Critique of Central Banking
By
Henry C K Liu
Part I: Monetary
theology
Part II:
The European Experience
Part III-a: The US
Experience
Part III-b: More on the US
experience
Part III-c: Still more on the US experience
This article appeared on AToL
on December 2, 2002
The selection of the chairman of the US Federal Reserve Board
of Governors, who serves four-year terms, is a political process
closely linked to ideological preference, subject to Senate
confirmation, much like the appointment of the chief justice of the
Supreme Court. White House and Treasury support for the chairman is of
critical importance for the chairman's exercise of leadership over
Board members, who are known for their independence.
The late Arthur Burns (Fed chairman 1970-78) abolished full
transcripts
of the Fed Open Market Committee (FOMC) meetings after the Freedom of
Information Act was enacted by Congress in 1975. The transcripts
traditionally were kept secret for five years before public release,
but they provided a rich and reliable source for historians who tried
to decipher the decision-making process in monetary policy. The
interrupted practice was revived after Burns' second term expired
without reappointment by president Jimmy Carter. Under a policy
announced on January 19, 2000, the FOMC, shortly after each of its
meetings, issues a brief statement that includes its assessment of the
risks in the foreseeable future to the attainment of its long-run goals
of price stability and sustainable economic growth. Nevertheless, the
Fed continues to enjoy a level of secrecy on its deliberation that is
the envy of the Central Intelligence Agency. Industrialist Henry Ford
was reported to have said: "It is well enough that the people of the
nation do not understand our banking and monetary system for, if they
did, I believe there would be a revolution before tomorrow morning."
Ford of course was a paternalistic entrepreneur with latent
socialist
leanings whose dislike of the "money trusts" was as passionate as any
diehard communist's, albeit from a different angle. Ford understood
that to sell his mass-produced products, high wages were necessary, for
which he professed a vested interest in promoting (he doubled the
market wage to US$5 a day, forcing the rest of the auto industry to
follow suit). And he viewed labor unions as having long-term effects in
holding wages down with their insistence on short-term gains that
hampered production efficiency.
Ford partisans believe to this day that the reason industrial
unions
are tolerated by management is that management knows that the long-term
effect of unionism is to moderate the rise of labor costs. Unionism has
been institutionalized in industrial capitalism in the role of the
factory foreman, with the job of maximizing labor productivity, which
means increasingly lower labor cost per unit of production. Union
chiefs are often invited to sit on corporate boards of directors, not
to influence management but to deliver management's message to the
union rank and file that wage increases can only come from company
profits, and not from any restructuring of the basic relationship
between labor and capital. What Ford opposed as fervently as he did
industrial unionism was the type of financial manipulation that created
General Motors through predatory mergers and acquisitions. This view
has come to be known as Fordism, which also influenced early Soviet
industrialization strategy.
Burns, a conservative Austrian-born economist from Columbia
University,
was appointed Fed chairman by president Richard Nixon in 1969. Between
1953 and 1956, he served as chairman of the Council of Economic
Advisors under president Dwight Eisenhower. He was known as the "No 1
inflation fighter". Burns was reportedly not well liked at the Fed by
his colleagues nor by members of his profession. Many accused him of
being intellectually dishonest.
The Burns era was the most opportunistically political in Fed
history,
with Burns' mistimed economic pump-priming designed merely to ensure
Nixon a second term, by engineering money growth of a monthly average
of 11 percent three months before the election from a monthly average
of 3.2 percent in the last quarter of 1971. Nixon's second term was
nevertheless aborted by political complications arising from the
Watergate scandal, leaving Gerald Ford in the White House. The economy
was left to pay for the pre-election boom with runaway inflation that
compelled the Fed to tighten with a vengeance, which produced a long
and painful post-election recession that in turn contributed to Ford's
defeat by Carter. The Fed as an institution above politics has yet to
recover fully from the rotten smell of 1972. Burns' sordid catering to
Carter in hope of securing a reappointment for a third term was a
contributing factor to the Carter inflation. And Carter's defeat by
Ronald Reagan was in no small measure caused by his appointment of Paul
Volcker as Fed chairman. Some said it was the most politically
self-destructive move by Carter.
Volcker, having served four years as president of the New
York Federal
Reserve Bank, replaced G William Miller as Federal Reserve Board
chairman on July 23, 1979. Volcker, as assistant secretary under
Treasury secretary John Connally in the Nixon administration, played a
key role in 1971 in the dismantling of the Bretton Woods international
monetary system formulated by 44 nations that met at Bretton Woods, New
Hampshire, in July 1944. Under that system, as worked out by John
Maynard Keynes, representing Britain, and Harry Dexter White, an
American who later in the McCarthy era was accused unfairly of having
been a communist, each country agreed to set with the International
Monetary Fund (IMF) a value for its currency and to maintain the
exchange rate of its currency within a specified range. The United
States, as lead country, pegged its currency to gold, promising to
redeem dollars for gold on demand at an official price of $35 an ounce.
All other currencies were tied to the dollar and its gold-redemption
value. While the value of the dollar was tied strictly to gold at $35
an ounce, other currencies, tied to the dollar, were allowed to vary in
a narrow band of 1 percent around their official rates which were
expected to change only gradually, if ever. Foreign-exchange control
between borders was strictly enforced, the mainstream economics theory
at the time being inclined to consider free international flow of funds
neither necessary nor desirable for facilitating trade.
Nixon was forced to abandon the Bretton Woods fixed exchange
rate
system in 1971 because recurring lapses of fiscal discipline on the
part of the United States had made the dollar's peg to gold
unsustainable. By 1971, US gold stock decline by $10 billion, a 50
percent drop. At the same time, foreign banks held $80 billion, eight
times the amount of gold remaining in US possession. Ironically, the
problem was not so much US fiscal spending as the unrealistic peg of
the dollar to $35 gold.
The Smithsonian Agreement concluded in December 1971 between
the Group
of Ten of the IMF at a meeting at the Smithsonian Institute in
Washington, DC, restored the major currencies to fixed parities but
with a wider margin, plus or minus 2.25 percent of permitted
fluctuation around their par values. The dollar was effectively
devalued by about 8 percent and the dollar price of gold increased to
$38 per ounce. Sterling was set at $2.6057. Improved telecommunications
and computerized fund-transfer techniques allowed speculators to move
funds quickly and efficiently around the world in anticipation of
foreign exchange fluctuation and intervention, making it difficult to
support even this widened band, which was eventually suspended.
Foreign-exchange control was largely abandoned by most governments by
the late 1970s, bringing forth the rapid growth of a largely
unregulated international exchange market, along with a globalized
capital and credit market. Foreign-exchange fluctuation increasingly
became subject to financial market pressures not directly related to
trade. It has now become a source of high speculative profit for many
institutions and hedge funds. The huge size of the market has reduced
the effectiveness of central-bank intervention in maintaining the
exchange value of currencies.
Miller, after only 17 months at the Fed, had been named
Treasury
secretary as part of Carter's desperate wholesale cabinet shakeup in
response to popular discontent and declining presidential authority.
After isolating himself for 10 days of introspective agonizing at Camp
David, Carter emerged in early summer to make his speech of "crisis of
the soul and confidence" to a restless nation. In response, the market
dropped like a rock in free fall. Miller was a fallback choice for the
Treasury, after numerous other potential appointees, including David
Rockefeller, declined personal telephone offers by Carter to join a
demoralized administration.
Carter felt that he needed someone like Volcker, an
intelligent if not
intellectual Republican, a term many liberal Democrats considered an
oxymoron, who was highly respected on Wall Street if not in academe, to
be at the Fed to regenerate needed bipartisan support in his time of
presidential leadership crisis. Bert Lance, Carter's chief of staff,
was reported to have told Carter that by appointing Volcker, the
president was mortgaging his own reelection to a less than sympathetic
Fed chairman.
Volcker won a Pyrrhic victory against inflation by letting
financial
blood run all over the country and most of the world. It was a toss-up
whether the cure was worse than the disease. What was worse was that
the temporary deregulation that had made limited sense under conditions
of near hyper-inflation was kept permanent under conditions of restored
normal inflation. Deregulation, particularly of interest-rate ceilings
and credit market restrictions, put an end to market diversity by
killing off small independent firms in the financial sector since they
could not compete with the larger institutions without the protection
of regulated financial markets. Small operations had to offer
increasingly higher interest rates to attract funds while their
localized lending could not compete with the big volume, narrow rate
spreads of the big institutions. Big banks could take advantage of
their access to lower-cost funds to assume higher risk and therefore
play in higher-interest-rate loan markets nationally and
internationally, quite the opposite of what Keynes predicted, that the
abundant supply of capital would lower interest rates to bring about
the "euthanasia of the rentier".
In the longer term, Keynes may still turn out to be
prescient, as the
finance sector, not unlike the transportation sectors such as
railroads, trucking and airlines in earlier waves, or the communication
sector such as telecom companies, has been plagued by predatory mergers
of the big fish eating the smaller fish, after which the big fish,
having grown accustomed to a unsustainably rich diet that has damaged
their financial livers, begin to die from self-generated starvation
from a collapse of the food chain.
High real interest rates ahead of inflation rate moved wealth
from
borrowers to lenders in the economy and from bottom to top in the
wealth pyramid. Moreover, the impact of high interest rates modifies
economic behavior differently in different income groups and even on
different activities within the same individual. When the prime rate
for some banks exceeded 20 percent in 1980, credit continued to expand
explosively in sectors where price appreciation occurred at a much
higher rate, such as in real estate. High rates only work to slow
credit expansion if the rates are ahead of inflation.
The Fed has traditionally never been prepared to raise
interest rates
too abruptly, trying always to prevent inflation without stalling the
economy excessively, thus resulting in interest rates often trailing
rampant inflation. The market demand for new loans, or the pace for new
lending, obviously would not be moderated by raising the price of
money, as long as the inflation/interest gap remain profitable. Yet
bank deregulation diluted the Fed's control of the supply of credit,
leaving price as the only lever. Price is not always an effective lever
against runaway demand, as Fed chairman Alan Greenspan was also to find
out in the 1990s. Raising the price of money to fight inflation is by
definition self-neutralizing because high interest cost is itself
inflationary. Deregulation also allows the price of money to allocate
credit, often directing credit to where the economy needs it least,
namely the speculative arena.
The Fed might have had in its employ a staff of very
sophisticated
economists who understood the complex multi-dimensional forces of the
market, but the tools available to the Fed for dealing with market
instability was by ideology and design single-dimensional.
Interest-rate policy was the only weapon available to the Fed to tame
an aggressively unruly market that increasingly viewed the Fed as a
paper tiger.
In the early weeks of 1980, the Consumer Price Index (CPI)
was 17
percent, prime rate was 16 percent and rising, and gold hit as high as
$875 an ounce. Having told the House Banking Committee on February 19
that credit controls do not deal with the "basic causes of inflation",
the Fed chairman Volcker announced on March 14 a program of emergency
credit controls not only on commercial banks, but also on money-market
mutual funds and retail companies that issue credit cards. Banks would
be limited to 9 percent credit growth instead of the 17 percent in
February. Only a week earlier, the FOMC, trailing inflation data, was
forced to raised the Federal Funds Rate (FFR) target to 18 percent.
The economy crash-landed abruptly in response. The gross
domestic
product (GDP) shrank 30 percent within three months. Consumer credit,
instead of growing by $2 billion a month, shrank by $2 billion a month.
Money dried up suddenly, leaving many otherwise healthy projects
hanging in midstream. Construction loans could not roll over into
permanent mortgages. Asset prices fell below their collateralized
value, causing loans to be "underwater" overnight, giving otherwise
conscientious borrowers an incentive to walk away from their debt
obligations. Insolvency became widespread, with financial dead bodies
strewn on the sidewalks of every city. For the first time in recent
history, a Democrat in the White House pushed the country into
recession, and in an election year.
Senate Democrat minority floor leader Robert Byrd of West
Virginia
expressed concern but was rebuked by senator William Proxmire, Senate
Banking Committee ranking Democrat from Wisconsin, who gave a technical
lecture on the iron law governing inflation and interest rates, a TINA
(there is no alternative) argument. More unemployment and bankruptcies,
while painful, had to be accepted as needed medicine.
Then the Hunt brothers' speculative silver bubble burst,
punctuated by
the silver price dropping from $50 an ounce to $10. The banks had lent
the Hunts $800 million to corner speculatively a silver cartel, 10
percent of all bank lending in the past two months, at rising interest
rates that inched toward 20 percent. By March 31, the Hunts defaulted
on their future contracts because they were unable to roll over the
short-term loans, partly due to credit control. To prevent systemic
panic, Volcker engineered a private bailout from the 11 banks with a
new $1.1 billion loan, similar to the Fed-engineered Long Term Capital
Management (LTCM) bailout in 1998. The Hunt brothers were wiped out of
their billion-dollar equity and had to file for bankruptcy, but their
banks were saved from the fate of having to raise more capital to cover
non-performing loans that magically became performing with the wave of
the Fed's unseen hand. The Fed waived credit-control rules imposed only
two weeks earlier. "Moral hazard" became a loud murmur heard from
shaking heads everywhere. The Fed had in the past refused requests for
bailouts for Chrysler, New York City, Midwestern grain farmers,
Lockheed, Pan Am Airways, etc, in the real economy, but it seldom
refuses to bail out the financial markets. TINA, together with the "too
big to fail syndrome", was after all a selective doctrine applicable
only to the Fed's political constituents.
Volcker, as chairman of the Fed, adopted a "new operating
method" for
the Fed in 1980 as a therapeutic shock treatment for Wall Street, which
seemed to have been conditioned by Burns' brazen political opportunism
to lose faith in the Fed's political will to control inflation. The new
operating method, by concentrating on monetary aggregates, and letting
it dictate FFR swings within a range from 13-19 percent, to be
authorized by the FOMC, was an exercise in "creative uncertainty" to
shock the financial market out of its complacency about interest-rate
stability and gradualism. There had been a traditional expectation that
even if the Fed were to raise rates, it would not permit the market to
be volatile. The banks could continue to lend as long as they could
profitably manage the gradual rise in rates. Under the new operating
method, the banks were exposed to risks that interest rates might
suddenly and drastically go against even their short-term credit
positions. Also, banks had been expanding new loans beyond the growth
of deposits, by borrowing shorter term funds at lower interest rates.
This practice was given the benign name of "managed liability",
allowing banks to profit from interest-rate spreads over the yield
curve, which had seldom if ever been allowed by the Fed to get
inverted, that is with short-term rates rising higher than longer-term
rates. This practice, known as "carry trade" in bank parlance, when
internationalized, eventually led to the Asian financial crisis of 1997
when interest-rate and exchange-rate volatility became the new
paradigm.
The Fed's new operating method would greatly increase the
banks' risk
exposure. On top of it all, Volcker also set an additional 8 percent
reserve on borrowed funds for lending. The new operating method worked
against the traditional mandate of the Fed, which, as a central bank,
was supposed to be responsible for maintaining orderly markets, which
meant smooth, gradual changes in interest rates. The new operating
method was a policy to induce the threat of short-term pain to
stabilize long-term inflation expectations.
Every economist agrees that when money growth slows, market
interest
rates go up. The trouble with the use of the FFR target to control
money supply was that it had to be set by fiat, which exposed the Fed
to political pressure. A case could be made, and was frequently made,
that the Fed's FFR target tended to be self-fulfilling prophecy rather
than a device to manage future trends. High FFR targets deflate while
low targets inflate, and there is little argument about that
relationship. But there is plenty of argument about the Fed's
projection ability on the economy. History has shown that the Fed, more
often than not, has made wrong decisions based on faulty projection.
The new operating method would let the monetary aggregates set the FFR
targets scientifically and provide political cover for the FOMC members
if the FFR target needed to go to double digits. This was monetarism
through the back door, not by intellectual commitment, but by political
cowardice.
The FOMC, as formed by the Banking Act of 1933, did not
include voting
rights for the Fed Board of Governors. This was changed in the Banking
Act of 1935 to include the Board of Governors and amended again in 1942
to the current voting structure, which consists of the seven members of
the Board of Governors, the president of the New York Fed and four
other district Fed presidents who serve on a rotating basis. These
legislative changes were an attempt to centralize the Fed's
policy-making while preserving input from Federal Reserve bank
presidents. While Federal Reserve bank presidents vote on a rotating
basis, they all attend each FOMC meeting and contribute to the debate
on monetary policy. The early FOMC at first met quarterly to consider
its business; today, the FOMC meets eight times a year, but decisions
regarding monetary policy are not limited to formal meeting dates, as
the chairman can call a teleconference of the FOMC at any time.
This system for making monetary policy - incorporating
regional
viewpoints in the making of national policy - is one of the hallmarks
of Fed structure. From the beginning of the Fed, opinions differed on
the need for, and the location of, geographic representation on the
Board, and the debate continued with the formation of the FOMC. In
1964, congressional hearings were held that considered abolition of the
FOMC. The importance and dominance of national policy over regional
considerations are now generally accepted. The FOMC would not alter
monetary policy to address an economic concern pertinent to just one
district. Regional input plays an increasingly peripheral role in the
formulation of that policy. By extension, as the Fed began to support
the Treasury's strong-dollar policy as a matter of national security
under Robert Rubin in the 1990s, dominance of US internationalist
policy over district concerns became institutionalized. The rust belt
and the agricultural exporting states would have to restructure the
local economy to survive.
Prior to 1970 and the arrival of Arthur Burns as the chairman
of the
Federal Reserve Board, the FOMC made comments in a set pattern, known
as a "go-around". Burns was not in sympathy with this formalized
process, as he was not a consensus builder when it came to making
monetary policy, as was his long-serving predecessor, William McChesney
Martin, who listened to everyone's input before making his decision. To
save himself the unpleasant prospect of having to ignore district views
face to face, Burns decided it would be a more efficient use of the
FOMC's time to have the reports on district conditions prepared in
advance and compiled for the Committee's edification. Burns' directive
formalized and broadened the information-gathering process, and thus
was born the Red Book, which was the predecessor to the Beige Book.
Aside from the color of their covers, the Red and Beige books
differed
in one important way: the Red Book was prepared for policy makers only,
and was not intended for public consumption. The Red Book became public
in 1983 after a request by the longtime representative from the
District of Columbia, Walter Fauntroy, for public release of the Green
Book, which contains the Fed's closely held national models and
economic forecasts. The Board deemed this unwise and the Red Book was
offered in its place. To mark the change, the color red was dropped in
favor of beige (it was for a time also called the Tan Book). To detract
from the implied importance of the document in FOMC policy-making, the
public release of the Beige Book was timed for two weeks prior to an
FOMC meeting, so that the media and others would recognize that the
information was not timely and, therefore, did not have a major
influence on policy. So much for policy transparency in a democratic
society.
The Fed protects itself from criticism of ideological bias in
its
decision-making by depriving the public and its critics of timely
information paid for by tax money. The Fed remains above criticism
because its decisions are always based on more recent information on
the economy than that available to the market, decisions that the
market would understand only if it had the same information, although
the rationale for depriving the market of the latest information in the
age of instant communication has never been made clear.
The Federal Advisory Council (FAC) of the Fed is unique in
that it is a
big bank lobby that officially advises the Fed, a government
institution owned by the banks. It meets in secrecy four times a year
with Fed officials to give the banking industry an inside track on
influencing Fed deliberation, if not decisions. The since-declassified
minutes of the FAC show that four weeks before the Fed announced its
new operating method, the FAC had recommended to the Fed a "review" of
its traditional operating method, before the president was even alerted
of the Fed's deliberation and final decision to adopt a new operating
method. Carter was totally in the dark about the impending
high-interest-rate policy with which the Fed was going to hit his
administration in an election year.
The Fed program of Emergency Credit Controls announce on
March 14,
1980, affected not only commercial banks, but also money-market mutual
funds and retail companies that issue credit cards. Banks would be
limited to 9 percent credit growth instead of the 17 percent in
February. By April, the Fed was shocked by data that money was
disappearing from the financial system at an alarmingly rapid rate. The
last two weeks in March saw more than $17 billion vanish, representing
an annualized shrinkage of 17 percent. Money was evaporating from the
banking system as credit dried up and borrowers paying off their debts
at Carter's urging: to save the nation from hyper-inflation through
personal restraint on consumption. Another cause was the shift of bank
deposits to three-month T-bills that were paying 15 percent.
Volcker's new operating method adopted six months earlier now
faced a
critical test. According to monetarist theory, the Fed now must pump up
bank reserves to stimulate money growth. But in practice, Volcker and
the FOMC were to apply monetarism, which by definition must be a
long-term proposition, to short-term turbulence, and in the process
undermined their own earlier efforts to fight hyper-inflation and,
worse, destabilized the economy unnecessarily. When mortals play god,
other mortals die unnecessarily.
On May 6, 1980, with the New York Fed's Open Market Desk
furiously
trying to brake the money-supply shrinkage now in raging progress,
pumping more bank reserves by buying government securities and creating
new "high power" money by increasing bank reserves, interest rates fell
abruptly. The FFR dropped 500 basis points in two weeks, from 18 to 13
percent, the bottom of the FOMC range, and was actually trading below
the FOMC target.
The Fed was in danger of losing control of its FFR target and
jeopardizing its credibility. The New York Fed notified the FOMC that
it could continued to follow the new operating method by injecting more
reserves or to tighten up the supply of bank reserves to get the FFR
back up to 13 percent, but it could not do both, any more than a train
could go in opposite directions simultaneously. Volcker opted for
continuing the new operating method and staged an emergency telephone
conference of the FOMC to authorize a new low FFR target of 10.5
percent, down from 13 percent.
Market conditions were such that the interest rate falling
below 10
percent would mean negative interest adjusted for inflation, which
would start another borrowing binge. The fundamental fault of
monetarism was being exposed by real life. The claim that stabilizing
the money supply would also stabilize interest rates was inoperative.
In reality, stabilizing one destabilized the other in a fast-reacting
dynamic market.
Desperate, the Fed, with concurrence from an even more
panic-stricken
Carter White House, started to dismantle Emergency Credit Controls as
fast as administratively possible, so that demand for credit would not
be artificially hampered, in hope of making market interest rates rise
from more borrowing. Still it took until July 1980 before the last of
the controls were lifted. In April, the New York Fed injected
additional reserves into the banking system at an annualized rate of 14
percent, and in May at 48 percent annualized rate in non-borrowed
reserves.
It was obvious Volcker panicked, spooked by the sudden
economic
collapse touched off by his own credit-control program. By the last
week of July, the FFR fell below the discount rate and hit 8.5 percent.
For one trading day, it dipped to 7.5 percent and for a time the Fed
lost control. The short-term rate that monetary policy regulates most
directly was free-floating on its own. With the FFR below the discount
rate, the FFR could fall to zero by banks responding to market forces.
So the pressure to lower the discount rate was overwhelming. The
financial markets had never seen anything like it. The FFR dropped from
20 percent in April to 8.5 percent in 10 weeks. In the autumn of 1979,
the Fed had seized the initiative to push the price of money up 100
percent to fight inflation. Now, barely seven months later, the Fed
allowed the price of money to fall even more rapidly to reverse a
money-supply shrinkage. The recession abruptly ended by the Fed's
overreaction and Volcker was facing a worse inflation problem than when
he first became chairman in July 1979. Many businesses went under
during this brief period of illiquidity, but the banks were dancing in
the streets with windfall profits.
The experience put the Fed back on its old path: focusing on
interest
rates and not money-supply numbers and vowing again to focus only on
the long term. Yet for the long term, money supply was the correct
barometer, while for the short term, interest rate was the appropriate
tool. The Fed did not seem to have learned anything, despite having
made the nation pay a very costly tuition.
In 2000, when the Humphrey-Hawkins legislation requiring the
Fed to set
target ranges for money-supply growth expired, the Fed announced that
it was no longer setting such targets, because money-supply growth did
not provide a useful benchmark for the conduct of monetary policy.
However, the Fed said, too, that "... the FOMC believes that the
behavior of money and credit will continue to have value for gauging
economic and financial conditions". Moreover, M2, adjusted for changes
in the price level, remains a component of the Index of Leading
Indicators, which many private-sector market analysts use to forecast
economic recessions and recoveries.
To make the case that money supply, rather than interest
rates, moves
the economy, one would have to assert that the money supply affects the
economy with zero lag. Such a claim can only be validated from the
long-term perspective. For the long term, six months may appear as near
zero, just as macro-economists may consider the bankruptcy of a few
hundred companies mere creative destruction, until they find out some
of their own relatives own now worthless shares in some of the bankrupt
companies. Targeting the money supply produces large sudden swings in
interest rates that produce unintended shifts in the real economy that
then feed back into demand for money. The process has been described as
the Fed acting as a monetarist dog chasing its own tail.
By September 1980, data on August money supply revealed that
it had
grown by 23 percent. Monetarists, backed by the banks, clamored for
interest-rate hikes dictated by money-supply data. Having been burned a
few months earlier, the Fed was not again going to abandon its
traditional interest-rate gradualism focus and again let the
money-supply tail wag the interest-rate dog. Nevertheless, the Fed
raised the discount rate from 10 to 11 percent on September 25, still
way behind both monetary aggregate needs and the inflation rate.
Carter, falling behind in the polls, attacked the Fed for its
high-interest-rate policy in the final weeks of his reelection campaign
in October. Reagan opportunistically and disingenuously defended the
Fed's unfair scapegoating by Carter. After the election, the Fed
continued its high-interest-rate policy while Reaganites were
preoccupied with transition matters. By Christmas, prime rate for some
banks reached 21.5 percent.
The monetary disorder that elected Reagan followed him into
office.
Carter blamed inflation on prodigal popular demand and promised
government action to halt hyper-inflation. Reagan reversed the blame
for inflation and put it on the government. Yet Reagan's economic
agenda of tax cuts, defense spending and supply-side economic growth
was in conflict with the Fed's anti-inflation tight-money policy. The
monetarists in the Reagan administration were all longtime right-wing
critics of the Fed, which they condemned as being infected with a
Keynesian virus. Yet the self-contradicting fiscal policies of the
Reagan administration (balanced budget despite massive tax cuts and
increased defense spending) overshadowed its fundamental
monetary-policy inconsistency. Economic growth with shrinking money
supply is simply not internally consistent, monetarism or no
monetarism.
The Reagan presidency marked the rehabilitation of classical
economic
doctrines that had been in eclipse for half a century. Economics
students since World War II had been taught classical economics as a
historical relic, like creationism in biology. They viewed its theories
as negative examples of intellectual underdevelopment attendant with a
lower stage of civilization. Three strands of classical economics
theory were evident in the Reagan program: monetarism, supply-side
theory, and phobia against deficit financing (but not deficit itself).
Yet these three strands are mutually contradictory if pursued equally
with vigor, what Volcker gently warned about in his esoteric speeches
as a "collision of purposes". Supply-side tax cuts and investment-led
economic growth conflict with monetarist money-supply deceleration,
while massive military spending with tax cuts means budgetary deficits.
Voodoo economics was in full swing, with the politician who coined the
term during the primary, George Bush, now serving as the
administration's vice president. Reagan, the shining white knight of
small-government conservatism, left the US economy with the biggest
national debt in history.
Volcker was a man of far superior intellect to most at the
Reagan White
House except Martin Feldstein, chairman of the Council of Economic
Advisors, whose incisive warnings against budget deficits were ignored
by the White House. Volcker began to gain control over the
administration on monetary policy through his rationality and adherence
to reality, which allowed him to dominate events over the White House's
doctrinaire "rational expectation": the theory that rational market
participants always anticipate government policy and adjust their
actions accordingly.
By March 1981, the FFR, which reached a historic high of 20
percent in
January, had been pushed below 16 percent by the FOMC. The bond market
refused to go along. Long-term rates went up. Henry Kaufman, a highly
respected Wall Street guru, blamed it squarely on Reagan's expansionary
tax cuts. The money-supply component M1 started to expand rapidly in
April. Bond traders feared a Fed tightening with interest rate hikes,
thus depressing the price of outstanding bonds with lower rates.
Traders, many of whom have been exposed to simplified summaries of
Milton Friedman's monetary theory in the trade press, began bidding up
rates in anticipation. "Rational expectation" was working against the
Reagan economic plan instead of with it. The Fed pleaded with market
specialists not to jump to extreme conclusions based on a two-week
change in the supply of money, that the Fed was no longer using the new
operating method. But the bond market, having simplistically embraced
Friedman's monetarist views to the point of conditional reflex, reacted
nervously to M1 data and the Fed reacted nervously to the bond market.
Monetarism was made real not by theoretical logic but by market herd
instinct.
The daily column "Credit Markets" in the Wall Street Journal
is a
gossip page on the private world of bond traders that lets the reader
eavesdrop on a no-nonsense summary of Fed-watcher analysis. Fed
economists also read the column religiously just as Broadway stars read
opening-night reviews or socialites read society pages. It is the
trade's main source of information on market sentiment and it
legitimizes an arcane abstraction as reality to the participants. To
participate in this esoteric media dialogue, one must subscribe to
certain basic assumptions, lest the material sound incomprehensible.
The assumptions are that the Fed's first priority is to maintain
interest-rate stability, orderly markets and "hard money", above
economic growth or full employment or any such socialist claptrap.
When bond prices fell in April 1981, the Fed discreetly
yielded to the
judgment of the bond market, instead of guiding it. Though economic
recovery was nowhere in sight, the Fed again changed direction in its
interest-rate policy and moved rates upward. The Fed was once more
forced to follow the market instead of leading it, thus merely
reinforcing market trends instead of preventing market excesses, as it
has always done throughout its history and continues to do today. As
the Reagan program moved through Congress, gathering popular enthusiasm
and legislative momentum, the bond market went into seizure. The Fed
was faced with the option of losing control of the FFR or cutting more
drastically the money supply and push up interest rates.
A tightening of money supply alongside a budget deficit is a
sure
recipe for a recession. Long-term high-grade corporate and government
bonds were seeing their market rates jump 100 basis points in one
month. New issues had difficulty selling at any price. The possibility
of a "double dip" recession was bandied about by commentators, as it is
now. The Fed was attacked from all sides, including the commercial
banks, which held substantial bond portfolios, and White House
supply-siders, despite the fact that everyone knew the trouble
originated with the Reagan economic agenda. The Democrats were
attacking the Fed for raising interest rates, which was at least
conceptually consistent.
The White House accused the Fed of targeting interest rates
again
instead of focusing on controlling monetary aggregates, and Volcker
himself was accused of undermining the president. Reagan publicly
discussed "abolishing" the Fed, notwithstanding his disingenuous
defense of the Fed from attacks by Carter during the election campaign.
Earlier, back in mid-April, Volcker had publicly committed himself to
gradualism in reining in the money supply and avoiding shock therapy,
to give the economy time to adjust. But he changed his promise by May,
and decided to tighten on an economy already weakened by high rates
imposed six months earlier, yielding to the White House and the bond
market. Gradualism was permanently discarded. Volcker's justification
was amazing, in fact farcical. He told a group of Wall Street finance
experts in a two-day invited seminar that since policy mistakes in the
past had been on the side of excessive ease, in the future it made
sense to err on the side of restraint. Feast and famine was now not
only a policy effect but a policy rationale as well. Compound errors,
like compound interest, were selected as the magical cure for the
nation's sick economy.
Financial markets are not the real economy. They are shadows
of the
real economy. The shape and fidelity of the shadows are affected by the
position and intensity of the light source that comes from market
sentiments on the future performance of the economy. The institutional
character of the Fed over the decades has since developed more
allegiance to the soundness of the financial market system than to the
health of the real economy, let alone the welfare of all the people.
Granted, conservative economists argue that a sound financial market
system ultimately serves the interest of all. But the economy is not
homogenous throughout. In reality, some sectors of the economy and
segments of the population, through no fault of their own, may not, and
often do not, survive the down cycles to enjoy the long-term benefits,
and even if they survive are permanently put in the bottom heap of
perpetual depression. Periodically, the Fed has failed to distinguish a
healthy growth in the financial markets from a speculative debt bubble.
The Reagan administration by its second term discovered an
escape valve
from Volcker's independent domestic policy of stable-valued money. In
an era of growing international trade among Western allies, with the
mini-globalization to include the developing countries before the final
collapse of the Soviet Bloc, a booming market for foreign exchange had
been developing since Nixon's abandonment of the gold standard and the
Bretton Woods regime of fixed exchange rates in 1971. The exchange
value of the dollar thus became a matter of national security and as
such fell within the authority of the president that required the Fed's
patriotic support.
Council of Economic Advisors chairman Martin Feldstein, a
highly
respected conservative economist from Harvard with a reputation for
intellectual honesty, had advocated a strong dollar in Reagan's first
term, arguing that the loss suffered by US manufacturing was a fair
cost for national financial strength. But such views were not music to
the Reagan White House's ears and the Treasury under Donald Regan,
former head of Merrill Lynch, whose roster of clients included all
major manufacturing giants. Feldstein, given the brushoff by the White
House, went back to Harvard to continue his quest for truth in
economics after serving two years in the Reagan White House, where
voodoo economics reigned. Feldstein went on to train many influential
economists who later would hold key positions in government, including
Lawrence Summers, Treasury secretary under president Bill Clinton and
now president of Harvard University, and Lawrence Lindsey, presidential
economic assistant to George W Bush (just dismissed along with Treasury
secretary Paul O'Neill in a Bush shake-up of his economic team).
By Reagan's second term, it became undeniable that the United
States'
policy of a strong dollar was doing much damage to the manufacturing
sector of the US economy and threatening the Republicans with the loss
of political support from key industrial states, not to mention the
unions, which the Republican party was trying to woo with a theme of
Cold War patriotism. Treasury secretary James Baker and his deputy
Richard Darman, with the support of manufacturing corporate interest,
then adopted an interventionist exchange-rate policy to push the
overvalued dollar down. A truce was called between the Fed and the
Treasury, though each quietly worked toward opposite policy aims, much
like the situation in 2000 on interest rates, with the Fed raising
short-term FFR while the Treasury pushed down long-term rates by buying
back 30-year bonds, resulting in an inverted rate curve, a classical
signal for recession down the road.
Thus a deal was struck to allow Volcker to continue his
battle against
domestic inflation with high interest rates while the overvalued dollar
would be pushed down by the Treasury through the Plaza Accord of 1985
with a global backing-off of high interest rates. Not withstanding the
Louvre Accord of 1987 to halt the continued decline of the dollar
started by the Plaza Accord two years earlier, the cheap-dollar trend
did not reverse until 1997, when the Asian financial crisis brought
about a rise of the dollar by default, through the panic devaluation of
Asian currencies. The paradox is that in order to have a stable-valued
dollar domestically, the Fed had to permit a destabilizing appreciation
of the foreign-exchange value of the dollar internationally. For the
first time since end of World War II, foreign-exchange consideration
dominated the Fed's monetary-policy deliberations, as the Fed did under
Benjamin Strong after World War I. The net result was the dilution of
the Fed's power to dictate to the globalized domestic economy and a
blurring of monetary and fiscal policy distinctions. The high
foreign-exchange value of the dollar had to be maintained because too
many dollar-denominated assets were held by foreigners. A fall in the
dollar would trigger a selloff as it did after the Plaza Accord of
1985, which contributed to the 1987 crash.
It was not until Robert Rubin became special economic
assistant to
president Clinton that the United States would figure out its strategy
of dollar hegemony through the promotion of unregulated globalization
of financial markets. Rubin, a consummate international bond trader at
Goldman Sachs who earned $60 million the year he left to join the White
House, figured out how the US was able to have its cake and eat it too,
by controlling domestic inflation with cheap imports bought with a
strong dollar, and having its trade deficit financed by a capital
account surplus made possible by the same strong dollar. Thus dollar
hegemony was born.
The US economy grew at an unprecedented rate with the
wholesale and
permanent export of US manufacturing jobs from the rust belt, with the
added bonus of reining in the unruly domestic labor unions. The
Japanese and the German manufacturers, later joined by their
counterparts in the Asian tigers and Mexico, were delirious about the
United States' willingness to open its domestic market for invasion by
foreign products, not realizing until too late that their national
wealth was in fact being steadily transferred to the US through their
exports, for which they got only dollars that the US could print at
will but that foreigners could not spend in their own countries. By
then, the entire structure of their economies was enslaved to export,
condemning them to permanent economic servitude to the dollar. The
central banks of these countries competed to keep the exchange values
of their currencies low in relation to the dollar and to each other so
that they can transfer more wealth to the United States, while the
dollars they earned from export had no choice but to go back to the US
to finance the restructuring of the US economy toward new modes of
finance capitalism and new generations of high-tech research and
development through US defense spending.
Constrained by residual limitation on rearmament resulting
from their
defeat in World War II, both Germany and Japan were unable to absorb
significant high-tech research funds in their own defense sectors and
had to buy weapon systems from the US. By continuing to provide a
defense umbrella over Japan and Germany after the Cold War, the US
preserved its leadership in science and technology, with financing
coming mostly from the exporting nations' trade surpluses. The more the
export economies earned in their trade surpluses, the poorer these
exporting nations became. Neo-liberal market fundamentalism is not the
same as 19th-century mercantilism in that trade surpluses in the form
of gold would flow back to the exporting economy - trade surpluses
denominated in dollars merely expand the US economy globally. The
sucking sound that Ross Perot warned of regarding the North American
Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) during his 1992 presidential campaign
turned out not to be the sound of US jobs migrating to Mexico, but the
sound of foreign-held dollars rushing into US equity and debt markets.
The Plaza Accord of 1985 produced an agreement among the
Group of Five
(United States, Britain, France, Germany, and Japan) calling for
coordinated and concerted effort to lower the value of the dollar. In
September 1985, the G-5 met at the Plaza Hotel in New York City to
ratify an initiative to use exchange rates and other macro policy
adjustments as the preferred and necessary means to bring about an
orderly decline in the value of the dollar. The agreement, intended to
curb increasing US trade imbalances and protectionist sentiment and
action, supported orderly appreciation of the main non-dollar
currencies against the dollar.
Two years after the Plaza Accord, the Louvre Accord of 1987
reached by
the G-7 (G-5 plus Canada and Italy) called for a halt in the dollar's
decline, re-establishment of balanced trade, and non-inflationary
growth by introducing reference ranges among the G-7 currencies. In
February 1987, the G-7 met at the Louvre in France and announced that
the dollar had reached a level consistent with the underlying economic
conditions, and that they would intervene only as needed to insure
stability. Under the Louvre Accord, nations would intervene on behalf
of their currencies as needed, unannounced.
These two elaborate arrangements set up by the major
industrial
countries to stabilize their exchange rates had a mixed record.
Developments since then have shown that it would be futile for
governments to waste scarce financial resources intervening in
unregulated foreign exchange markets, as the Bank of England discovered
in 1992. Another reason exchange-rate instability will continue to
increase in the near term is that the euro-dollar exchange rate will be
of less concern to the European Central Bank (ECB) than it was to the
national central banks of Europe because the economy of the euro zone
as a whole will be more closed and inward looking than the individual
members' economies. The euro zone's openness rate (measured by the
ratio of trade in goods and services to GDP) is about 14 percent,
compared with 25 percent for France and Germany individually. Euroland
has discovered the indispensability of domestic development and the
disadvantage of excessive reliance on exports.
International commitment to the Louvre Accord eventually
waned. Germany
raised interest rates in 1990 to combat inflation after reunification,
while the United States eased monetary policy to counteract a decline
in economic activity after the 1987 crash. Although the interest-rate
differentials between the US and Europe caused several European
currencies to appreciate, the G-7 did not react. Nor did it try to halt
depreciation of the yen in 1990. By 1993, the Louvre Accord was
virtually dead, as domestic policy objectives took priority over
internationally agreed targets. Political shocks (such as German
reunification and the invasion of Kuwait) and economic facts (such as
the persistence of Japan's current account surplus in spite of a strong
yen) also weakened commitment to the accord. The G-7's approach changed
from "high-frequency" to "low-frequency" activism, with ad hoc
interventions only in cases of extreme misalignment, and the focus
shifted from exchange rate levels to exchange rate volatility.
Reagan replaced Volcker with Alan Greenspan as Fed chairman
in the
summer of 1987, over the objection of supply-side partisans, most
vocally represented by Wall Street Journal assistant editor Jude
Wanniski, a close associate of former football star and presidential
potential Jack Kemp of New York. Wanniski derived many of his economics
ideas from Robert Mundell, who was to be the recipient of the Nobel
Prize for economics in 1999 on his theory on exchange rates. Wanniski
accused Greenspan of having caused the 1987 crash, with Greenspan, in
his new role as Fed chairman, telling Fortune magazine in the summer of
1987 that the dollar was overvalued. Wanniski also maintained that
there was no liquidity problem in the banking system in the 1987 crash,
and "all the liquidity Greenspan provided after the crash simply piled
up on the bank ledgers and sat there for a few days until the Fed
called it back". Wanniski blamed the 1986 Tax Act, which while sharply
lowering marginal tax rates nevertheless raised the capital gains tax
to 28 percent from 20 percent and left capital gains without the
protection against inflated gains that indexing would have provided.
This caused investors to sell equities to avoid negative net after-tax
returns, according to Winniski.
On Monday, October 19, 1987, the value of stocks plummeted on
markets
around the world, with the Dow Jones Industrial Average (DJIA, the main
index measuring market activity in the United States) falling 508.32
points to close at 1738.42, a 22.6 percent fall, the largest one-day
decline since 1914. The magnitude of the 1987 stock-market crash was
much more severe than the 1929 crash of 12.8 percent. The loss to
investors amounted to $500 billion. Over the four-day period leading up
to the October 19 crash the market fell by over 30 percent. By peak
value in January 2000, this would translate into the equivalent of an
almost 4,000-point drop in the Dow. However, while the 1929 crash is
commonly believed to have led to the Great Depression, the 1987 crash
only caused pain to the real economy but not its collapse. It is widely
accepted that Greenspan's timely and massive injection of liquidity
into the banking system saved the day. The events launched the
super-central banker cult of Greenspan, notwithstanding Winniski's
criticism.
The 1987 market crested on August 25 with the DJIA at 2,747.
It is hard
to relate to the fact that the same DJIA peaked in January 2000 near
12,000 without thinking of bubble inflation. The United States' 1987
GDP was $4.7 trillion and 2000 GDP was $9.8 trillion. The GDP doubled
in this period while the DJIA quadrupled. After reaching the top in
1987, the market fell off to 2,500, rallied back to 2,640 then fell
back to a slightly lower level around 2,465. Another longer rally
started that took the Dow to around 2,660. Technical analysis shows
that in 55-day declines, the market's rallies tend to end around the
40th day. It was almost as if investors gave up hoping things would
turn back to the upside and decided to take some money off the table.
Some 50 percent or more of the total market decline was in the last
three or four days. In 1987, the market fell from 2,747 to 1,600, a
total of 1,147 points. The last three days ranged from 2,400 to 1,600,
a total of 800 points or 69.7 percent of the total range of 1,147
points. Yet the 1988 GDP grew to $5.1 trillion, up $360 billion over
1987, while it took until 1941 and a war economy for the GDP to recover
to the level before the 1929 crash.
Panic-driven trading on the New York Stock Exchange on
October 19,
1987, reached 604.3 million shares, nearly double the prior record
volume of 338.5 million shares set the previous Friday, when the Dow
lunged a then-record 108.35 points. Nowadays, a routine daily volume
would be 1.6 billion shares and the system is supposed to handle 3
billion shares with ease. But the ability to handle increased volume
itself created a demand for high-volume trading. It is not unlike the
opening of new lanes of traffic in a crowded expressway: the new lanes
themselves attract more traffic until overload occurs again.
The DJIA was down 36.7 percent on October 19, 1987, from its
closing
high less than two months earlier. The selling started right from the
opening on the day of the crash. Some 11 of the 30 stocks in the DJIA
did not open for the first hour because of order imbalances - there
were so many sell orders they could not be matched to buy orders. With
many stocks on the NYSE not trading, traders turned to the futures
markets to cover their positions. An eerie quiet settled over the
normally teeming stock-index futures pit at the Chicago Mercantile
Exchange early on October 19 as traders watched the beginning of the
worst washout in stock-market history. The Wall Street Journal reported
the following day, October 20, 1987: "With trading delayed in many
major New York Stock Exchange issues because of order imbalances,
Chicago's controversial 'shadow markets' - the highly leveraged, liquid
futures on the Standard & Poor's 500 stock index - were, for just a
few minutes, the leading indicator for the world's equity markets. And
the stock-index markets were leading the way down - fast. In a
nightmarish fulfillment of some traders' and academicians' worst fears,
the five-year-old index futures for the first time plunged into a
panicky unlimited free fall, fostering a sense of crisis throughout the
US capital markets."
The Fed supplied liquidity through the open-market purchase
of US
government securities, adding $2.2 billion in non-borrowed reserves
between the reserve periods ended on November 4, 1987. In addition, the
Federal Reserve provided help to commercial banks by making the
discount window available when they encountered heavy reserve needs.
Chairman Greenspan also reassured the public that the Federal Reserve
would serve as a source of liquidity to support the economic and
financial system. Interest rates on short- and long-term instruments
fell in order to provide liquidity. For example, the rate on
three-month Treasury bills dropped from 6.74 percent on October 13 to
5.27 percent on October 30, while the FFR declined by 179 basis points
over this interval, and the rate on 30-year Treasury bonds fell from
9.92 percent to 9.03. Further, banks' increasing lending to securities
firms during October 19-23 enabled firms to finance the inventories of
securities accumulated by their customers' sell orders. Partially
because of the Federal Reserve's and banks' assistance, the stock price
recovery period was much shorter than after the 1929 crash.
Initial blame for the 1987 crash centered on the interplay
between
stock markets and index options and futures markets. In the former,
people buy actual shares of stock; in the latter they are only
purchasing rights to buy or sell stocks at particular prices. Thus
options and futures are known as derivatives, because their value
derives from changes in stock prices even though no actual shares are
owned. The Brady Commission, officially named the Presidential Task
Force on Market Mechanisms, concluded that the failure of stock markets
and derivatives markets to operate in sync was the major factor behind
the crash. In part, investors' concern about the US federal budget and
international trade deficits were found to be responsible. Comments
made by the US Treasury secretary, who criticized foreign economic
policies and hinted that the Reagan administration would let the US
dollar's value decline further, also contributed. The key factor was
program trading, a recent development on Wall Street in which computers
were programmed to order the buying or selling automatically of a large
volume of shares when certain circumstances occurred. The commission
also criticized "specialists" on the floor of the New York Stock
Exchange who neglected their duty by not becoming buyers of last resort
and by treating small investors "capriciously". The Securities and
Exchange Commission (SEC) joined in, faulting computerized trading and
exchange specialists as well as citing a negative turn in investor
psychology. Both the Brady Commission and the SEC called for greater
regulation to prevent a similar occurrence in the future.
On February 4, 1988, the New York Stock Exchange established
safeguards
forbidding the use of its electronic order system for program trading
whenever the DJIA increases or drops 50 points in a single day. The
NYSE implemented on Tuesday, February 16, 1999, new trigger levels at
which restrictions on index arbitrage trading, or trading "collars",
would track the movement of the DJIA. The revisions to NYSE Rule 80A
were approved by the SEC. The NYSE implemented new circuit-breaker and
trading-collar trigger levels that changed with the level of the DJIA.
Circuit-breaker points represent the thresholds at which trading is
halted marketwide for single-day declines in the DJIA. The 10, 20 and
30 percent decline levels, respectively, in the DJIA at its peak around
the first quarter of 2000 were as follows: A 1,050-point drop in the
DJIA before 2pm would halt trading for one hour; would halt trading for
30 minutes if between 2pm and 2:30pm; and would have no effect if at
2:30pm or later. A 2,100-point drop in the DJIA before 1pm would halt
trading for two hours; for one hour if between 1 and 2pm; and for the
remainder of the day if at 2pm or later. A 3,150-point drop would halt
trading for the remainder of the day regardless of when the decline
occurred. Trading collars, which restrict index-arbitrage trading,
would be triggered when the DJIA moved 180 points or more above or
below its closing value on the previous trading day and removed when
the DJIA was above or below the prior day's close by 90 points.
Trading collars were first implemented in July 1990 in
response to
concerns that index arbitrage may have aggravated large market swings.
When implemented, the collars represented an approximate 2 percent move
in the DJIA. The amendment took into account the dramatic advances in
the DJIA over the previous few years. Widely credited with helping
reduce market volatility, trading collars were triggered 23 times on 22
days in 1990; 16 times in 1992; nine times in 1993; 30 times in 28 days
in 1994; 29 times in 28 days in 1995; 119 times in 101 days in 1996;
303 times in 219 days in 1997; and 366 times in 227 days in 1998.
The stock market recovered from the 1987 crash and began
another upward
climb, with the DJIA topping 3,000 in the early 1990s. While technical
problems within markets may have played a role in the magnitude of the
market crash, they could not have caused it. That would require some
action outside the market that caused traders dramatically to lower
their estimates of stock-market values. The main culprit had been
legislation that passed the House Ways and Means Committee on October
15, 1987, eliminating the deductibility of interest on debt used for
corporate takeovers.
Two SEC economists, Mark Mitchell and Jeffry Netter,
published a study
in 1989 concluding that the anti-takeover legislation did trigger the
crash. They note that as the legislation began to move through
Congress, the market reacted almost instantaneously to news of its
progress. Between Tuesday, October 13, 1987, when the legislation was
first introduced, and Friday, October 16, when the market closed for
the weekend, stock prices fell more than 10 percent - the largest
three-day drop in almost 50 years. In addition, those stocks that led
the market downward were precisely those most affected by the
legislation. Many pending merger and acquisition (M&A) deals were
abruptly aborted. The entire industry that grew to support M&A
activities - investment banks, lenders, law firms, arbitrageurs,
corporate raiders and greenmailers - was faced with imminent idleness.
Another important trigger for the market crash was the
announcement of
a large US trade deficit (3.4 percent of GDP) on October 14, 1987,
which led Treasury secretary James Baker to suggest the need for a fall
in the dollar on foreign-exchange markets. Fears of a lower dollar led
foreigners to pull out of dollar-denominated assets, causing a sharp
rise in interest rates. The front page of the New York Times Business
Day section (June 10, 2000) ran an article headlined "Economy may have
a soft spot - swelling trade gap worries some experts and policy
makers". The US current account deficit reached $338.9 billion in 1999,
up 53.6 percent from 1998. It amounted to 3.7 percent of GDP in 1999
and 4.2 percent of Q4. The DJIA peaked in January 2000 at close to
12,000, and has since lost more than 40 percent of its peak value.
What the 1987 crash ultimately accomplished was to teach
politicians
that markets heed their words and actions, reacting immediately when
threatened. Thus the crash initiated a new era of market discipline not
so much on bad economic policy, but on policy honesty.
Greenspan issued a statement at 8:41am on Tuesday, October
20, 1987,
before the markets opened: "The Federal Reserve, consistent with its
responsibilities as the nation's central bank, affirmed today its
readiness to serve as a source of liquidity to support the economic and
financial system." This statement was widely credited as limited the
systemic damage of the 1987 crash by restoring market confidence.
The forces behind the 1987 crash actually began two years
earlier. In
January 1985, the value of the dollar peaked and began to weaken. But
its decline was nominal and nine months later there was no discernible
improvement in the trade deficit. In fact, by September 1985, the US
trade deficit had worsened substantially, just as the J-curve theory
predicts. The J-curve is the illustration of the performance of a
country's balance of payments after its currency has been devalued. The
immediate effect of a devaluation is to raise the cost of imports and
reduce the value of exports, so that the current account deteriorates.
Gradually, however, the volume of exports increases because their price
is down and the volume of imports declines because they have become
more expensive. This should rectify the current account balance,
turning deficit to surplus. Like much in economics, this is a
persuasive theory that appears to straddle the line between natural law
and wishful thinking. The adjustment period, which was expected to be
six to 12 months (nine-month average), should have been over. But in
1985, the dollar fell for nine months with no discernible improvement
in the trade deficit.
The Brady Commission concluded that the failure of stock
markets and
derivatives markets to operate in sync was the major factor behind the
crash. The crash is now part of a pantheon of financial market
"problems" that included Barings, Daiwa, Metallgesellschaft, Orange
County, Sumitomo, LTCM, Quantum Funds, Tiger Funds, Enron, Global
Crossing, WorldCom, etc. It was also a forerunner of the 1997 financial
crises that started in Thailand.
The investing public has been assured that the lessons of the
1987
crash have been learned and that changes have been installed to prevent
a recurrence. Among the key changes in the US financial market after
the 1987 crash are "circuit breakers" restricting program trading. Some
believe that the halts they cause will provide time for brokers and
dealers to contact their clients when there are large price movements
and to get new instructions or additional margin. Others argue that
trading halts can increase risk by inducing trading in anticipation of
a trading halt.
Circuit breakers were triggered for the first and only time
on October
27, 1997, when the second wave of the Asian financial crisis that had
begun on July 2 in Thailand hit New York markets, and the DJIA fell 350
points at 2:35pm and 550 points at 3:30. That reflected an approximate
7 percent overall decline and shut the market for the remainder of the
day.
The circuit breakers were installed primarily to prevent
extreme
changes in the stock market. Their usefulness is often in doubt because
in order to prevent extreme shifts in the market the causes of values
change must be revealed. There are several suggestions as to what can
cause these changes. A primary cause is fundamental changes in the
economy, including the availability of money or changes in interest
rates. Here restrictions on trading are detrimental because they can
decrease the effectiveness of the pricing in the stock market. The
advocates of circuit breakers insist that periods of suspension of the
market will allow time for the investors to consider what their next
move will be and how to overcome this large price move. Yet it is
unlikely that investors will sit and contemplate the reasoning behind
the drop in points. Most are apt to become nervous and anxious as they
consider what the market will do when it resumes, at which time they
will be poised to sell.
Circuit breakers are widely cited today as one of the
successes of the
crash post-mortems. Yet circuit breakers have only been triggered once,
in contrast to some of the so-called "speed bumps" that affect
particular trading strategies and are now tripped routinely. (In
contrast to circuit breakers, which are coordinated across the equity
and derivative markets, speed bumps are trading restrictions that have
been put in place by individual marketplaces.) If circuit breakers have
been used to halt trading only once, it follows that we have never had
sufficient experience of trying to restart trading either. The scariest
times during the market crash were those in which trading was not
occurring. The tendency to worry more about stopping trading than
restarting it is mystifying. Recent reassessments of circuit breakers
have focused on increasing the magnitude of price declines necessary to
trigger coordinated trading halts. It is not clear that circuit
breakers continue to be the best public-policy response to market
volatility.
Many features of financial markets have changed over the past
decade
and are still changing rapidly, not least of which is the continuing
growth in international activity. Circuit breakers are much more
difficult to impose when trading activity can move to markets that do
not participate in the trading halt. The main concerns is the
restarting of trading following a halt. If liquidity has moved to
over-the-counter markets or foreign venues, that liquidity may not
return to the domestic, exchange-traded market when the trading halt
ends. Domestic specialists and market makers may have problem in
restarting if the market has moved away from them during the halt.
Recent changes to shorten the duration of the circuit breakers may
ameliorate these concerns somewhat, but these changes also reduces the
effectiveness of the circuit breakers in achieving their intended
goals.
After the crash of 1987, federal regulators were pressured to
prevent
any sort of crash again from market manipulation. But no one knows the
best way to prevent a crash from occurring. In order to design
"preventive measures" that would "protect" the market from dangerous
speculative declines, the regulators imposed the circuit breakers that
would act as weak restraints and would probably do no harm. Circuit
breakers have little to do with the stock market but demonstrate more
about the use of regulation. Because of the very weak restraints
provided by these circuit breakers, it does seem that their purpose is
to cover the backs of the stock-market regulators. Despite the
empirical evidence on the futility of throwing sand in the gears of the
market, mechanisms like circuit breakers are attractive to policy
makers because they offer a relatively low-cost way for regulators to
say to the public that they are doing something to try and prevent
another crash. If they did nothing to try to prevent another crash, the
public would not question the necessity. If nothing was done after the
crash, the public would distrust the market and its high volatility.
Because of this distrust, investors would be reluctant to put their
money in the market and might instead deposit it in banks and the
market would decline.
Uniform margin requirements are another change introduced
after the
1987 crash. They aim to reduce volatility for stocks, index futures,
and stock options. An April 1997 study by Paul H Kupiec, senior
economist, Trading Risk Analysis Section, Division of Research and
Statistics, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, assesses
the state of the policy debate that surrounds the federal regulation of
margin requirements. It found no undisputed evidence that supports the
hypothesis that margin requirements can be used to control stock return
volatility and correspondingly little evidence that suggests that
margin-related leverage is an important underlying source of "excess"
volatility. The evidence does not support the hypothesis that there is
a stable inverse relationship between the level of Regulation T margin
requirements and stock returns volatility, nor does it support the
hypothesis that the leverage advantage in equity derivative products is
a source of additional returns volatility in the stock market. So the
question of margins appears to be a red herring.
After the crash, some stock exchanges upgraded their computer
systems
to improve data-management effectiveness and increase speed, accuracy,
efficiency, and productivity. Many stock-market analysts believe that
the crash was set off by a number of events that include the poor
choices of portfolio insurance professionals and program trading, which
made portfolio insurance operational. A portfolio is a collection of
stocks. Portfolio insurance, a form of investment, is the guarding of
other stock investments against losses. This is regarded as a highly
risky way of investing in the stock market because these portfolio
insurance professionals rely on their intuition instead of reliable
information. These risky investors sell their stocks at a high price
when they think the market is declining and their stocks are losing
value. But when they feel that the market will increase again, they buy
back their stocks at a lower value and use the profit made by the
purchase to make up for the monetary losses within the portfolio. This
type of massive selling caused the value of the stocks used to decrease
below their true value and because of the low value the process would
be repeated.
In the summer of 1987 the yield of a 30-year US bond
increased to
almost 10 percent. Because of this, investors began to shift from
investing in stocks to putting their money into bonds, which yielded
more money. Program trading was itself also a cause of the crash of
1987. This is when the prices of a stock fall below a preset price, and
a programmed computer automatically sells that stock. Within one
second, a computer would finalize 60 transactions in 1987. Now it can
handle 2,000. These computers were handling trillions of dollars of
transactions per second. The market was being controlled more by
computers and set prices than by investors who made considered deals.
The rises and falls of the stock market echoed the sounds of the
computers programmed buying and selling stocks, rather than a
dependence on sound judgments made by investors.
The changes brought by the 1987 crash to clearing systems
have received
far less attention than those to trading systems, but their long-term
consequences likely are more profound. Such critical parts of the
"plumbing" as the agreements between the futures clearing houses and
the settlement banks have been clarified and put on sounder footing. In
addition, many clearing organizations have established backup liquidity
facilities that will enable them to make payments to clearing members
in a timely fashion even if a clearing member has defaulted.
There is now supposedly a better understanding of the way
these systems
work, but the understanding tended to be through the rearview mirror.
During ordinary trading days, market participants rarely if ever
question counterparties' ability and willingness to perform on
obligations. In the months following the crash, policy makers and
market participants began to examine those payment conventions more
closely. The bulk of the changes to risk management systems that flowed
from the 1987 crash related to efforts to clarify or make more rigorous
the responsibilities and obligations of market participants that
previously had been left ambiguous or were part of the lore of "normal"
market practice.
The options clearing house has strengthened its liquidity
reserve and
taken other steps to avoid a collapse. Just as significantly, so has
the Clearing House Inter-Payments System (CHIPS), the large-dollar
clearing and settlement system for the largest US banks and many of
their foreign counterparts. CHIPS in 1998 could withstand the
simultaneous failure of the two largest banks on the system, a level of
safety far greater than that of a decade ago. But banks are merging
faster than the divorce rate in Hollywood. It is unknown what a failure
of a giant like JP Morgan/Chase or Citibank would mean to the banking
system.
Another intangible legacy of the crash is the acceptance of
the need
for cooperation and coordination among commodity, securities, and
banking market authorities. The 1987 crash vividly illustrated the
extent to which markets are intertwined and the extent to which large
financial firms have lines of business that cut across many markets.
The forums for coordination are numerous, the most high-power being the
President's Working Group on Financial Markets, which the market has
dubbed the Plunge Prevent Team. The Working Group comprises the heads
of the Treasury, SEC, Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC), and
Federal Reserve and, in addition, other banking supervisory agencies,
the National Economic Council, and the Council of Economic Advisors
participate. Yet every new crisis resulted in yet another Presidential
Working Group, such as after the LTCM episode. None has ben able to
prevent new unanticipated crises.
An important change in the financial landscape in the years
since the
crash has been a greater focus on risk management by both market
participants and supervisors. Developments of new instruments, both on
and off exchanges, and of new methods for evaluating risk, have given
market participants powerful new tools to allow them to absorb market
shocks. Similarly, risk management tools have been enhanced at clearing
organizations. Yet these new tools do not enhance systemic safety, they
merely raise the level of "acceptable" risk for individual participants
and transfer them to increase systemic risk. The phenomenal growth of
day trading since 1978 also thrived on volatility and systemic stress.
Regulators have been slow to respond to these new tools.
Seduced by
their benefits, regulators merely approach regulation and supervision
in traditional, permissive ways. Greenspan's official approach has been
timid on that front. In essence he thinks the benefits outweigh the
risks, and that regulation will threaten US financial hegemony. Like
Winston Churchill, whose narrow vision failed to transform the British
Empire into a lasting sphere of influence for Britain after World War
II, Greenspan is also not about to give the empire away voluntarily.
Whereas Churchill plunged the British Empire into a sea of
revolutionary wars of independence, Greenspan, by insisting on
structural advantages for US interests in US-led finance globalization,
is plunging the world into a battlefield of economic nationalism and
protectionism.
The approach by banking supervisors to developing a universal
capital
requirement for market risk has been less than adequate. The
one-size-fits-all approach has been too lenient for big banks in the
advanced economies and too strict for those in developing economies.
After initial fits and starts, the Basel Supervisor's Committee
halfheartedly embraced the concept of using banks' internal models as a
basis for a capital requirement for market risk. Internal models are
meaningless when the bulk of the risk facing banks lies in counterparty
credit risk. The Federal Reserve has favored an incentive-compatible
approach to regulation. Self-regulatory organizations (SROs) obviously
find such an approach beneficial, particularly in this era in which
SROs are being asked to assume more and more regulatory
responsibilities. Incentive-compatible regulation in essence tries to
harness the self-interest of market participants to achieve broader
public-policy goals, but often only modify those goals to fit private
special group self-interest. This approach smells of policy abdication.
By January 1989, 15 months after the crash, the market had
fully
recovered, but not the US economy, which remained in recession for
several more years. When a recession finally hit in full force, three
years after the crash, it was blamed on excessive financial borrowing,
not the stock market, notwithstanding the fact that excessive financial
borrowing itself was made possible by the stock market. The Tuesday
after the crash on Black Monday, Alan Greenspan issued a one-sentence
assurance that the Federal Reserve would provide the system with
necessary credit. John D Rockefeller had made a somewhat similar
declaration in 1929 - but failed to buoy the market. Rockefeller was
rich, but his funds were finite. Greenspan succeeded because he
controlled unlimited funds with the full faith and credit of the
nation. The 1987 crash marked the hour of his arrival as central banker
par excellence, the beginning of his status as a near-deity on Wall
Street. All the world now hums the mantra: In Alan We Trust (an
update of the slogan "In God We Trust" printed on every Federal Reserve
note, known as the dollar bill). It was the main reason for his
third-term reappointment by president Clinton. He is the man who will
show up with more liquor when the partying hits a low point.
At a macroeconomic level, public policies are supposed to
ensure that
markets and the economy itself can withstand shocks. While the 1987
crash escaped significant, real economic effects in the years
immediately following, this is not always the case with stock-market
crashes. Such episodes are generally accompanied by dramatic increases
in uncertainty and increased demands for liquidity and safety. Some of
these demands for liquidity may, in turn, reflect the fear that the
crisis will spread more broadly to the economy. In 1987, a key role
played by the Fed was to demonstrate a determination to meet liquidity
demands, and thereby to reassure market participants that problems
would not spread beyond the financial system. Problems were contained
in this instance, not without cost of "exuberant irrationality". The
1987 market bailout has created widespread complacency. Greenspan has
become the main source of moral hazard.
In a speech before the Federation of Bankers Associations of
Japan in
Tokyo on November 18, 1996, Alan Greenspan said: "This expanded role of
governments, central banks, and bank supervisors implies a complex
approach to managing and even sharing the risks of failure between
governments and privately owned banks. Some of what central banks do
might be termed 'shaping' or reducing some kinds of risks, primarily by
providing liquidity in certain situations to reduce the odds of extreme
market outcomes, in which uncertainty feeds market panics.
Traditionally this was accomplished by making discount or Lombard
facilities available, so that depositories could turn illiquid assets
into liquid resources and not exacerbate unsettled market conditions by
forced selling of such assets or calling in loans. Similarly, open
market operations, in situations like that which followed the 1987
stock-market crash, satisfy increased needs for liquidity that
otherwise could feed cumulative, self-reinforcing, contractions across
many financial markets.
"Guarding against systemic problems also has involved, on
very rare
occasions, an element of more overt risk-sharing, in which the
government - or more accurately the taxpayer - is potentially asked to
bear some of the cost of failure. Activating such risk-sharing quite
appropriately occurs at most maybe two or three times a century. The
willingness to do so arises from society's judgment that some bank
failures may have serious adverse effects on the entire economy and
that requiring banks to carry enough capital to avoid any risk of
failure under all circumstances itself would have unacceptable costs in
terms of reduced intermediation."
Having said that, the United States would go on to criticize
Japan for
dragging its feet in cleaning up its banking mess. Since 1987,
financial crises have occurred every two to three years around the
globe. Greenpsan has already used up his quota of risk-sharing
incidents for the century. With the unprecedented polarization of
wealth in recent decades, it is amazing that the chairman of the Fed
can talk about the socialization of the cost of systemic bank failure
without mentioning the need for bank profit sharing with the tax-paying
public, and not just among bank shareholders. The risk takers with
other people's money, such as top investment bankers and top executives
of their bank-holding parents, each routinely take home hundreds of
millions of dollars in annual pay. Such winnings remain safely in their
private pockets while the loss from their risk-taking is shared by
taxpayers. The former chairman of Citibank, John Reed, reportedly
earned more than $1 billion during his decade of high-risk lending.
The question is not whether stock markets are overvalued,
which can be
benignly cured by market corrections. The danger is when market
corrections are cumulatively delayed by a dam of financial hedging
instruments: the dam will break one day, with overwhelmingly damaging
force. The crash of 1987 demonstrated how structural flaws in the
financial infrastructure could significantly aggravate a sudden
downturn in prices triggered by any one of many possible causes. If
trading volume overwhelms the physical ability of the exchanges to
handle it, then trade and price information is delayed. The resulting
uncertainty can induce many investors to sell before they wait to find
out how far their stocks have fallen. Prices can plunge even further if
investors fear that the mechanisms for clearing and settling trades
will grind to a halt, as they nearly did in the case of the options
clearing house in Chicago in October 1987. And contagion can spread if
stock prices are falling against a backdrop of weakness elsewhere in
the financial system, as was the case in 1987, when many of the United
States' leading banks were plagued with problem loans to real-estate
developers and less developed countries. In the 2000s, counterparty
default in over-the-counter (OTC) derivative trades will no doubt be
the weak link in the precarious financial chain.
But that is only the mechanical side of the problem. The
demise of LTCM
and Tiger Funds showed that even if the trading system can handled the
volume, which twice topped 3 billion shares since 2001, the market
tends to have difficulty absorbing large liquidation. Large holdings
cannot liquidate suddenly and quickly without incurring severe
additional harm to themselves. Recent deregulation have directly
contributed to bigness in every sector, particularly in the finance
sector, thus increasing systemic vulnerability.
The trend toward aggregation, reflected by investors
participating
through mutual funds, makes the market more susceptible to sudden deep
plunges. At the end of 1996, equity funds accounted for 21 percent of
the overall market, three times the 7 percent share they had in 1987.
Since a good chunk of the new money comes from investors who have never
experienced a bear market and who can least afford any loss on their
retirement pensions, when a normal market correction occurs, there is
widespread concern that these investors will flee from the markets,
aggravating any initial selling pressure.
The minutes of the FOMC meeting of March 22, 1994, showed
Greenspan
saying: "I'd like to take a minute to put the current period in some
historical perspective. We have had extraordinary financial turmoil,
and it's worthwhile to go back in time and see where it came from and
where it's likely to go.
"My impression is that we are looking at the aftermath of the
1987
stock-market crash, which is the first and perhaps the only major
stock-market crash in history that actually was beneficial to the
economy. In other words, it appeared to me in retrospect that the crash
stripped out a high degree of overheating and sort of got right to the
edge of where the overheating got into the muscle of the economy and
stopped. We came out of it with a very shaken environment but one which
recovered relatively quickly. As a consequence of that, from the 1987
stock-market crash on, all the key risk spreads started to narrow. We
saw it in, say, this stage of the economic recovery.
"Historically, waiting too long to adjust rates has been a
greater
risk, and I think it's the one that we need to be especially sensitive
to in this current environment. I am sensitive to the financial risks
that you point out, but I must say that in one form or another that has
been the argument around the table for not moving in the past when we
should have moved. It also may be that this point is significantly
different from other points historically, but my guess is that if we
push on this economy, we will get inflation and we will end the growth.
So one can come up with lots of arguments, some subtle, some not.
"I think the important thing is to stick to the basics and go
to the
heart of the matter. We have an economy that is telling us that we need
a less accommodative monetary policy, and in my view we ought to move
in that direction decisively. It's surprising, but when people do
things decisively, they end up getting better results than if they try
to outsmart themselves and consider all the angles in the curve. So, I
think we ought to go to the heart of the matter."
By 1994, Greenspan was already riding on the back of the debt
tiger
from which he could not dismount without being devoured. The DJIA was
below 4,000 in 1994 and rose steadily to a bubble of near 12,000 while
Greenspan raised the FFR seven times from 3 percent to 6 percent
between February 4, 1994, and February 1, 1995, to try to curb
"irrational exuberance", and kept it above 5 percent until October 15,
1998. When the DJIA started its current slide downward after peaking in
January 2001, the Fed lowered the FFR from 6.5 percent on January 3,
2001, to the current rate of 1.25 percent set on November 6, 2002.
In testimony before the Joint Economic Committee of the US
Congress on
October 29, 1997, on Turbulence in World Financial Markets, chairman
Greenspan stated: "Yet provided the decline in financial markets does
not cumulate, it is quite conceivable that a few years hence we will
look back at this episode, as we now look back at the 1987 crash, as a
salutary event in terms of its implications for the macroeconomy. From
the market peak to the October lows the S&P 500 lost 35.9 percent
of its value. The S&P 500 regained the lost value about two years
later."
The Asian financial crises that began in 1997 did represent
temporarily
a "salutary" event for US financial markets with flight capital rushing
into safe haven in the US, but there was little doubt that it led to
the crash of October 1998 when the DJIA fell below 7,000, and the crash
of September 2000 when the DJIA fell below 8,000 from its all-time high
of near 12,000 nine months earlier in January, and the crash of July
2002 when the DJIA fell to 7,500, and in October 2002 when the DJIA
fell to 7,000. The bottom is far from being in sight.
Fed Board member Ben S Bernanke in a speech on November 21
reinforced
an earlier Greenspan speech, particularly statements during questions,
that the Fed would not be out of bullets even if the FFR fell to zero,
as it can move out to longer-term debt instruments to drive interest
rates down. Bernanke said: "The US government has a technology, called
a printing press, or today, its electronic equivalent, that allows it
to produce as many US dollars as it wishes at essentially no cost." It
is an amazing statement from a Fed Board governor.
Of course, the last part of the statement is inoperative: the
cost is
inflation. There is not much wrong with the Fed printing money, as it
has been doing since 1971 when Nixon took the dollar off the gold
standard. The question is how the money is injected into the system,
and toward whom. By bailing out credit-impaired illiquid banks, the
money will only go to fuel more speculative excess, or to keep
corporate walking deads walking, as Japan has discovered. At least
Japan has a rationale for its madness, which is the cultural fix of the
role of national banking: to feed the industrial sector of the economy.
The Japanese economy does not exist to feed the banks, as the US
economy does. This is why bank bailouts in Japan makes some sense while
they do not in the United States.
Next: The
Lesson of the US experience
|