|
The Real
Interest Rate
Conundrum
By
Henry C.K. Liu
This article
appeared in AToL
on June 12, 2007, one month before the implosion of the financial
crisis rhat started in New York
Suddenly
this summer, all eyes
are trained
on rising interest rates around the globe. The prospect of central
banks
tightening to ward off impending inflation has abruptly interrupted the
spectacular rise of all stock markets driven by abnormally ample
liquidity, but
has yet to precipitate a market crash. Under normal conditions, rising
rates
lowers bond prices as well as equity prices. But in the current
liquidity boom
that has produced a persistently inverted yield curve, high short-term
interest
rates have crashed bonds but have left equity prices higher than market
fundamentals could justify.
Yet even
as rising interest rates will
eventually reduce liquidity to reverse the rise of stock markets, it
will not
arrest the real decline of the dollar as otherwise expected. The
anomalous
combination of rising interest rates and overpriced stocks is explosive
enough
by itself; but adding to it the shocking impotence of rising interest
rates to arrest
the declining value of the dollar, we have an unstable mixture of
deadly financial
dynamite waiting to be detonated by even seemingly unrelated minor
events.
Normally, high
interest rates should lift
the exchange value of a currency to reduce import prices to constrain
inflation
which is one of the offsetting benefits of a tight monetary policy that
otherwise
slows down the domestic economy. Increased global capital inflow would
also be
attracted by high interest rates.
But the dollar is
not a normal currency. It
is a fiat currency that can be produced at will by the US, not backed by
anything of intrinsic value, yet assuming the
role of a reserve currency for international trade and finance. This
unique
characteristic is what lies behind dollar hegemony.
The US dollar is the
head of the world’s
fiat currencies snake. As the fiat dollar declines in value over the
long term,
as expressed by its dwindling purchasing power, all other fiat
currencies
decline with it because of dollar hegemony within the current
international
finance architecture, even though some currencies may decline faster
temporarily due to varying local conditions such as different interest
rates
and inflation rates, in which case the market registers the dollar as
rising in
exchange value against these currencies, while in reality, all
currencies are following
the dollar in steady net decline against real assets. Market
cheerleaders then mislabel
the persistent rise in asset prices from the steady decline in currency
value as
the sign of a healthy business boom in an allegedly dynamic global
economy led
by the liquidity boom in the US.
Concurrently, some
currencies may decline
slower in purchasing power than the dollar, causing the market to view
these
currencies as rising in exchange value against the dollar while in
reality they
are also declining in real value. The temporary divergence or
convergence of
exchange values between and among currencies caused sometimes by market
inefficiency or other times by market overshoots are what make currency
arbitrage profitable, albeit with corresponding risk of loss.
This global trend of
declining currency value
has been going on in the current international finance architecture for
several
decades and has distorted the historical and conventional relationship
of
interest rates to inflation and economic growth. This distortion has
sent
central bankers looking desperately for, if not new, at least newly
rediscovered economic theories to construct improved algorithms to
guide their deliberation
on monetary policy in the new paradigm.
A New Guru for the
Fed
The Wall Street
Journal (WSJ) on Oct 3, 2000 reported that the
Federal Reserve, the US central bank then
under Alan Greenspan, had of late fallen
under the influence of the views of Swedish economist Johan G. K.
Wicksell
(1851-1926) on the relationship between interest rates, inflation and
economic
growth. Wicksell argues that monetary policy works best at containing
inflation
by pegging interest rates not to the level of money supply as mandated
by textbook
neoclassical economics theory, but to the rate of return on investment
(ROI).
Some critics described the Fed’s new fad as asking for advice from dead
men who
never had a chance to analyze present-day data. Wicksell died three
years
before the 1929 crash.
Greenspan made his
famous “irrational
exuberance” speech at the conservative American Enterprise Institute in
Washington
DC on December 5, 1996, when the Dow Jones
Industrial Average (DJIA) was at 6,442, already
more than twice the pre-1987-crash high of 2,722. Less
than a year earlier, on January 31, 1996, the Fed had
lowered Fed Funds Rate (FFR) target 25 basis points from 5.5% to 5.25%
to add liquidity
to the very same irrational exuberance Greenspan later warned against.
The Fed
did not raise the FFR target again until four months after Greenspan’s
warning
and then only by 25 basis points back to 5.5% on March 25, 1997.
Not surprisingly,
the market kept rising despite
the Greenspan warning and on January 14, 2000, with the FFR
target still at 5.5%, the DJIA peaked at a hyper-irrational
level of 11,723, rising another 83% over Greenspan’s warning level. But
the
Gross Domestic Product (GDP) only rose from $7.8 trillion in 1996 to
$9.8
trillion in 2000, or 25.6%. The DJIA
climbed
three times more than the GDP in the four-year period after Greenspan’s
warning
of irrationality. One can only conclude that the dollar had declined in
value
by 57.4% in that time.
Two months later,
after some secular bull
market corrections in which each down closing was erased by subsequent
gains, the
DJIA scored on March 16, 2000 its largest one-day point gain in
history, 499.19
points, to close at 10,630.60. On April 14, 2000, 22 trading
days later, the DJIA plummeted 617.78 points, closing at 10,305.77, its
steepest point decline in a single day historically so far, but the
DJIA was still
50% higher than the 6,442 that prompted Greenspan’s irrational
exuberance
warning more than 4 years earlier. This volatility came purely from
speculative
forces operating in a liquidity bubble. The real economy did not change
in 22
trading days.
Interest Rates and
Elections
The fed
in its board meeting on October 3, 2000,
the same day of the WSJ report on Wicksell, with the DJIA closing at
10,719.74,
left the FFR target unchanged at 6.5%, keeping inflation-adjusted real
short-term
interest rate at historical high. This decision left the DJIA in the
historical
high range, but left the Democrats with an anemic economy despite a Clinton fiscal surplus and
robust corporate earnings in the crucial
months before the presidential election in November. Though a rate
reduction had been warranted by conventional wisdom over weak economic
data and
ominous leading economic indicators, the DJIA stayed high because the
market
believed the Fed would have to cut rates soon to prevent a sharp market
correction.
As it turned out,
the Fed did not lower the
FFR target until its January 3, 2001 board meeting,
after the Supreme Court snatched a near victory
from the jaws of Democratic candidate Al Gore and delivered a
bitterly-contested
White House to Republican George W. Bush. The Fed then lowered the FFR
target by
larger-than-usual 50 basis points to 6% to commence a long downward
rate cycle with
13 more cuts in 30 months to bottom at 1% on June 25, 2003, pushing short-term
rate below neutral, meaning below inflation
rate, feeding a multi-year credit bubble.
Belated Epiphany on
Inflation Threats
Only five days after
the FFR hitting a historical
low of 1%, the Fed, in a belated epiphany on rediscovering inflation
threats
that had been glaringly visible for some time, reversed course and
raised the
FFR target by 25 basis points, followed by a “measured pace” of 18 more
upward moves
to 5.25% on June 29, 2006 and kept it there unchanged for over 11
months up to
now, with no signs of ending the cautious interest rate “pause”,
extending a
liquidity boom that creates an interest rate “conundrum”.
Conundrum is Just
Another Word for Denial
Maestro Greenspan
confessed publicly that
with all his acknowledged wisdom, he could not understand why long-term
rates
stayed low despite a high FFR while the flat or inverted yield curve
had been
obviously caused by the Fed’s own earlier actions of releasing too much
credit
into the system. This easy credit fueled a trade deficit which due to
dollar
hegemony was recycled as a capital account surplus in US Treasuries,
pushing
long-term rates down. This trend is still going on and is exacerbated
by
endogenous liquidity generated internally by debt securitization and
hedging
through derivatives. What determines long-term interest rates is
sustained monetary
liquidity or excess money already in the system from previous
short-term rates
staying too low and too long which the Fed’s subsequent gradualism in
short-term
rate hikes would not be able to stop the momentum effectively and
quickly.
Timed for Elections
On Tuesday November
9, 2004, the election
day for Bush’s second term, the FFR target was still at a below-neutral
1.75%,
with the DJIA closing at a bullish 10,386.37, giving Bush a temporary
bull
market, if not quite a sustainable strong economy, to achieve an easy
win over
challenger John Kerry, all the while with the Fed keeping a straight
face about
itself being an apolitical institution that operates on scientific
monetary principles.
The Fed raised the FFR target to 2% in its meeting the day after the
2004
presidential election when it was politically safe to raise rates and
kept it going
upward to its current 5.25%.
The DJIA closed at
10,719.74 on the same
day of the WSJ-Wicksell report on October 3, 2000, having broken the
psychological 10,000 for the first time in
history on March 19, 1999. The DJIA had risen
50% from its previous low of 7,161.15 recorded
on October 27 1997, when it suffered a
big one-day fall of 554.26 points, or 7.2%,
from contagion from the Asian Financial Crisis. On Monday, June 4, 2007, defying persistent
news of a slowing economy, the key index rose 91% higher than its 1997
low to
close at an all-time high of 13,673.
Wicksell: Link
Interest Rates to Return on Investment
Monetarists who
dominate the Fed throughout
most of its history subscribe to the theory that inflation can only be
prevented either by high interest rates to reduce growth by reducing
the growth
of money supply, or by high unemployment to depress wages, which are
two faces
of the same coin. Wicksell argues that monetary policy works best at
containing
inflation by pegging interest rates to investment returns rather than
money
supply.
Wicksell’s theory
was given credence empirically
in 1980 by then Fed Chairman Paul Volcker’s brief experiment with
targeting the
monetary base with automatic interest rate adjustments by his “new
operating
procedure”. The disastrous and damaging result of violent fluctuation
of the
FFR forced the Fed to drop Volcker’s misguided approach after about six
months.
Volcker’s
Blood-letting Experiment
The “new operating
procedure" was adopted on October 6, 1979 by the Fed
under
Paul Volcker as a therapeutic shock-treatment for Wall Street, which
had been conditioned
by former Fed Chairman Arthur Burns’ brazen political opportunism
during the
Nixon era in the 1970s to lose faith in the Fed’s political will to
control
inflation. The new operating procedure, by concentrating on monetary
aggregates, and letting it dictate FFR swings within a range from
13-19%, to be
authorized by the Fed Open Market Committee (FOMC), was an exercise in
“creative uncertainty” to shock the financial market out of its
complacency
about the Fed’s traditional policy of interest-rate stability and
gradualism.
There had been a
traditional expectation in
the market that even if the Fed were to raise rates it would do so
gradually so
as to not permit the market to be volatile. The banks could continue to
lend as
long as they could profitably manage the gradual rise in rates. Under
the new
operating procedure, the banks would be exposed to risks that interest
rates
might suddenly and drastically go against even their short-term credit
positions. Also, banks had been seeking higher earnings by expanding
new loans
beyond the growth of deposits, by borrowing shorter term funds at lower
interest rates. This practice was given the benign name of “managed
liability”
by regulators, allowing banks to profit from interest-rate spreads over
the
yield curve, which had seldom if ever been allowed by the Fed to stay
inverted,
that is with short-term rates higher than longer-term rates, at least
for long.
This practice of interest rate arbitrage later came to be known as
“carry
trade” in bank parlance, and when internationalized, eventually led to
the
Asian financial crisis of 1997 when interest-rate and exchange-rate
volatility
became the new paradigm that could roil equity and currency markets.
The Fed’s new
operating procedure would greatly increase the banks’
risk
exposure, at least before the widespread practice of loan
securitization shifting
individual bank risk to systemic risk for the entire financial market.
On top
of it all, Volcker also set an additional 8% reserve on bank borrowed
funds for
lending. The new operating procedure violated the traditional mandate
of the
Fed, which, as a central bank, was supposed to be responsible for
maintaining
orderly markets, which meant smooth, gradual changes in interest rates
which in
turn would keep money supply fluctuation moderate and gradual so that
prices
would not be detached excessively from market fundamentals. The new
operating
procedure was a policy to induce the threat of severe short-term pain
to
stabilize long-term inflation expectations.
Most economists
agree that when money growth slows, market interest
rates go
up. The trouble with the use of the FFR target to control money supply
is that
it has to be set by fiat, which exposed the Fed to political pressure
to keep a
liquidity boom going forever. A case can be made, and is frequently
made, that
the Fed’s FFR targets tend to be self-fulfilling prophecies rather than
a
device to manage future trends. High FFR targets deflate while low
targets
inflate, and there is little argument about that relationship, at least
before
the age of structured finance when virtual money can be created within
the
system circularly outside of the Fed’s control. Under structured
finance, high
FFR targets can actually inflate because they raise the cost of money
needed
for protection through hedging and for profiteering through financial
arbitrage.
But
there is plenty
of argument about the
Fed’s projection ability on the economy. History has shown that the
Fed, more
often than not, has made wrong decisions based on faulty projection
that at
times borders on blind denial of clear data. The new operating
procedure would
let the monetary aggregates set the FFR targets scientifically and
provide
political cover for the Fed Open Market Committee (FOMC) members if the
FFR
target needs to go to double digits. This amounts to monetarism through
the
back door, not by heroic intellectual confidence in scientific truth,
but by
political cowardice.
The Federal Advisory
Council (FAC) of the Federal Reserve Board is
unique in
that it is a big-bank lobby composed of twelve representatives of the
banking
industry that officially advises the Fed, itself a peculiar
institution: an all
powerful public institution mandated by law, but owned by private
banks. The
FAC meets in secrecy four times a year with Fed officials to give the
banking
industry an inside track on influencing Fed deliberation, if not
decisions. The
since-declassified minutes of the FAC show that four weeks before the
Volcker Fed
announced its “new” operating procedure on October 6, 1979, the FAC had
recommended to the Fed a review of its “traditional” operating
procedure,
before even the President was alerted of the Fed’s deliberation and
final
decision to adopt a “new” operating procedure. Initially, the FAC was
concerned
that political pressure was likely to push FFR down, not anticipating
that
money supply would turn volatile to create extreme interest rate
volatility. Carter, preoccupied with the Iran hostage crisis, was
totally in the dark about the impending volatile
high-interest-rate policy with which the Fed under Volcker, a
Republican, was
going to hit Carter’s Democrat administration running for a second term
within
a year.
To stabilize money
supply, the Fed announced on March 14, 1980 a program of
Emergency Credit Controls. The program affected
not only commercial banks, but also money-market mutual funds and
retail
companies that issue credit cards. Banks would be limited to a 9%
credit growth
instead of the 17% in February. By April, the Fed was shocked by data
showing
money disappearing from the financial system at an alarmingly rapid
rate. The
last two weeks in March saw more than $17 billion vanish, representing
an
annualized shrinkage of 17%, yielding a 34% change. Money was
evaporating from
the banking system as credit dried up and borrowers paying off their
debts in
response to Carter’s moralistic jawboning to save the nation from
hyper-inflation through personal restraint on consumption. Another
cause was
the shift from bank deposits to three-month T-bills that were paying
15%,
causing money to exit the market back into the Fed’s vault.
Volcker’s new
operating procedure adopted
six months earlier now faced a critical test. According to monetarist
theory,
the Fed now must pump up new bank reserves to stop the money supply
shrinkage.
But in practice, Volcker and the FOMC were applying monetarism, which
by
definition must be a long-term proposition, to short-term turbulence,
and in
the process undermined their own earlier efforts to fight
hyper-inflation and,
worse, destabilized the economy unnecessarily. When mortals play god,
other
mortals die unnecessarily.
On May 6, 1980, with
the New York Fed’s Open Market Desk furiously
trying to reverse
a raging money-supply shrinkage, pumping in money to the system by
buying
government securities and depositing the funds in banks to create new
additional “high power” money by increasing bank reserves for lending,
interest
rates fell sharply and abruptly. The FFR dropped 500 basis points in
two weeks,
from 18 to 13%, the bottom of the FOMC range in the new operating
procedure,
and was actually trading below the low FOMC target range at one point.
Telling the Monetary
Train to go in Opposite Directions
Simultaneously
The Fed was in
danger of losing control of its FFR target to the market
and
jeopardizing it own credibility. The New York Fed notified the FOMC
that it
could continue to follow the new operating procedure by injecting more
bank reserves
to let the FFR fall below the low limit set by the FMOC or to tighten
up the
supply of bank reserves to get the FFR back up to the 13% set by it,
but it
could not do both, any more than a train could go in opposite
directions
simultaneously.
Volcker opted for
continuing the new
operating procedure and staged an emergency telephone conference of the
FOMC to
authorize a new low FFR target of 10.5%, down from 13%, way below the
inflation
rate of over 12%.
Market conditions
were such that interest rate falling below 10% would mean below-neutral
negative interest rate after inflation adjustment, which would start
another
borrowing binge to exacerbate further inflation. The fundamental fault
of
monetarism was being exposed by real life. The claim that stabilizing
the money
supply would also stabilize interest rates was shown to be inoperative
by
events. In reality, attempts to stabilize the money supply actually
destabilized
interest rates and pushed them down in a fast-reacting dynamic market
in an
environment of shrinking liquidity.
Desperate,
the Fed under Volcker, with
concurrence from an even more panic-stricken Carter White House,
started to
dismantle Emergency Credit Controls as fast as administratively doable,
so that
demand for credit would not be artificially shut down, in hope of
making market
interest rates rise from more borrowing. Still it took until July 1980
before
the last of the credit controls were lifted. Back in April, the New
York Fed had
injected additional reserves into the banking system at an annualized
rate of
14% and in May at 48% annualized rate in non-borrowed reserves, pushing
interest rates down and lay the ground for future inflation.
It was obvious
Volcker panicked, spooked by the sudden economic collapse set
off by his own credit-control program to slow the rise in money supply.
By the
last week of July, the FFR fell below the 13% discount rate and hit
8.5% down
from 20% in late March. For one trading day, it dipped to 7.5% and for
a time
the Fed lost control. The short-term rate that monetary policy
regulates most
directly was free-floating down on its own, unhinged from FFR target.
With the
FFR below the discount rate, the FFR could fall to zero by banks
responding to
market forces. So the pressure to lower the discount rate was
overwhelming. The
financial markets had never seen anything like it. The money market
became a
game in which the guards had thrown in the towel and the inmates were
running
the asylum.
Correcting one
Overshoot with another Overshoot
The FFR dropped from
20% in April to 8.5%
in 10 weeks, effectively banishing interest rate gradualism out to the
wilderness. In the autumn of 1979, the Fed had seized the initiative to
push
the price of money up 100% to fight inflation. Now, barely seven months
later,
the Fed allowed the price of money to fall even more rapidly to reverse
the
money-supply shrinkage, with “damn the inflation torpedo - full speed
ahead in
the sea of liquidity” frenzy. The recession abruptly ended by the Fed’s
overreaction and Volcker, the self-ordained slayer of the inflation
dragon, became
overnight a breeder of baby dragons of even more aggressive
inflationary DNA and
the economy was facing a worse, and more interest-rate immune inflation
problem
than when he first became Fed chairman in July 1979 less than a year
ago.
Many
businesses that were profitable under
a steady interest rate regime went bankrupt during this brief period of
sudden Fed-manufactured
volatility in liquidity, but the banks were dancing in the street with
windfall
profits and excess cash to lend. Volcker’s
“new operating procedure” experiment put the Fed back on its
traditional path:
focusing on interest rates and not money-supply numbers and vowing
again to
focus only on the long term. Yet for the long term, money supply was
the
correct barometer, while for the short term, interest rate was the
appropriate
tool. The Fed did not seem to have learned anything, despite having
made the
nation and the world pay a very costly tuition.
Volcker’s high
interest rate policy caused
the dollar to rise in the foreign exchange market, making US exports
less
competitive, but US investment overseas less expensive. The rise in
import
prices was moderated by lower profit margins made affordable to foreign
importers whose dollar earning now was worth more in local currencies.
Instead
of restructuring the US economy
and
to reform the terms of globalized trade to address a mounting
structural US
trade deficit, Treasury Secretary James Baker under President Reagan
took the
easy way out and engineered the Plaza Accord on September 22, 1985 to
push the
dollar down by coordinated intervention by the central banks of US,
Japan and
Germany, France and Britain. Two weeks earlier, on September 6, the Fed
had raised
the Fed Funds Rate target 25 basis points to 8% from 7.75% set
mid-July,
putting upward pressure on the dollar as the Treasury was trying to
push the
dollar down.
The Plaza Accord
when finally put in place
pushed the Japanese yen down by over 50% against the dollar with
central bank
intervention. But it had little discernable effect on the US trade deficit. It
did allow the US to export deflation
to Japan to use the dollar’s
low exchange rate to boost up US asset value
nominally. The Plaza Accord decoupled dollar
interest rates from the exchange value of the dollar and also decoupled
the
traditional link between rising interest rates and falling equity
prices.
Time Magazine
reported on January 26, 1987 that John
Makin, director of fiscal-policy studies at Washington’s American
Enterprise Institute, argued that the value of the
dollar was “totally irrelevant. If the budget deficit isn’t going to
improve
very much, the trade deficit isn’t either.” Sidney Jones, an economist
at the Brookings
Institution, also warned of a danger if the dollar’s exchange rate
continued to
serve as the main instrument for altering the trade balance: the risk
that the US inflation rate,
about 2% in 1986, would flare up. “Once those
import prices do go up, then you can get away with increasing domestic
prices.
That's probably a greater inflation risk than simply the increase in
the price
of imported goods,” Jones was quoted as saying. Yet the House passed a
highly
restrictive omnibus trade bill, but it stalled in the pro-trade
Republican-controlled
Senate.
China Enters the Trade
Picture
Predictably the same passion play
over
trade with Japan two decades ago is
now being reenacted with China. And if China yield to US
pressure as Japan did to revalue its
currency upward against the dollar, China will face decades
of deflation as Japan did. China launched
its economic reform and “open to the
outside” policy in 1978 and a good part of the excess global liquidity
resulting
from the recycling of oil revenue after the 1973 oil crisis went into
China
after 1978, and to other economies in Asia to fund the newly
industrialized
countries (NICs), known as Asian Tigers, eager to trade with and invest
in
China. For almost three decades, China has been riding on
a liquidity boom created by the US Fed’s
stealth devaluation of the purchasing power of the dollar.
Ironically, pundits
of all colors have since
applauded China for its “wisdom” in adopting market capitalism as a
path out of
poverty, while the whole world has become addicted to easy money
denominated in
dollars of falling value that actually makes everyone poorer in real
terms,
only that some become poorer more and faster by comparison. Pathetically, neo-liberal economists fell
over each other hailing the poverty eradication powers of market
fundamentalism.
The Income Equality
Hoax
J. Bradford DeLong,
an economic professor at
the University of California at Berkley and former official in the
Clinton White
House, attracted mainstream attention by claiming in a February 2001
article (The
World’s Income Distribution: Turning the Corner?) that global income
distribution has been trending towards equality through globalization.
Such
claims not only fly in the face of World Bank data on the gini
coefficient which
measures income equality in economies, they ignore the fact that all
wages were
falling in purchasing power globally even if rising nominally,
improving
statistical equality as nominal wages in poor economies rise at the
faster rate
because they started from a lower base both nominally and in real terms.
Neo-liberal ideology
asserts that inequality
is the result of poverty and that as poverty is relieved, inequality
recedes. This assertion neglects the possibility that inequality
itself
causes poverty, not as calculations in a zero sum game, but as a damper
on
consumer demand in a global economy plagued by overcapacity. Globalized
trade,
rather than domestic development, has been hailed by neo-liberal
economists as
the solution to both inequality and poverty. Opposition to
globalization by
the world’s poor has been labeled misguided by the neo-liberal
mainstream that
holds monopolistic sway in the media in defiance of glaring conditions
of
poverty on the ground.
The Harrod-Domar
Model of Development
Neo-liberal
economists point to the
Harrod-Domar model of economic growth to argue that unequal
distribution of
income promotes faster economic growth and greater employment because
the rich
save more than the poor so that a greater volume of domestic
savings will
increase the supply of capital available for investment; and the
accelerated
capital formation will raise gross domestic product and resulting
incomes, a
virtuous cycle feeding back into greater savings. Thus, income
inequality, even
with widespread poverty, is regarded as good for development, not
merely as a
transitional compromise but as a permanent structural
necessity. This is
essentially the IMF/WTO model of market fundamentalism since
discredited by
factual data.
Even Deng Xiao-ping,
paramount leader of China’s economic reform,
fell for this fallacy and accepted the need
to “let some people get rich first.” Predictably, the word “first” soon
disappeared in Chinese economic policy deliberations until it was too
late.
Finally, the new leadership in China is at long last addressing the
problem of
income disparity both between people and between regions, but the task
is made
more Herculean by the two-decade-long solidification of a political and
bureaucratic superstructure imbedded with powerful resistance of
special
interests of those who had gotten rich first and want to stay more rich
permanently.
Notwithstanding that
the Harrod-Domar model
may not be operative in a world plagued by overcapacity from
over-investment
and insufficient demand as a result of income inequality, the model
neglects
the fact that under globalized finance capitalism, even the savings of
the rich
in the poor economies are siphoned off to US capital markets, draining
the
local economy of desperately needed capital. The global dollar
glut in
the context of dollar hegemony that Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke mistook
for a
global savings glut is the living evidence against the validity of the
Harrod-Domar
model of economic growth. Income inequality in the economies that
export to the US provides capital
formation only to the US by financing a US capital account
surplus with the current account surpluses these
economies earn from trade.
China, World’s
Biggest Creditor, is Starved for Capital
This increases the
cost of capital for the exporting
economies which have to offer returns drastically higher than the
return they
get from US sovereign debt merely to induce their own capital to come
back
home. And even then, capital flows only to the export sector to earn
even more dollars
to pay foreign capital denominated in dollars, putting these economies
in a
perpetual competitive disadvantage for global capital. China is a perfect
example of a booming economy caught in this trap.
To look for better returns than what its dollar reserves get from US
Treasuries, China is beginning to
pursue so-called “alternative investment” in
higher risk private equity firms while China is continues to
face capital shortage in its rural regions and
most non-export sectors.
The GDP Growth Mirage
By the mid-1960s,
the theory equating domestic
development with GDP (gross domestic product) growth was already not
empirically supported by evidence. GDP attributes profits to the
country where
factories or mines or financial institutions are located, regardless of
ownership nationality, even though profit and investment may not stay
there
permanently. The accounting shift from GNP which measures total value
added
from both domestic and foreign sources claimed by residents of a
country, to
GDP has turned many struggling, exploited economies into statistical
boomtowns,
while seducing local leaders to embrace a global economy while their
countries
slide into further poverty.
The Perverse Logic
of Economics
But such micro
evidence has been
systemically dismissed by mainstream economics because it goes against
the
prevalent macro paradigm of trade globalization, which is deemed
intellectually
uncontestable and ideologically correct. Moreover, the evidence goes
against powerful
economic interests of the rich economies and is dismissed as the result
of a
democracy deficit. By making the rules of development treat capital as
more scarce
compared to labor and thus is the more valuable factor of production,
owners of
capital are logically justified in receiving a larger share of the
benefits
from development.
Lawrence Summers as
chief economist of the
World Bank used a similar economic argument for dumping pollution from
advanced
economies onto developing economies to achieve an overall lower cost
globally.
The only problem
with this perverted
cost-benefit approach to welfare economics is that it is not true.
Optimum
development requires capital and labor to be assigned fair and
equitable value
so that supply and demand can be balanced and for all human lives to be
treated
with equality because as many around the world have since recognized,
global
warming recognized no economic or national borders.
Foreign Central
Banks are Captured Buyers of US Sovereign Debt
In 1995, after the Federal Reserve
started
to hike the FFR target in 1994 and sharply curtailed its own purchase
of
Treasury bills, triggering the Mexico peso crisis and a
subsequent US slowdown, the Bank
of Japan initiated a program to use its
foreign reserves to buy $100 billion of US treasuries.
China bought $80 billion.
Hong Kong and Singapore bought $22 billion
each. Korea, Malaysia, Thailand, Indonesia and the Philippines bought $30 billion. The
Asian purchase totaled $260 billion from 1994 to 1997, the entire
increase in
foreign-held US dollar reserves. In
1995, East Asia claimed 47% of
capital flows to all low-and-middle-income
countries. In 1996 alone, about $100 billion flowed into East Asia,
which Asian central banks had to buy up with local currencies and
invest the
dollars in US Treasuries. But in 1997, $150 billion flowed out in the
three
months after July, exacerbating the Asian Financial Crisis by draining
foreign
reserves held by Asian central banks. These recycled dollars pushed up
stock
prices in the US both before and
after the Asian Financial Crisis.
Structured Finance
Renders Interest Rate Gradualism Inoperative
Volcker’s new
operating procedure was in 1980,
some 27 years ago. Nowadays, with structured finance, which can add
endogenous
liquidity created internally by risk management schemes to protect
against a
liquidity crunch, a new dimension has been added. That new dimension is
that in
stabilizing the money supply, instead of sending interest rates down,
it will
send interest rate skyward due to a fierce competition for money by
market
participants addicted to an endless supply of cheap money, turning the
liquidity boom into a liquidity bust. When the market anticipates money
getting
tight, everyone wants to borrow before money dries up. Money
becomes easy only if there are fewer
borrowers than money available for lending. When everybody wants more
easy
money, including lenders who must borrow money in order to lend, money
becomes
hard to get very fast.
It is now generally
recognized that the most effective way for the Fed
to
stabilize the monetary system is through a consistent, gradual “steady
as she
goes” interest rate policy without surprises or sudden reversals. The credit market has grown accustomed to
gradual interest rate policies. That is the rationale for a soft
landing to cushion
the adverse effects of the previous bubble. The problem with gradualism
is that
the approach is increasingly out of step with a fast-paced financial
world
driven by structured finance with all manners of financial derivatives
that
tend to create sudden super systemic volatility even though the
financial
instruments employed have been designed to ensure stability for
individual
market participants. High volatility has become profit opportunities
for hedge
funds and banks and traders.
Chinese Gradualism
Under Attack
Ironically,
China’s gradualism in
financial reform and exchange rate adjustment
has been vehemently attacked by impatient US officials and politicians,
notwithstanding
the Fed’s own traditional preference for monetary gradualism.
Ironically,
gradualism works in a controlled capital market which China still has, but not
in a de-controlled global capital market led
by the US.
Wicksell Provides
Greenspan with Scientific Cover
Wicksell’s theory of
linking interest rate
to the rate of return on investment (ROI) provided a timely scientific
cover
for Greenspan’s high interest rate policy in the face of an economic
slowdown
as the 2000 presidential election approached. Interest rates could
stay
high with theoretical justification because US investment offshore
was getting good returns even though the
domestic economy was showing clear signs of stagnation.
Global money supply
continues to expand
through the effect of Fed policy under dollar hegemony which permits
the US trade deficit to
finance the US capital account
surplus, keeping dollar long-term rates low
even as the Fed kept FFR high. The flat yield curve, at times inverted,
meaning
long-term rates falling below short-term rates, no longer automatically
bring
on recessions because liquidity is kept high by the circular flow from
the
trade deficit back into the capital account surplus, with inflation
kept low by
outsourced low wages and asset prices kept high by excess money that
steadily
loses purchasing power.
Trade-off Between
Global Growth and Domestic Growth
This was the point
when US economic policy
began to make the macro trade-off in seeking
benefits from globalization at the expense of the US domestic economy.
This trade off became possible because of
dollar hegemony in which global trade and finance are denominated in
fiat
dollars that the US, and only the US, can print at will with little
short-term
penalty.
Capital is permitted
to milk labor in all
economies, including labor in the US, so that global ROI
can stay high. The tradition of lowering
short-term interest rates in response to a slowing US economy has been
preempted by the need to keep short-term
interest rates high to attract capital inflow and to compensate for the
continuing
devaluation of the dollar independent of short-term exchange rate
fluctuations.
High dollar interest rates are needed to sustain the capital account
surplus. With the help of the Fed, the US
Treasury has become a major player in the “carry trade” business,
paying low
interest rate in Treasury bonds to lend the proceeds to US banks at
higher rate
which in turn lend to corporate and private borrowers as even higher
rates.
While this trade-off
had been fully
understood by the Clinton economic team led by Robert Robin, a bond
trader par
excellence from Goldman Sachs prior to joining the Clinton White House,
the
public, particular labor, had been completely oblivious until too late
to an
impending fate that would cause them to lose the shirts off their backs
made by
the Ladies Garment Workers Union members to be replaced by cheaper ones
made in
low-wage Asia, particularly China.
Bond Market Crash
Pimco’s
Total Return Bond Fund manager
William H. Gross, a highly respected veteran bond fund manager with an
impressive record for profitably managing over $100 billion of bond
funds, the
world’s largest, admitted publicly recently he made “a big mistake”
betting on
the Fed lowering interest rate to offset a slowing US economy caused by
collapse of the housing sector due to a sub-prime mortgage meltdown. As
a bond
investor, Gross understandably sets his sight single-dimensionally on
interest
rates movements since the price of bonds moves in the opposite
direction of
interest rates.
While Gross
accurately predicted a slowing
economy, he failed to realize that the Fed was pegging interest rate to
high nominal
corporate global earnings boosted by a regime of universal currency
devaluation,
but with the dollar devaluing at a faster rate than many other
currencies, thus
increasing overseas earnings in dollars terms. Pimco bond portfolios
lost on
two levels from its bad interest rate call: from a collapse in nominal
bond
prices as rates stay high and from a net long-term decline in the real
purchasing power of the dollars its bonds hold after persistent
devaluation
against real assets.
Strong Dollar is in
the US National
Interest
Of course, the
Treasury, which by law
requires the Fed to support its exchange rate policy as a matter of
national
security, has repeatedly declared that a strong dollar is in the US national interest.
And a strong dollar in the existing international
finance architecture requires high dollar interest rates. Now, in
addition to national security and national interest justifications, a
respectable
scientific theory has been resurrected to support Greenspan’s high
interest
rate policy required by his liquidity bubble.
With globalization
of trade and finance, field
data have since demolished the conventional wisdom that unemployment
below
structural level of 6% causes inflation because US consumer prices are
held down by import costs kept low by
global wage arbitrage and by low-wage illegal immigrant workers,
despite a
global decline in the purchasing power of all currencies led by dollar
hegemony.
Greenspan called his high rates “equilibrium interest rates.” But a
strong
dollar is only in relation to other key currencies, while all
currencies
continue to devalue against real assets in a global weak currency trend
led by
the dollar. Despite rhetoric, the US has not had a real
strong dollar policy for decades.
The Politics of
Economics
The Fed,
notwithstanding its intellectual pretense and self-proclaimed
political
independence, has always been a political institution. The
politics
of monetary economics repeatedly resurrects from the intellectual
wasteland,
the theoretical Siberia as it were, new
gurus to support its latest ideological
interpretation of an ever-changing economy. Nobel winners are
proponents
of theories that explain “scientifically” the latest wave of political
expediency.
The list includes
the most politically-contested
joint-award to Gunar Myrdal and Friedrich August von Hayek (1974,
Myrdal for
interdependence of economic, social and institutional phenomena in
contrast to Hayek
for theory of money, economic fluctuations and market fundamentalism)
that led
Myrdal to call for the abolition of the prize on moral grounds. Others on the list were: Milton Friedman
(1976,
monetary history and monetarism theory and stabilization policy),
Theodore W. Schultz
and Arthur Lewis (1979, economic development of developing countries),
James Tobin
(1981, financial markets and expenditure decisions, employment,
production and
prices), George J Stigler (1982, industrial structures, functioning of
markets
and causes and effects of public regulation), Franco Modigliani (1985,
saving
and of financial markets), Robert M Solow (1987, economic growth),
Robert Lucas
(1995, rational expectation), Amartya Sen (1998, welfare economics),
Robert C Merton
and Myron S Scholes (1997, precise valuation of options/derivatives),
Robert A
Mundell (1999, exchange rate regimes), George A Ackerlof, A Michael
Spence and
Joseph E Stiglitz (2001, markets with asymmetric information), etc, etc.
It is not difficult
to see that many
economic concepts honored by the Nobel Committee, while usually for
work done
decades earlier, were concepts much in vogue at the time the prizes
were
awarded, soon to be followed by real life disasters caused by the
unquestioning,
widespread applications of these very same admired concepts. The latest
example
is Stiglitz, who, very much part of the economics establishment that
promoted market
fundamentalism, summarized by the Washington Consensus, despite his
early work
on asymmetrical market information, only belatedly raised questions
about the
claim of market fundamentalism as the god-sent solution for the post
Cold War economic
order. Like the Nobel Peace Price, the Prize for Economics is highly
politicized.
Wicksell provides an
intellectually respectable
cover for Greenspan to abdicate his responsibility as Chairman of the
most
powerful central bank in the world, by pretending to follow the flow of
the market,
to treat interest rate as the price of money set by market forces, and
not as a
monetary authority with a mandate to promote full employment and
balanced growth
for the world’s interconnected economies. The embarrassing
question is
never asked why a central bank is even needed if financial markets are
on self-adjusting
auto pilot.
Everyone Has an
Income Policy
The fact is that
monetarists at the Fed are
fervently and ceaselessly intervening in the financial and currency
markets,
the only difference between them and Keynesians is that they intervene
to favor
capital as expressed by the nominal value of money while Keynesians
intervene
to protect labor from structural unemployment and below-inflation wages
deemed
necessary by monetarists for fighting inflation. As
post-Keynesian
economist Paul Davidson insightfully said: “everyone has an income
policy; they
just don't like the other fellow’s income policy but claiming their own
is
‘free’ market determined.” Extending their distaste for inept
bureaucracy, neo-conservatives
monetarists reject the policy imperative of government while
neo-liberal
monetarists reject government responsibility for the welfare of all
citizens by
favoring an income policy favoring the rich.
A New Guru
The installation of
a new guru at the Fed stimulates
rethinks on Wall Street. Traders and investors now have to
reverse their traditional
knee-jerk reaction to sell when the Fed raised short-term interest
rates. Even
as real corporate earnings fall amid rising rates, such falls are
disguised nominally
as rising profit by across-the-board currency devaluation.
Wicksell, born in Stockholm,
Sweden, published his
book: Value, Capital and Rent (1893) in Swedish,
which was not translated into English until 1954. His two-volume
Lectures on
Political Economy (1901-6,) and Selected Papers on Economic Theory
(1958) were
read only by professionals. Wicksell did rigorous work on marginal
theory
of price and distribution and on monetary theory. The Lectures on
Political
Economy has been aptly called a “textbook for professors”. In an
unusually volatile
career, including brief imprisonment for exercising free speech rights,
he
wrote and lectured tirelessly on radical issues, which did not figure
among the
attitudes admired by Greenspan, a disciple of Ayn Rand’s cultish
objectivism of
extreme individualism.
Wicksell was an
advocate of social and
economic reforms of all sorts, most notably neo-Malthusian population
controls.
He extended Ricardo’s concept of uneven income distribution based on
the iron
law of wages, asserting that a totally free economy does not naturally
equalize
wealth distribution, as wealth created by growth would be distributed
in
greater share to those who already had wealth. Wicksell defended
government
intervention to improve national and public welfare through equitable
distribution of the benefits of growth.
Wicksell’s theory of
interest, published in
his 1898 book, Interest and Prices, distinguishes the natural rate of
interest
from the money rate of interest. The money rate of interest, or nominal
rate,
is merely the interest rate in the capital markets while the natural
rate of
interest is the interest rate that is neutral to prices in the real
market, or
rather, the interest rate at which supply and demand in the real market
are at
equilibrium. Economic growth takes place when the natural rate of
interest is
higher than the market rate; a view shared by the Austrian
School, despite the
difference Austrian individualism has with the
institutionalism of Wicksell.
In his later years,
Wicksell was admired by
a new generation of economists who became known as the Stockholm
School whose members
include Nobel laureates Gunnar Myrdal (1974-institutional
interdependence) and Bertil Ohlin (1977-trade theory). They developed
Wicksell’s
ideas on the cumulative process into a dynamic theory of monetary
macroeconomics simultaneously with but independently of the Keynesian
revolution.
Greenspan’s
selective use of other people’s idea is notorious.
His fondness
of Schumpetrean “creative destruction” which he cites in practically
every speech,
always leaves out the second half of Schumpeter’s world view: that
“creative
destruction” leads to monopolies (a la Microsoft) and accelerates the
coming of
socialism, the worst possible nightmare for Greenspan and his fellow
central
bankers.
Joseph A. Schumpeter
(1883-1950) writes in
his Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy (1942 Chapter 3): “Economic
progress in
capitalist society means turmoil.” And in Chapter 13, sect. 2, he
writes:
“Capitalism inevitably and by virtue of the very logic of its
civilization
creates, educates and subsidizes a vested interest in social unrest.”
Keynesianism
aims to save capitalism by taming its internal contradiction with a
moderate
dose of socialist prescription.
Next: Currency
Devaluation Depresses Wages Globally
|
|
|
|
|