since the
mid-1990s
although the Chinese Government has been more successful in reducing
rural
poverty. Urban poverty is concentrated in three groups: the disabled
and
elderly without family, the unemployed and migrant workers. Given the
absence
of a sound social security system in the country’s move toward
socialist market
economy, the rich-poor gap among Chinese urbanites may become
threatening to
social stability. Popular resentment towards the rich is approaching
seismic
dimensions, unlike in the US where the rich enjoy the enviable status
of adored
celebrities. The business newspaper, China Daily, identified
“government policies
as mainly to blame for their failure to ensure equal opportunity and
fair wealth
distribution and to give enough help on a timely basis to the urban
needy.”
To the government’s credit, Premier Wen Jiabao in a press
conference on March 14, 2005 referred to Nobel laureate economist
Theodore
Schultz (1979) who maintained that rural poverty in poor countries
persists
because government policy in those countries is biased in favor of
urban residents
at the expense of rural dwellers. Schultz visits to farms and
interviews of
farmers led to new ideas, such as human capital (Investment in Human
Capital, American Economic Review 51 - March
1961). “So if we knew the economics of the poor, we would know much of
the
economics that really matter. Most of the world's poor people earn
their living
from agriculture. So if we knew the economics of agriculture, we would
know
much of the economics of being poor,” said the premier.
Yet free trade prevents government subsidy to
agriculture. China Daily suggested that the government should also be
concerned
with the urban poor. This disparity of
wealth naturally accompanies market liberalization and deregulation in
all
economies. For the Chinese economy to remain a socialist market
economy, income
and wealth disparity is the biggest obstacle that must be tackled as a
top
priority. Socialism does not reject
wealth, only the mal-distribution of it.
US Rethinks China
Trade Policy
For a decade now, debate in US policy circles has swirled
over whether China - a “socialist market economy” according to its
constitution
- is a strategic partner, a strategic competitor or a rising military
rival. What
makes China unacceptable to the US is that it is a communist country,
albeit
the neo-communism being put in place in China is increasingly free of
authoritarian effects of a garrison mentality that has resulted from US
hostility and containment during the Cold War.
Neo-communism in China is largely a strategic
response to and the
resultant consequence of expanding global neo-liberalism. Yet while the
policy
debate between orthodox communism and neo-communism has yet to be
definitively
settled in China, free trade and market fundamentalism are under
reconsideration in US policy circles. If neo-liberalism should fail and
the
global trading system freezes, the future of Chinese neo-communism will
also be
put in jeopardy. Thus US isolationism is
the unwitting ally of Chinese orthodox communism.
Paul Samuelson, a Nobel laureate economist, famed author of
the standard economics textbook and an ardent supporter of free trade,
in an
article in the Journal of Economic Perspectives (2004) suggested that
China’s
growing economic might calls into question whether free trade is a
win-win game
for the US. Samuelson said open trade
helped the US economy grow since World War II, but that competition
from abroad
drove down wages in lower-skill jobs. Over time, China and India could
displace
US high-tech jobs as well and more US wages could be forced further
down to
sustain competitiveness. Even though US consumers get cheaper
Chinese-made
goods, many US citizens could be net losers from such trade, Samuelson
wrote.
Consumer gains from lower prices are offset by worker income losses. If
globalization causes enough US citizens to suffer lower wages, the US
as a
whole loses. “It is going to become so big a problem that some slowing
down is
going to be politically popular - and has some merits,” says Samuelson,
who
estimates that from World War II to the early 1980s, increased trade
with a
revived Europe and the Pacific Basin accounted for 30% of the rise in
the
standard of living in the US, as a result of the law of comparative
advantage.
But Samuelson expects the US to gain less from trade,
outsourcing, investment, and other aspects of globalization in the
coming 30
years, possibly even lose out on a net basis. In such case, a minority
of the
US population would gain, but more would suffer lower living standards.
“The
general dogma that anything that expands globalization is good for
everyone
isn't right,” Samuelson says. And as all political scientists know,
when the
majority loses, the politics turns ugly in a democracy.
Even for free-trade guru Samuelson, free
trade in a global market economy is only desirable if its serves US
national
interest. When it does not, free trade needs to be replaced by managed
trade,
directed by a domestic command economy.
One difference between free trade then, when it was good for
the US, and now is that greater inequality has become institutionalized
in the
US, Samuelson argues. Neither the political establishment nor the
electorate is
any longer willing to spread around the benefits of freer trade to help
those in
the US hurt by globalization, as they did in the aftermath of the Great
Depression after World War II, through a progressive tax structure,
government social
spending, and transfer payments. Those harmed are usually at the lower
end of
the income and wealth ladder. This is true of individuals within the US
as well
as those in other trading nations. Free trade has worsened the fair
distribution
of income for the working class and emasculated the ability trade
unions to
command pricing power for labor, while the more educated professional
classes,
particularly those in management and finance, have gotten most of the
financial
gain. Warren Buffet, one of the most
successful investing capitalists in the world, has also been saying
that the
current US tax regime favors the rich unfairly. Inequality of wealth
and
disparity of income during the 1920s, coupled with easy credit to fuel
a
speculative debt bubble, led to the 1929 stock market crash. But it was
the
resultant pain that disproportionately fell on the unemployed and the
working poor
that led to the politics of protectionism that prolonged the Great
Depression.
A repeat of similar economic-political dynamics seems to be evolving in
the
first decade of the 21st century in the US.
Political philosophers in the past worried that in a
democracy, lower-income classes would elect politicians who would
confiscate
much of the riches of the wealthy. Proponents of democracy then guard
against
this tendency by promoting the concept of minority rights. The US
version of representative
democracy has turned that worry on its head. The cost of getting a
representative elected in a US election has escalated so much that the
rich minority
has been able to protect and enhance its interests through campaign
contributions to sympathetic if not captured politicians.
Trade was kept from emerging as an important issue in the
2004 presidential campaign. The Bush administration had taken
protective
measures during its first term in areas where key political
constituencies faced
competitive pressures, such as steel, agriculture, and lumber, but the
president remained solidly a free trader. The AFL-CIO has been pushing
for
trade with the poor nations to be “fair,” by forcing them to adopt of
international
labor and environmental standards. Fair trade has become the slogan for
both
labor and conservatives, but the practical effect of fair trade as
defined by
US labor would be no trade, as the poor country are not allowed any
pricing
power, particularly in wages and environmental protection, by the
unfair and
unequal terms of trade set by their more powerful trading partners in
the
on-going trade regime.
The labor movement in the US has been the main victim of
neo-liberal global trade. Union
membership has fallen from 31.8% of the workforce in 1948 to 12.5% in
2004. Unions have been increasingly
ineffective in protecting worker interests as US domestic politics
turns
conservative in favor of management. Yet
US labor had been in the forefront in the support for US global
anti-communist
policy and was among the most fervent supporters of every unpopular
war, from
Vietnam to Iraq, wars waged to lay the ground for a world of
neo-liberalism
that eventually came to undermine the economic interests of US labor. Traditionally, union pay and benefits helped
lift even non-union worker pay as employers had to match or better
union pay
scale to keep employees from joining unions. While union membership of
government workers increased from 25% in 1975 to 36% in 2004, the total
number
of government workers has been declining as a direct result of
anti-big-government trends since the Reagan era.
Membership in the private sector where most of the jobs are,
union membership has dropped from 21.5% in 1975 to 8% in 2004. The
industries
that have the largest declines are: manufacturing (from 36% in 1975 to
13% in
2004); transportation (from 47% in 1975 to 27% in 2004); and
construction (from
35% in 1975 to 16% in 2004). Manufacturing
workers unions suffer from both sector-wide aggregate job loss and a
drastic
drop in membership percentage of the remaining work force, as the first
waves
of outsourcing were concentrated in union plants where labor cost was
highest. While
wage arbitrage has been the driving force behind the decline of labor
unions,
the US bankruptcy regime had been the legal venue for the wholesale
abrogation
of labor contracts and employee pension obligations.
The growing disparity of income in the US translates into
low pay for place-related service jobs that cannot be outsourced. Yet the disproportionate concentration of
women, minorities, new immigrants, both legal and illegal, in these
jobs presents
opportunities for union organization.
The emergence of large employers such as
Wal-Mart, Home Depot, FedEx,
major national cleaning and telecommunication companies, and
labor-intensive
food packaging companies such as Tyson, presents identifiable
organizing targets. There is a trend in
union strategy to shift from
improving the pricing power of labor in vibrant sectors of the economy,
to
resistance against inhumane oppression in a structurally unfair
economy. This
trend will move the labor movement increasing out of progressive
economics into
radical political confrontation. The
first signs of such a shift came from the withdrawal from the AFL-CIO
by the
service workers union and the Teamsters on July 16, at the opening of
its
annual convention in Chicago, followed by the United Food and
Commercial
workers and United Here which represents hotel, restaurant and apparel
workers. These dissident unions aim to
cooperate with
other unions of laborers, farm workers and carpenters to develop
multi-union
drives against Cintas, the big nation-wide laundry company, as well as
Wal-Mart
and FedEx.
In the 2004 presidential campaign, Democratic challenger
John Kerry was careful not to disappoint US organized labor,
traditionally a
key political constituent. But labor is a captured constituent for the
Democrats, with no alternative champions in US politics.
In a tight race, the strategy was to woe the
undecided who otherwise would vote for the opponent. The opposing
presidential candidates
of both political parties proclaimed support for trade liberalization,
while
they make protectionist concessions separately to their traditional
constituents for purely tactical reasons of election politics rather
than as
strategic reforms in national trade policy, with Bush favoring big
business
such as steel and Kerry opposing outsourcing. Samuelson of course warns
that
just because free trade sometimes hurts does not mean that trade
barriers in
the form of tariffs can help. Most efforts at protectionism are
self-defeating,
Samuelson says. Nonetheless, a slowdown in globalization might be “more
comfortable,” allows the guru of free trade.
Many politicians
whose own fates are dependent on voter sentiments, are less sanguine.
Liberal
Senator Charles Schumer (D - New York), and Conservative Senator
Lindsey Graham
(R - South Carolina), with broad-based bi-partisan support reflective
of
popular sentiment, introduced the China Currency Bill (S. 295) in April
2005,
calling for 27.5% tariffs on all Chinese products sold in the US if
China does
not revalue its currency by 27.5% within 180 days of the passage of the
bill. The bill was “attached” as an amendment to the Foreign
Affairs
Authorization Act (S. 600) -- the umbrella legislative authority for
the $34
billion foreign aid program. The pro-free-trade Senate leadership
attempted to have the amendment struck down, but was defeated by an
overwhelming margin of 67-33. After that, Senator Schumer agreed to withdraw his
amendment only with the quid pro quo compromise of being
allowed to hold
a full-blown Senate Finance Committee hearing on the Chinese currency
issue and
the guarantee of a vote on S. 295 before the end of this
summer. Similar
bi-partisan legislation was also introduced in the US House of
Representatives
by Reps. Duncan Hunter (R - CA) and Tim Ryan (D - OH).
In the past
decade, Chinese exports have increased 6.5 times, from US$91.7 billion
in 1993
to US$593.4 billion in 2004. Yet 62% of that increase has been
driven by
foreign direct investment as offshore Chinese outposts of foreign
companies and
investors from the US, Europe, Japan and elsewhere in Asia. For
every
dollar China retains as a trade surplus, another $4 goes to returns on
foreign
investment. And even that dollar goes to
the Chinese central bank to buy US Treasuries to finance the US debt
economy,
and cannot be spent inside China. This is why economists say Chinese
GDP growth
is supporting the global economy, which is dominated by the dollar
economy.
China is significant not only because it is the most
populous nation with the fastest growing economy, but also because it
is one of
the poorest and thus has much prospect and room for basic growth.
Blessed with
a long history of a rich culture, the economic revival of China can
proceed at
lightning speed and bring with it a new world of plentitude. The whole
world now
wants to trade and interact with the Chinese economy because under the
current
trade regime, trade with China benefits the foreign trading partners
more than
its does China itself.
It does not matter what the exchange rate of the Chinese
currency is; China is totally free to set the exchange rate as long as
trade is
ultimately denominated in Chinese currency and Chinese prices are
competitively
adjusted according to the exchange value of the Chinese currency, even
if the
dollar remains the world’s main reserve currency for global trade. The
question
of the exchange value of the Chinese yuan in relation to the US dollar
is a
minor technical issue within the peculiar regime of dollar hegemony. It
has no fundamental
macroeconomic significance. The day will
come when this technical issue will become mute, when the Chinese yuan
will
naturally become a reserve currency for trade, reflecting the reality
of
changing global trade patterns.
As the attempt of a Chinese state owned oil company to merge
with US-based Unocal Corporation fanned protectionist passions in the
US Congress,
Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan warned senators in public
testimony not
to let their misguided frustrations with China’s economic policies
breed
reactions that would do the US economy more harm than good. What is not
generally recognized is the fact that Chinese monetary and trade
policies are
defensively driven by US policy. Proposed tariffs against Chinese goods
and
other forms of protectionism would significantly lower US living
standards and
would not save jobs in the US, Greenspan told members of the Senate
Finance
Committee.
Greenspan testified that he was “aware of no credible
evidence” that revaluing the Chinese currency “would significantly
increase manufacturing
activity and jobs” in the US. Many of
the goods sold in the U.S. with a “Made in China” label are merely
assembled in
China from parts made elsewhere in Asia. If the yuan, and therefore
Chinese
labor, were more expensive in dollar terms, those goods would be
assembled
elsewhere in Asia, at no net benefit to the US, Greenspan said. He said that Senator Schumer’s proposed
tariffs on Chinese goods “would significantly lower US imports from
China but
would comparably raise US imports from other low-cost sources of supply
in Asia
and perhaps Latin America as well. Few, if any, jobs in the US would be
protected. In this respect, CAFTA (Central America Free Trade
Agreement) is
linked to the China trade issue.
Greenspan credited the relatively free flow of goods and
services across national borders with enabling the global prosperity of
the
last six decades. “A return to protectionism would threaten the
continuation of
much of the extraordinary growth in living standards worldwide, but
especially
in the United States, that is due importantly to the post-World War II
opening
of global markets,” he said. For
lawmakers worried about US job losses, Greenspan recommended that they
bolster
job retraining programs and improve education in middle and high
schools. Nevertheless, Congress introduced
political
obstacles that successfully blocked the proposed CNOOC/Unocal merger,
forcing
CNOOC to withdraw on August 4.
US False Hope on
Yuan Revaluation
The People’s Bank of China announced on July 20 that
effective immediately the Renminbi (RMB) exchange rate will go up by
2.1% to
8.11 yuan to the dollar and that China will drop the dollar peg to its
currency. Instead, China will move to a “managed float” of the RMB,
pegging the
currency’s exchange value to a basket of currencies. In an effort to
limit the
amount of volatility, China will not allow the currency to fluctuate by
more
than .3% in any one trading day. Linking the yuan to a basket of
currencies
means China’s currency is relatively free from market forces acting on
the
dollar, shifting to market forces acting on a basket of currencies of
China’s
key trading partners. The basket will be
composed of the euro, yen and other Asian currencies as well as the
dollar.
Though the precise composition of the basket is not disclosed, it can
nevertheless be deduced by China’s trade volume with key trading
partners and
by mathematic calculation from the set-daily exchange rate.
The valuation shift to a basket of currencies is only a superficial
move because the exchange rate of the dollar in an efficient foreign
exchange
market already reflects the equilibrium of the exchange rates of major
currencies around the dollar. This equilibrium is the function of the
market by
definition, sustained by the complex workings of hedging through
derivative
trading with the dollar as the base. By a
managed float for its currency, China will enjoy the flexibility of
leading the
market, but it cannot go against the market as soon as the yuan becomes
freely
convertible, which according to current policy intention, may not
become
reality for some years.
Even when the yuan is not freely convertible under China’s
strict capital control regime, hedge funds and other speculators have
been
trading yuan for years in the derivative market and through the trading
in the
equities of companies with large operations in China, and through
trading of
Asian currencies with flexible but close links to the Chinese yuan. Companies such as Wal-Mart and Motorola,
which buy from China, and LVMH Moet Hennessy Louis Vitton, which sells
to
China, face opposite impacts from a stronger yuan, with Wal-Mart losing
on
higher import cost and LVMH gaining on more Chinese purchasing power
for
foreign goods.
Non-deliverable forwards (NDF) have been an instrument of
choice for professional currency traders. The NDF market allows traders
to
speculate on the value of currencies whose fluctuation is restricted by
government fiat. In recent years, the NFD market has grown from $3 to
$5 billion
a day. Despite the huge size of China’s $1.4
trillion-a-year economy, the volume of currency traded in Shanghai is
tiny,
averaging just under $1 billion per day. By comparison, daily currency
trading
on the Chicago Mercantile Exchange averages about $43 billion and
worldwide around
$2 trillion, with most of it transacted in London. Following the
news of
the yuan revaluation, NDF traders were taking bets for further
revaluation
ranging from 2.5% to 6% for 12-month contracts. In Singapore, one day
after the
news, one-year RMB NDF rose to about 7.64 yuan per dollar, a level that
predicts further revaluation of more than 6% by the middle of next
year. Big
international banks routinely act as counterparties between opposing
bets to
generate risk-free fees. Merrill Lynch
forecast that the renminbi would rise to 7.5 yuan to the dollar by the
end of
this year. Other analysts were more conservative. Bank of America saw
the
reminbi being held at 8.11 yuan to the dollar until the year-end, while
BNP
Paribas believed Beijing would allow the renminbi to firm to 7.9 yuan
to the
dollar by the year-end. When market participants disagree, the market
becomes
active.
Xia Bin, director general of the Financial Research
Institute under the State Council, China’s cabinet, warned speculators
against
harboring “illusions” about further revaluation, saying Beijing was
likely to
move carefully and slowly. Xia said no “clear” appreciation was likely
in the
remainder of this year. China Daily warned that expectation of a
revaluation
bigger than the 2.1% announced on July 20 “was, and will be,
unrealistic.” Yu
Yongding, a member of the monetary policy committee of the People’s
Bank of
China, the central bank, and a long-standing supporter of revaluation,
was
reported to have said he did not think China would allow dramatic
changes in
the exchange rate. “The principle is stability as well as flexibility,”
Prof Yu
said. “We don't want to encourage speculative capital inflows.”
Gradualism has
always been the hallmark Chinese economic policy. As
this article is being written, the flood
of hot money into China and Hong Kong, which had begun some two years
earlier
when the market was anticipating eventual adjustments, has continued to
accelerate.
China’s central bank repeatedly insisted with strongly
phrased announcements that there would be no more government-led
revaluation of
the renminbi, saying that the currency’s exchange rate was already
reflecting
market forces. Zhou Xiaochuan, People’s Bank governor, unintentionally
fuelled market
expectations by describing the revaluation move as “an initial
adjustment to
the exchange rate level”. The central bank later clarified that the
remark did
not mean there might be more adjustments to come. “Some foreign people
have
tried to create misunderstanding by saying this adjustment is an
initial move
and there will be more to come,” the bank said, adding that such
foreigners had
come up with such explanation "to suit their own purposes". In fact,
the bank said, the renminbi rate was being set “according to objective
rules”. “These
movements will be created by the floating mechanism and there will be
no more
official adjustments of the renminbi level,” it said, and that “in
trading
since revaluation, the renminbi had been reflecting market forces and
movements
in international currency exchange rates.” Yet
the more China stresses its determination
to resist further evaluation, the more such announcements would induce
stronger
US pressure to push the yuan higher. China is caught between market
pressure
and US political pressure in that moves to quell market pressure to
push up the
yuan will increase political pressure from the US to push up the yuan.
China
should stay quiet to avoid agitating more US political reaction and let
actions
deliver the message to the market. The
most effective way to manage the market is to make speculators lose
money.
Despite its recent rhetoric, the Chinese central bank itself
is widely seen in Beijing as favoring a more substantial revaluation
than was
announced, and is suspected of accepting the 2.1% move with open
reluctance, only
under pressure from other government departments.
Yuan credit and interest rates are mostly administered by Chinese
government policy which is normal for a national banking regime. In
such a
regime, state-owned enterprises are not affected by the short-term
market cost
of loans. That means the People’s Bank of China (PBoC), the central
bank, does
not have as much leverage over the economy as the US Federal Reserve
does. Also,
the large foreign-exchange inflows into China affect the flexibility of
PBoC to
set interest rates to manage the credit needs of the domestic economy.
A stable
currency has macroeconomic merits, but a currency kept below market
expectations produces inflationary fallouts.
In a central banking regime, it is the central
bank’s responsibility to
fight inflation with interest rate policies. But China is still in a
transition
stage between national banking and central banking. The PBoC is working
feverishly on building the finance infrastructure of monetary policy
needed for
changing China’s previous national banking regime to a new central
banking
regime. Shifting the yuan’s peg to the dollar to crawling rates pegged
to a
basket of currencies will help facilitate structural reforms that will
enable monetary
policy to act as a key tool for managing China’s economy in a central
banking
regime. Whether a shift to a central
banking regime in the context of global dollar hegemony is good for an
economy that
cannot print dollars at will is another question. A
central banking regime for China serves
only the interest of foreign capital denominated in dollars.
In market economies operating under central banking, interest
rate is the main means by which central bankers manage aggregate
demand, fight inflation
and reining in unruly financial markets when the economy overheats, and
fighting deflation and stimulating economic activities when the economy
slows. This
approach remains controversial as it can lead to liquidity traps under
certain
conditions, as in Japan in the last decade, or debt bubbles as in the
US in
recent years. Yet most neo-liberal monetary economists continue to view
interest rate policy as the best tool for managing aggregate demand in
market
economies.
In the late 1990s, China used fiscal policy to stimulate the
stalled economy and to fight deflation. Treasury-bond issuance rose,
and in
2001 the central bank encouraged Chinese banks to lend more, leading to
huge
credit expansion and an investment boom that the government now is
trying to
slow down. Fiscal stimulant worked in China and not in Japan because
the
Chinese economy had not yet been saturated with built infrastructure,
as was
the case in Japan where new unneeded expressways were built that led to
points
of no economic significance. Fiscal spending in China, even if
indiscriminately
applied, while suffering from less than optimum effectiveness, still
produced
positive impacts on the vastly underdeveloped Chinese economy.
Year-on-year annual M2 growth in China hit 21.6% in August
2003, overall bank credit grew at 23.9%, and annual fixed-asset
investment was
booming at 30% to 40%. By 2004, the government was compelled to curb
over-investment and speculation, particularly in the real-estate
sector. Over-investment
was creating overcapacity, causing a new wave of nonperforming loans
for the
banks. As monetary policy had repeatedly proved ineffective in
directing market
trends, raising rates was decidedly not a policy option, as such
broad-brush measures
would hurt the healthy sectors along with the speculative sectors.
Instead, the
government administratively managed its fiscal stimulus and imposed
planned-economy measures.
In April 2004, a “macro-economic adjustment” program was launched
targeting over-investment in key heavy industries, including steel,
cement and coal.
National Development Reform Commission (NDRC) approval was required for
all new
investment, with some on-going projects suspended in midstream. Control
over
land development rights was tightened, and banks were instructed to
curb their
lending selectively, instead of responding to market demand by lending
only to
borrowers who were prepared to pay high interests. Instead of raising
interest rates
which would put all projects in distress, the government chose to
selectively turn
off the funding source for undesirable projects. By June 2004, M2
growth was
back below 16% year on year, domestic credit growth had fallen back,
and
consumer price inflation was heading downward. The PBoC was allowed to
raise
bank rates just once, in October 2004, by 27 basis points, perhaps just
enough
to signal rates could rise. Apart from that, it has played a subsidiary
role in
macro-policy over the past 18 months.
With that experience, one would think that Chinese policymakers
would learn the lesson of the ineffectiveness of central banking with
its
fixation on keeping banks profitable at the expense of the economy, and
revert
back to a national banking regime to support industrial policy for
effective
development of the Chinese economy. Yet
the central banking movement in China, urged on by neo-liberal
economists both
inside and outside of China, is adopting a “damn the torpedoes, full
steam
ahead” mentality.
Ongoing structural changes towards a central banking regime are
leading China’s economy towards being increasingly more sensitive to
interest
rates. State-owned enterprises will be forced to manage their
operations with
an eye on quarterly earnings for repayment of short-term loans,
preventing them
from making long-range plans for growth. They are subjected to the
unpredictable short-term fluctuation of the market cost of funds, while
they are
still at a stage of undercapitalization which puts them at structural
disadvantage in the global arena of market capitalism. As more
state-owned
enterprises are privatized and sold off at fire sale prices to foreign
competitors, political pressure to keep rates low for the remaining
state-owned
enterprises wanes, making them more vulnerable to foreign takeovers.
More private
companies are accessing credit in the open market and be rate sensitive
in the
business decisions. Chinese banks now lend 11% of their outstanding
loans to
consumers who are sensitive to rate changes. Recent upstream imported
raw
materials inflation is pushing interest rates up and slowing economic
expansion
generally, rather just in overheated sectors.
In a global regime of financial liberalization
based on dollar hegemony,
it is not wise for a nation such as China, which lacks capital
denominated in
dollars, to expose its economy to market capitalism, a game in which
those with
less capital always loses.
As the yuan is not a freely convertible currency, there is
no market basis to judge if the yuan is undervalued or overvalued. The
trade
imbalance, as many economists has pointed out, is a complex phenomenon
of which
exchange rate is only a last resort compensating factor.
Besides, the US-China trade imbalance is only
nominally in favor of China, with China earning a foreign fiat currency
that
can only be spent in the dollar economy and not the yuan economy. Even then, Chinese held dollars are not
fungible as they can only be spent under political constraints imposed
by the
issuer of the dollar, as the failed CNOOC/Unocal merger has shown.
And for a currency that is not freely convertible, fixed exchange
rate has no basic effect on trade balance except as a positive
stabilizing
force against price volatility. Usually, undervalued currencies, even
if nor
freely convertible, cause domestic inflation, thus making export prices
higher
even if the exchange rate remains unchanged. This is because a cheap
currency
means more exports than imports, and the resulting current account
surplus
causes net inflows of money from overseas. These inflows add to the
monetary
base, allowing banks to lend the added money out to new customers.
Prices will
rise as a result of more money chasing goods and services which expand
at a
slower rate than money supply expansion. Domestic inflation translates
into
higher export prices. But for China, the bulk of the profit from higher
export
prices goes to pay unlimited returns on foreign capital, not to higher
domestic
wages.
Even then, there are domestic economic benefits from this
inflow of funds if it goes to facilitating domestic economic expansion
beyond
the export sector. But with dollar hegemony, these economic benefits of
China’s
trade surplus are blocked from domestic economic expansion, with all
the
dollars from the Chinese trade surplus going back into US Treasuries to
finance
the US debt bubble with which to incur more US trade deficits. It is a classic example of the poor lending
their meager wages received from the rich back to the rich to enable
the rich
to make the next pay day, with the rich demanding that the money they
pay the
poor should buy less in the neighborhood where the poor live. The US is
confusing the spread of freedom with an expanding collection of
freebies.
Dollar inflows into China were $206 billion in 2004. This
came on an accelerated basis, meaning the rate of inflow increased
toward the
end of the year. Some $101 billion flowed into China in the first half
of 2005,
a 50% year-on-year growth rate for first halves. The PBoC uses open
market
operations, mainly selling PBoC bills, to deal with these inflows.
These bills allow
the PBoC to take high-power money from the commercial banks in exchange
for bills
that the banks cannot re-lend to customers, thus stopping the creation
of new
money by banks issuing loans on partial reserve requirements. Net bill
issuance
accelerated in late 2004 to cope with dollar inflows of up to $30
billion a
month, and remained at high levels. During 2004, the PBoC withdrew a
total of
616 billion yuan ($74.5 billion) from the monetary base through bill
issuance
in the interbank market. This was the equivalent of 36.1% of forex
inflows for
the year.
In addition, the PBoC issued 196.6 billion yuan ($23.8 billion)
in PBoC bills in May 2004 to the four major state-owned banks. In
total, the
PBoC sterilized 812.6 billion yuan ($98.3 billion) during the year,
equivalent
to 47.5% of forex inflows during 2004. In the first half of 2005, there
was an estimated
increase in outstanding PBoC bills of 645 billion to 672 billion yuan,
soaking
up the equivalent of $78 billion to $81 billion worth of the forex
inflows. In
other words, the PBoC sterilized 68% to 71% of the inflows. Still, some 30% of the forex inflows went
into the expansion of the yuan money supply.
Another tactic the PBoC used to control forex reserve
inflows was higher required reserve ratios, (RRR) which banks are
required to
place with the central bank in proportion to their deposits. On
September 21,
2003, RRR was raised to 7% from 6%, and to 7.5% on April 25, 2004.
These moves
had the effect of withdrawing 203 billion yuan ($24.5 billion) and
111.2
billion yuan ($13.4 billion) from the banking system.
The PBoC also issues guidance
to banks on which sectors and
regions to lend and which to restrict credit, less to cement plants and
real
estate, and more to agriculture and small- and medium-sized enterprises
and
less to the coastal regions and more to the interior west.
China’s commercial banks are trying to meet the new
capital-adequacy ratios of 8% by January 2007 that bank regulators have
imposed. Investments in PBoC paper and most other forms of debt, which
carry no
capital requirement, are now preferable to loans to corporate
borrowers. This
is causing banks to draw back lending. China
had to pay a price to defend the yuan’s peg to the dollar. Faced with
massive
forex inflows, fast-growing bank deposits and limited profitable
investment
options, commercial banks are eager buyers of PBoC paper. The ample
liquidity
in China’s money markets drove yields low. The overnight borrowing rate
in the
market is now hovering around 1.2%, and one-year PBoC bills sold for 2%
in late
May, down from an average in 2004 of 3.2%.
For a more in-depth analysis of the exchange rate issue, see: China
steady
on the peg.
The revaluation move by China is basically a political
gesture to appease US pressure on an allegedly over-valued Chinese
currency
against the dollar. The market was expecting a lot more from China. Key
Asian
currencies will now float with the RMB yuan. As global trading began
after the initial
news of the yuan revaluation, the dollar was falling against other
major
currencies. The dollar dropped to 110.97 yen from 113.06 in New York at
the end
of the day of the news, while the 12-nation euro jumped to US$1.2196
from US$1.2108.
Minutes after China announced its decision on the evening news,
Malaysia said
it was also un-pegging its currency, the ringgit, from the dollar,
replacing it
with a managed float in a move similar to that of China. That left Hong
Kong as
the only major economy in Asia that pegs its currency to the U.S.
dollar. As
long as the yuan is still not freely convertible, Hong Kong can keep
its
currency peg to the dollar, albeit at a high cost.
Eventually, as the yuan fluctuates against
the dollar, the HK peg to the dollar will create transactional
inefficiencies
and instabilities and possibly new manipulative attacks from hedge
funds. In
South Korea, the news was received in stride, and government officials
said
they didn't expect it to have a big impact on the nation's economy, the
third
largest in Asia following Japan and China. Philippine central bank
Governor
Amando Tetangco said the move was expected to strengthen all regional
currencies, including the Philippine peso.
The yuan will now be allowed to trade in a tight 0.3 percent
band against an undisclosed basket of foreign currencies. Under the new
system,
the yuan immediately jumps to 8.11 to the dollar. But once off this
starting
block, it could, in theory anyway, rise (or fall) as much as 0.03
percent a
day, since each day’s closing price against a basket of currencies
becomes the
center of the next day's trading band. Each step is tiny, but over time
they
add up. Yet gradualism is a key to
stability.
The yuan revaluation move is a response to the Schumer-Graham China Currency Bill
(S. 295), calling for 27.5% tariffs on all Chinese products sold in the
US if
China does not revalue its currency by 27.5% within 180 days of the
passage of
the bill, which had been slated to pass before the end of the summer.
A
deal was worked out months ago to postpone a vote in exchange for a
Senate
hearing to be followed by a token gesture by China, so everyone could
claim
they won something without any real changes.
The desire to ease tension in preparation for President
Hu Jintao’s planned visit to
the
Washington in September 2005 and the pending US Treasury ruling, also
due in
the Fall, on whether China is a “currency manipulator” also played a
role in
the timing of the move. The 2.1% upward revaluation of the yuan
against
the dollar was immediately neutralized by readjustments by other Asian
currencies.<>
Managed Float
China has now officially adopted the Singapore manage float
model rather than the HK currency-board model. This is a significant
move. It
shows that the HK tycoons are losing their myopic influence on Chinese
economic/monetary policy. The smug Hong
Kong Monetary Authority has been emanating false pride of superior
monetary
wisdom by stubbornly hanging on to its currency board arrangement
pegged to a
volatile dollar mistaken as a stable currency.
The blind error left by the parting British
colonial rulers launched
Hong Kong into a bubble economy when the dollar was undervalued
throughout much
of the 1990s that burst with unprecedented disaster in 1997 as part of
the
Asian financial crisis a day after the British left Hong Kong. The same currency board regime kept the Hong
Kong economy from recovering for more than seven years after 1997 when
Hong
Kong was returned to China, until the dollar began to fall in 2004. During that painful period, , the Hong Kong
equity market was exposed to manipulative attacks by hedge funds in
1998 that
required massive government incursion in the market to foil.
By contrast, Singapore has used what is known as the “basket,
band and crawl”, or BBC, system since the early 1980s. The Singapore
dollar is
managed against an undisclosed basket of currencies of its main trading
partners and competitors. It allowed Singapore to devalue its currency
immediately after the Asian financial crisis to moderate unnecessary
pain on
its economy. John Williamson, the
neo-liberal economist who coined the term Washington Consensus, is
credited
with developing the BBC model in the 1970s. The Monetary Authority of
Singapore
asserts that the BBC policy has given it flexibility in responding to
changes
in local, regional and global conditions to maintain export
competitiveness and
control inflation. The composition of the currency basket is revised
periodically to take into account changes in trade patterns. The secret
policy
band is also regularly reviewed to ensure it remains consistent with
economic
changes, with adjustments every six months if needed.
Singapore, whose currency was first pegged to
the US dollar and then floated in the 1970s, chose the BBC regime
because of a
close link between exchange rates and interest rates in a small and
open
economy. Whether the BBC system will work for a gigantic, relative
closed
economy like China remains an open question.
The city-state of Singapore has since guided monetary policy
through exchange rates instead of directly adjusting interest rates.
This in
theory has the advantage of insulating borrowers from interest rate
risks. But
for an international finance center, exchange rate risks are equally
problematic. In recent years,
derivatives have been the instruments of choice in hedging both
interest rate
and foreign exchange rates. Inflation
has been relatively low at 2% a year since the early 1980s. Under the
BBC
managed float, the Singapore dollar has appreciated by about 20%
against the US
dollar as the dollar fell against other key currencies, although its
strong
currency policy has eased since the Asian financial crisis in 1997. In
contrast, the currency has fallen 40% against the levitating Japanese
yen.
Both China’s and Malaysia’s managed float exchange rate
systems appear broadly similar to that of Singapore, although details
remain
sketchy on their operations. But there are several obvious differences.
The
most significant is that the yuan is not freely convertible. The
currency
trading bands in China and Malaysia are narrower than in Singapore,
which means
smaller currency movements. China’s trading band is also adjusted on a
daily
basis. The fundamental difference for
China lies in the option of administrative measures to manage both
interest
rates and exchange rates, with consistency between the two less
critical
because the yuan remains not freely convertible.
The International Monetary Fund has listed about 40
countries that use some type of managed float system. But Singapore
officials
say their system is in some ways unique since it is used also to
control
monetary policy, while policy statements provide a clear indication to
the
markets of where the currency is headed. Some neo-liberal economists
have
argued that a BBC regime could provide the basis for the eventual
adoption of a
common Asian currency. Others suggest the system is not widely
applicable in
spite of Singapore’s success. Supporters
of floating exchange rates argue that Singapore has strengths, such as
a well
regulated banking and financial system and large fiscal reserves that
many
other countries do not have to support a BBC system. A managed float
system for
a freely convertible currency largely rests on gaining the confidence
of the
markets. Only if other macroeconomic policies are consistent with a
managed
float will it be a success. Many
economists and market participants believe China faces a potential
challenge in
introducing a managed float since a small revaluation would continue to
attract
speculative foreign capital in anticipation of further currency
appreciation.
As a result, China may have to widen its currency trading band
eventually to
gain market acceptance. This problem
will be magnified if and when the yuan
becomes freely convertible, which is not likely to happen until China’s
banking
system is brought up to BIS standards, in which case, the problem
shifts from
exchange rates to interest rates.
A strong yuan not
good for US economy
The US has been saying that the Chinese yuan is between
20-40% undervalued against the dollar and this undervaluation is a key
factor
in recurring US-China trade imbalance. Reality shows a very different
picture.
Let us examine the economic impacts on the US economy of a
yuan suddenly trading at 20% higher against the dollar. The first
impact will
be that prices of US imports from China will rise some 20%,
significantly pushing
up US inflation rate and dollar interest rates. High dollar interest
rates will
lift the exchange value of the dollar, pushing to problem back to
square one.
Since the bulk of US consumer goods are imported from China, a sudden
and
drastic rise in import prices of 20% will dampen US consumption of
Chinese
imports at a time when consumer spending is holding up the US economy.
There is a possibility that US consumer spending will hold
in dollar terms, but the actually amount of goods sold will be reduced,
lowering US living standards while not reducing the US trade deficit.
The
dollar value of US-China trade may remain the same, with more Chinese
goods
available for export to other countries or staying in the Chinese
domestic
market, raising Chinese living standards, and shrinking the relative
size of
the US economy. And if the US Federal
Reserve further accommodates consumer credit to absorb the rise in
import
prices to prevent a real reduction in consumer product sales, the US
trade
deficit may actual increase while US standard of living remains
unchanged. Even if US trade deficit with
China should
moderate, it would only lead to a corresponding reduction in US capital
account
surplus with China. With a slower growth
of Chinese holdings of dollars, China will buy less US sovereign debt,
pushing
US interest rates higher, possibly bursting the already precarious US
debt
bubble.
With a yuan pegged to a basket of currencies of which the
dollar is only one among several, China will have less of a need to
hold
dollars. With a drop in Chinese export
to the US, China may see its ability to buy US sovereign debt reduced.
And with
the uncertainty of the exchange values of the dollar against the other
volatile
currencies in the Chinese basket, the market price of the yuan may at
times
fall as well as rise against the dollar.
If market forces should act against the yuan
and push the dollar higher
against the yuan, US political pressure on letting the market determine
the
value of the yuan would have proved to be counterproductive toward its
goal of
a stronger yuan against the dollar. And
the adverse consequences the misguided cure can be significantly worse
than the
current malady. For one thing, with a
stronger dollar, US assets not directly related to import prices, such
as real
estate, will suffer a price collapse, adding a last straw effect to the
already
precarious housing bubble. A strong yuan
may not be a blessing for the US economy.
On the Chinese side, a stronger yuan will have to be
compensated with lower Chinese wages, or a slowdown of rising wages, in
order
that Chinese exports remain price competitive. Lower Chinese wages will
slow
the development of a vibrant Chinese market for US exports. The better option would be to let the peg
stand, and push China to raise wages. In a global market dominated by
dollar
hegemony, it is idiotic to expect that the complex problems of the US
economy
can be solved by the exchange value of one single foreign currency. Dollar hegemony by definition eliminates the
impact of the exchange value of the dollar on the dollar economy.
Hostile, ill-considered US political pressure on China’s
economic/monetary policies has opened a can of currency worms with
highly
unpredictable and possibly negative consequences for the US and the
whole
world. Just as the 1985 Plaza Accord on
the Japanese yen destroyed the Japanese export economy and brought
stagflation
to the US that led to the 1987 crash, forcing the yuan off its
decade-old
dollar peg now may well be the spark that will ignite a raging forest
fire in
the US debt-infested economy in the coming years.
The Danger of Trade
Wars
US geopolitical hostility toward China will manifest itself
first in trade friction, which will lead to a mutually recriminatory
trade war
between the two major economies that will attract opportunistic trade
realignments among the traditional allies of the US.
US multinational corporations, unable to
steer US domestic politics, will increasingly trade with China through
their
foreign subsidiaries, leaving the US economy with even less jobs, and a
condition that will further exacerbate anti-China popular sentiments
that
translate into more anti-free-trade policies generally and anti-China
policies
specifically.
The resultant global economic depression from a trade war
between the world’s two largest economies will in turn heighten further
mutual
recriminations. An external curb from the US of
Chinese export trade will accelerate a
redirection of Chinese growth
momentum inwards, increasing Chinese power, including military power,
while further
encouraging anti-US sentiment in Chinese policy circles.
This in turn will validate US apprehension of
a China threat, increasing the prospect for inevitable armed conflict.
A war between the US and China can have no winners,
particularly on the political front. Even if the US were to prevail
militarily
through its technological superiority, the political cost of military
victory
will be so severe that the US as it currently exists will not be
recognizable
after the conflict and the original geopolitical aim behind the
conflict would
remain elusive, as the Vietnam War and the Iraq War have demonstrated. By comparison, the Vietnam and Iraq
conflicts, destructive as they have been on US social fabric, are mere
minor
scrimmages compared to a war with China. US policymakers have an option
to make
China a friend and partner in a peaceful world for the benefit of all
nations.
To do so, they must first recognize that the world can operate on the
principle
of plentitude and that prosperity is not something to be fought over by
killing
consumers in a world plagued with overcapacity.
(End of series)
|