|
Critique of Central
Banking
By
Henry C K Liu
Part I:
Monetary theology
This article
first appeared in Asia
Times on Line on November 6, 2002
Central bankers
are like librarians who consider a well-run library to
be one in which all the books are safely stacked on the shelves and
properly catalogued. To reduce incidents of late returns or loss, they
would proposed more strict lending rules, ignoring that the measure of
a good library lies in full circulation. Librarians take pride in the
size of their collections rather than the velocity of their
circulation.
Central bankers
take the same attitude toward money. Central bankers
view their job as preserving the value of money through the restriction
of its circulation, rather than maximizing the beneficial effect of
money on the economy through its circulation. Many central bankers
boast about the size of their foreign reserves the way librarians boast
about the size of their collections, while their governments pile up
budget deficits. Paul Volcker, the US central banker widely credited
with ending inflation in the early 1980s by administering wholesale
financial blood letting on the US economy, quipped lightheartedly at a
Washington party that "central bankers are brought up pulling legs off
of ants".
Central banking
insulates monetary policy from national economic policy
by prioritizing the preservation of the value of money over the
monetary needs of a sound national economy. A global finance
architecture based on universal central banking allows an often
volatile foreign exchange market to operate to facilitate the instant
cross-border ebb and flow of capital and debt instruments. The workings
of an unregulated global financial market of both capital and debt
forced central banking to prevent the application of the State Theory
of Money (STM) in individual countries to use sovereign credit to
finance domestic development by penalizing, with low exchange rates for
their currencies, governments that run budget deficits.
STM asserts
that the acceptance of government-issued legal tender,
commonly known as money, is based on government's authority to levy
taxes payable in money. Thus the government can and should issue as
much money in the form of credit as the economy needs for sustainable
growth without fear of hyperinflation. What monetary economists call
the money supply is essentially the sum total of credit aggregates in
the economy, structured around government credit as bellwether.
Sovereign credit is the anchor of a vibrant domestic credit market so
necessary for a dynamic economy.
By making STM
inoperative through the tyranny of exchange rates,
central banking in a globalized financial market robs individual
governments of their sovereign credit prerogative and forces sovereign
nations to depend on external capital and debt to finance domestic
development. The deteriorating exchange value of a nation's currency
then would lead to a corresponding drop in foreign direct or indirect
investment (capital inflow), and a rise in interest cost for sovereign
and private debts, since central banking essentially relies on interest
policy to maintain the value of money. Central banking thus relies on
domestic economic austerity caused by high interest rates to achieve
its institutional mandate of maintaining price stability.
Such domestic
economic austerity comes in the form of systemic credit
crunches that cause high unemployment, bankruptcies, recessions and
even total economic collapse, as in the case of Britain in 1992, the
Asian financial crisis in 1997 and subsequent crises in Russia, Turkey,
Brazil and Argentina. It is the economic equivalent of a blood-letting
cure.
A national bank
does not seek independence from the government. The
independence of central banks is a euphemism for a shift from
institutional loyalty to national economic well-being toward
institutional loyalty to the smooth functioning of a global financial
architecture. The international finance architecture at this moment in
history is dominated by US dollar hegemony, which can be simply defined
by the dollar's unjustified status as a global reserve currency. The
operation of the current international finance architecture requires
the sacrifice of local economies in a financial food chain that feeds
the issuer of US dollars. It is the monetary aspect of the predatory
effects of globalization.
Historically,
the term "central bank" has been interchangeable with the
term "national bank". In fact, the enabling act to establish the first
national bank, the Bank of the United States, referred to the bank
interchangeably as a central and a national bank. However, with the
globalization of financial markets in recent decades, a central bank
has become fundamentally different from a national bank.
The mandate of
a national bank is to finance the sustainable
development of the national economy, and its function aims to adjust
the value of a nation's currency at a level best suited for achieving
that purpose within an international regime of exchange control. On the
other hand, the mandate of a modern-day central bank is to safeguard
the value of a nation's currency in a globalized financial market of no
or minimal exchange control, by adjusting the national economy to
sustain that narrow objective, through economic recession and negative
growth if necessary.
Central banking
tends to define monetary policy within the narrow
limits of price stability. In other words, the best monetary policy in
the context of central banking is a non-discretionary money-supply
target set by universal rules of price stability, unaffected by the
economic needs or political considerations of individual nations.
The
theology of monetary economics
Inflation, the
all-consuming target of central banking, is popularly
thought of as too much money chasing too few goods, which economists
refer to as the Quantity Theory of Money (QTM). QTM is one of the
oldest surviving economic doctrines. Simply stated, it asserts that
changes in the general level of commodity prices are determined
primarily by changes in the quantity of money in circulation. But the
theology of monetary economics has a long and complex history, an
understanding of which is necessary for forming any informed opinion on
the validity and purpose of central banking. Below is a brief summary
of the stuff dinner conversation is made of among the gods of monetary
theory.
Jean Bodin
(1530-96), a French social/political philosopher, attributed
the price inflation then raging in Western Europe to the abundance of
monetary metals imported from the newly opened gold and silver mines in
the Spanish colonies in South America. Though he held many aspects of
mercantilist views, Bodin asserted that the rise of prices was a
function not merely of the debasement of the coinage, but also of the
amount of currency in circulation. Bodin's religious tolerance in a
period of fanatical religious wars drew upon him the accusation of
being a "freethinker", a label as damaging as being called a communist
sympathizer in the United States in modern times. In his Les Six
Livrers de la republic (1576), Bodin replaced the concept of a past
golden age with the concept of progress. He foreshadowed Thomas Hobbes
(1588-1679: The Leviathan, 1651) by stating the political
necessity of absolute sovereignty, subject only to the laws of God
(morality) and nature (reality). Bodin also anticipated Baron
Montesquieu (1689-1755: De l'esprit des lois, 1748) by
highlighting environment as a determinant of laws, customs, beliefs and
the interpretation of events, a view that influenced the US
constitution, a view since rejected by current US moral imperialism.
John Locke
(1632-1704) and David Hume (1711-76) provided considerable
refinement, elaboration and extension to the QTM, allowing it to be
integrated into the mainstream of orthodox monetarist tradition. Locke
developed the right of private property based on the labor theory of
value and the mechanics of political checks and balances that were
incorporated in the US constitution. Locke, in 1661, asserted the
proportionality postulate: that a doubling of the quantity of money (M)
will double the level of prices (P) and half the value of the monetary
unit.
Hume, in 1752,
introduced the notion of causation by stating that
variation in M (money quantity) will cause proportionate changes in P
(price level). Concurrently with Irish banker Richard Cantillon
(1680-1734), Hume applied to the QTM two crucial distinctions: 1)
between static (long-run stationary equilibrium) and dynamic (short-run
movement toward equilibrium); and 2) between the long-run neutrality
and the short-run non-neutrality of money. Hume and Cantillon provided
the first dynamic process analysis of how the impact of a monetary
change spread from one sector of the economy to another, altering
relative price and quantity in the process. They pointed out that most
monetary injection would involve non-neutral distribution effects. New
money would not be distributed among individuals in proportion to their
pre-existing share of money holdings. Those who receive more will
benefit at the expense of those receiving less than their proportionate
share, and they will exert more influence in determining the
composition of new output. Initial distribution effects temporarily
alter the pattern of expenditure and thus the structure of production
and the allocation of resources. Thus it is understandable that
conservatives would be sympathetic to the QTM to maintain the wealth
distribution status quo, or if the QTM is skirted, to ensure that the
maldistribution tilts toward those who are more likely to engage in
capital formation, namely the rich. Thus developing economies in need
of capital formation would find logic in first enriching the financial
elite while advanced economies with production overcapacity would need
to increase aggregate demand by restricting income disparity.
Hume describes
how different degrees of money illusion among income
recipients, coupled with time delays in the adjustment process, could
cause costs to lag behind prices, thus creating abnormal profits and
stimulating optimistic profit expectations that would spur business
expansion and employment during the transition period. These
non-neutral effects are not denied by the adherents of QTM, who
nevertheless assert that they are bound to dissipate in the long run,
often with great damage if the optimism was unjustified. The latest
evidence of the non-neutral effects of money is observable in expansion
of the so-called New Economy from easy money in the past decade and the
recent collapse of its bubble.
The QTM formed
the central core of 19th-century classical monetary
analysis, provided the dominant conceptual framework for interpreting
contemporary financial events and formed the intellectual foundation of
orthodox policy prescription designed to preserve the gold standard.
The economic structure in 19th-century Europe led analysts to
acknowledge additional non-neutral effects, such as the lag of money
wages behind prices, which temporarily reduces real wages; the stimulus
to output occasioned by inflation-induced reduction in real debt
burdens, which shifts real income from unproductive creditor-rentiers
to productive debtor-entrepreneurs; the so-called "forced saving"
effect occasioned by price-induced redistribution of income among
socio-economic classes having structurally different propensity to save
and invest; and the stimulus to investment imparted by a temporary
reduction in the rate of interest below the anticipated rate of return
on new capital.
Yet classical
quantity theorists tended persistently to minimize the
importance of non-neutral effects as merely transitional. Whereas Hume
tended to stress lengthy dynamic disequilibrium periods in which money
matters much, classical analysts focused on long-run equilibrium in
which money is merely a veil. David Ricardo (1772-1823), the most
influential of the classical economists, thought such disequilibrium
effects ephemeral and unimportant in long-run equilibrium analysis.
Gods, of course, enjoy longer perspectives than most mortals, as do the
rich over the poor. As John Maynard Keynes famously said: "In the long
run, we will all be dead."
As leader of
the Bullionists, Ricardo charged that inflation in Britain
was solely the result of the Bank of England's irresponsible overissue
of money, when in 1797, under the stress of the Napoleonic Wars,
Britain left the gold standard for inconvertible paper. At that time,
the Bank of England was still operating as a national bank, not a
central bank in the modern sense of the term. In other words, it
operated to improve the English economy rather than to strengthen the
sanctity of international finance. Ricardo, by focusing on long
term-equilibrium, discouraged discussions on the possible beneficial
output and employment effects of monetary injection on the national
level. Like modern-day monetarists, Bullionists laid the source of
inflation, a decidedly evil force in international finance, squarely at
the door of the national bank. As Milton Friedman declared some two
centuries after Richardo: inflation is everywhere a monetary
phenomenon. Friedman's concept of "money matters" is the diametrical
opposite of Hume's.
The historical
evolution in 18th-century Europe from a predominantly
full-metal money to a mixed metal-paper money forced advances in the
understanding of the monetary transmission mechanism. After gold coins
had given way to banknotes, Hume's direct mechanism of price adjustment
was found lacking in explaining how banknotes are injected into the
system.
Henry Thornton
(1760-1815), in his classic The Paper Credit of
Great Britain (1802), provided the first description of the
indirect mechanism by observing that new money created by banks enters
the financial markets initially via an expansion of bank loans, through
increasing the supply of lendable funds, temporarily reducing the loan
rate of interest below the rate of return on new capital, thus
stimulating additional investment and loan demand. This in turn pushes
prices up, including capital good prices, drives up loan demands and
eventually interest rates, bringing the system back into equilibrium
indirectly.
The central
issue of the doctrines of the British classical school that
dominated the first half of the 19th century was focused around the
application of the QTM to government policy, which manifested itself in
the maintenance of external equilibrium and the restoration and defense
of the gold standard. Consequently, the QTM tended to be directed
toward the analysis of international price levels, gold flow,
exchange-rate fluctuations and trade deficits. It formed the foundation
of mercantilism, which underpinned the economic structure of the
British Empire via colonialism, which reached institutional maturity in
the same period.
Bullionists
developed the idea that the stock of money, or its currency
component, could be effectively regulated by controlling a narrowly
defined monetary base, that the control of "high-power money" (bank
reserves) in a fractional reserve banking regime implies virtual
control of the money supply. High-power money is the totality of bank
reserves that would be multiplied many times through the money-creation
power of commercial bank lending, depending on the velocity of
circulation.
In the 1987
crash when the Dow Jones Industrial Average (DJIA) dropped
22.6 percent in one day (October 19) on volume of 608 million shares,
six times the normal volume then (current normal daily volume is about
1.6 billion shares), the US Federal Reserve under its newly installed
chairman, Alan Greenspan, created US$12 billion of new bank reserves by
buying up government securities. The $12 billion injection of
high-power money in one day caused the Fed Funds rate to fall by
three-quarters of a point and halted the financial panic. If the
government had been running a balanced budget and there were no
government securities to be bought, the economy would have seized up.
This shows that government deficits and debt are part and parcel of the
modern financial architecture.
In the three
decades after Britain returned to the gold standard in
1821, the policy objective focused on the maintenance of fixed exchange
rates and the automatic gold convertibility of the pound. But the
Currency School (CS) versus Banking School (BS) controversy broke out
over whether the "Currency Principle" of making existing mixed
gold-paper currency expand and contract in direct proportion to gold
reserves was sufficient to safeguard against note overissuance, or
whether additional regulation was necessary. This controversy grew out
of the expansion pressure put on the supply of pound sterling by the
rapid expansion of the British empire.
Members of the
CS argued that even a fully, legally convertible
currency could be issued in excess with undesirable consequences, such
as rising domestic prices relative to foreign prices,
balance-of-payment deficits, falling foreign-exchange rates, gold
outflow resulting in depletion of gold reserves and ultimately forced
suspension of convertibility. The rate of reserves drain often
accelerated when the external gold drain coincided with internal
domestic-panic conversion of paper into gold in fear of pending
depreciation. Thus the CS promoted full convertibility plus strict
regulation of the volume of banknotes to prevent the recurrence of gold
drains, exchange depreciation and domestic liquidity crises.
The
apprehension of the CS was fully justified by past actions of the
Bank of England, which had been perverse and destabilizing by
international finance standards. The destabilizing argument stressed
the time lag on the Bank's policy response to gold outflow and to
exchange-rate movements. The inevitably too little, too late measures
taken by the national bank, instead of protecting gold reserves, merely
exacerbated financial panics and liquidity crises that inevitably
followed periods of currency-credit excess. The famous Bank Charter Act
of 1844, in modern parlance, imposed a 100 percent reserve requirement,
with an unabashed bias toward wealth preservation over wealth creation.
The CS also asserts that money substitutes cannot impair the
effectiveness of monetary regulation. Thus if banknotes could be
controlled, there would be no need to control deposits explicitly, on
the ground that money substitutes have low velocity and are of
declining substitutional value in times of crisis.
Keynesians
argue that the QTM is invalid because it assumes an
automatic tendency to full employment. If resource under-ultilization
and excess capacity exist, a monetary expansion may produce a rise in
output rather than a rise in prices, as in the case of the 1930s
Depression. Money is not a mere veil. Monetary changes may have a
permanent effect on output, interest rates, and other real variables,
contrary to the neutrality postulate of the QTM. Post-Keynesians also
contend that the QTM erroneously assumes the stability of velocity and
its counterpart, the demand for money. Velocity is a volatile,
unpredictable variable (technically known as exogenous - due to
external causes), influenced by meta-rationality and by changes in the
volume of money substitutes, not to mention hedges in the form of
derivatives. The erratic behavior of velocity makes it impossible to
predict the effect of a given monetary change on prices.
John Law
(1671-1729), a contemporary of Bodin, elaborated in 1705 on
the distinction drawn by Bernardo Davanzati (1529-1606) between "value
in exchange" and "value in use", which led Law to introduce his famous
"water-diamond" paradox: that water, which has great use-value, has no
exchange-value, while diamonds, which have great exchange-value, have
no use-value. Contrary to Adam Smith, who used the same example but
explained it on the basis of water and diamonds having different labor
costs of production, Law regarded the relative scarcity of goods in
demand as the generator of exchange value.
Davanzati
showed how "barter is a necessary complement of division of
labor amongst men and amongst nations"; and how there is easily a "want
of coincidence in barter", which calls for a "medium of exchange"; and
this medium must be capable of "subdivision" and be a "store of value".
He remarked "that one single egg was more worth to Count Ugolino in his
tower [prison] than all the gold of the world", but that on the other
hand, "ten thousand grains of corn are only worth one of gold in the
market", and that "water, however necessary for life, is worth nothing,
because superabundant". That was of course before International
Monetary Fund (IMF) conditionality requiring the poor in the indebted
Third World to pay for water through privatization of basic utilities
to service foreign debt.
Davanzati
observed that in the siege of Casilino, "a rat was sold for
200 florins, and the price could not be called exaggerated, because
next day the man who sold it was starved and the man who bought it was
still alive". Of course, modern economists would call that a market
failure. Davanzati viewed all the money in a country as worth all the
goods, because the one exchanges for the other and nobody wants money
for its own sake. Davanzati did not know anything about the velocity of
money, and only recognized that every country needs a different
quantity of money, as different human frames need different quantities
of blood. The mint ought to coin money gratuitously for everybody; and
the fear that, if the coins are too good, they should be exported is
simply illusory, because they must have been paid for by the exporter.
Law's "Real
Bills Doctrine" of money applied the "reflux principle" to
the money supply. Money, Law argued, was credit and credit was
determined by the "needs of trade". Consequently, the amount of money
in existence is determined not by the imports of gold or trade balances
(as the Mercantilists argued), but rather on the supply of credit in
the economy. And money supply (in opposition to the Quantity Theory) is
endogenous (growing from within), determined by the "needs of trade".
Post-Keynesians
have drawn on the Real Bills Doctrine, which asserts
that the money supply is an endogenous variable that responds passively
to shifts in the demand for it. Thus monetary changes cannot affect
prices. Being demand-determined, the stock of money cannot exceed or
fall short of the quantity of money demanded. In short, there is no
transmission mechanism running from money to prices. Analysts should
look instead for the source of economic dislocations in real rather
than monetary causes. Inflation creates a corresponding increase in the
money supply, not the other way around. Yet QTM theorists exposed the
Achilles' heel of the Real Bills Doctrine by demonstrating that as long
as the loan rate of interest is below the expected yield on new capital
projects, the demand for loans will be insatiable. Thus the "real
bills" criterion as an automatic regulator of the money supply is
inoperative unless central banks intervene to raise interest rates in
concert with expected return on capital.
The attack on
the QTM from the Banking School (BS) also supported
modern Keynesian views, by pointing out that new money may simply be
absorbed into idle balances (gold hoards, a liquidity trap) without
entering the spending stream, while the supply of money is determined
by the need of trade and thus can never exceed demand (in modern
parlance: pushing on the credit string). The BS went farther than the
"Real Bills" argument that even if the real-bills criterion of
restriction of loans to self-liquidating paper were violated, the law
of reflux would prevent overissue. Holders of excess papers would
simply redeposit them in banks rather than spending them. The BS
asserts that prices are determined by income and not by the quantity of
money. For national economies, factor incomes earned from overseas
investment, rather than money, are the sources of expenditure that act
on prices, unless neutralized by imports. This income-expenditure
approach was later developed by Keynes and became a characteristic
feature of Keynesian macro-economic models.
The BS also
disputed the quantity-theory view of money as an exogenous
or external independent variable by arguing that the stock of money and
credit is a passive, endogenous demand-determined variable. The stock
of money and credit is the effect, not the cause, of price changes. The
channel of causation runs from prices to money, not the opposite
direction as contended by the CS. What determines the volume of
currency in circulation is the active initiation of the non-bank public
(borrowers) with the banks playing only a passive accommodating role.
Implicit in the BS view of massive money are three anti-quantity theory
propositions: 1) changes in economic activities precede and cause
changes in the money supply (the reverse causation argument); 2) the
supply of circulating media is not independent of the demand for it and
3) the central bank does not actively control the money supply, but
instead accommodates or responds to prior changes in the demand for
money. Against the CS emphasis on a narrowly defined money supply, the
BS emphasized the overall structure of credit.
The BS
advocates more free banking against regulated banking, favoring
the discretion of bankers over regulation by government or fixed rules,
and, most important, the BS regards attempts to regulate prices via
monetary control as futile, since the money supply, especially notes,
is an endogenous variable independent of exogenous control. BS views
fighting inflation via the supply of money and credit as putting the
cart before the horse, since it is prices that determine the quantity
of money and credit, and not vice versa.
Despite the
BS's criticism, the QTM emerged victorious from the
mid-19th century Currency-Banking Debate to command wide acceptance
until the 1930s. The CS policy of fixed exchange rate, gold standard,
convertibility and strict control of banknotes became British monetary
orthodoxy in the second half of the 19th century within the context of
the triumph of British imperialism. But the rigorous mathematical
restatement of the QTM by neo-classical economists around the dawn of
the 20th century was the crowning factor to QTM's success in
intellectual circles.
Irving Fisher
(1876-1947) in his classic The Purchasing Power of
Money (1911) spelled out his famous equation of exchange: MV=PT,
where M is the stock of money, V is the velocity of circulation, P is
the price level and T is the physical volume of market transaction.
This and other equations, such as the Cambridge cash balance equation,
which corresponds with the emerging use of mathematics in neo-classical
economic analysis, define precisely the conditions under which the
proportional postulate is valid.
Yet these
conditions include constancy of the velocity of money and of
real output. Neoclassical economics assumed that velocity was a near
constant determined by individuals' cash-holding decisions in
conjunction with technological and institutional factors associated
with the aggregate payment mechanism. Today, with interest-bearing cash
accounts, electronic payment regimes and cashless credit-card
transactions, such assumptions are less valid. Money velocity, like
wind velocity in a weather pattern, fluctuates widely and suddenly,
caused by complex factors feeding back on each other.
Fisher and
other neo-classical economists, such as Arthur Cecil Pigou
(1877-1959) of Cambridge, demonstrated that monetary control could be
achieved in a fractional reserve banking regime via control of an
exogenously determined stock of high-power money. Underlying their
argument that the total stock of money and bank deposits would be a
constant multiple of the monetary base is the claim that the stock of
money is governed by three proximate determinants: 1) the high-power
monetary base, 2) the banks' desired reserve to deposit ratio and 3)
the public's desired cash-to-deposit ratio, and with the the monetary
base dominating determinants 2) and 3). Again the financial reality
today is very different. Banks routinely borrow through the repos
window to bypass reserve requirements. Banks, to reduce the capital
requirement based on their balance sheets, also sell their loans
regularly as securitized financial products in the credit markets. Yet
QTM continues to exercise a strong hold on monetary theory.
Neo-classical
quantity theorists stress the long-run non-neutrality of
money, a topic not well developed in classical analysis. They integrate
the QTM into their analysis of business cycles, identifying the
quantity of money as a major cause of booms and busts and monetary
effects on price as a prerequisite to the stabilization of economic
activity.
It was not
until the 1930s that the QTM encountered serious criticism
and was discredited, replaced by the Keynesian income-expenditure
model. Notwithstanding Keynes' earlier support for QTM in A Tract
on Monetary Reform (1923), Keynes' General Theory (1936)
launched a frontal attack on QTM by observing that if the economy were
operating at less than full employment, with idle resources to draw
from, changes in spending would affect output and employment rather
than prices.
Keynes reversed
the QTM assumption by treating prices as rigid and
output flexible, a situation any businessman could recognize. Keynes
criticized the QTM equations as tautological and that QTM erroneously
treated the circulatory velocity of money as a near constant. Keynes
pointed out that the velocity variable in Fisher's equation was in
reality extremely unstable by showing that any change in M (money
stock) might be absorbed by an offsetting change in V (circulation
velocity) and therefore would not be transmitted to P (price level).
Likewise, any change in income or the volume of market transaction
might be accommodated by a change in velocity without requiring any
change in the money supply.
Keynes revived
the BS conclusion that economic disturbances arise from
exogenous shocks originating in the real economy rather than from
erratic behavior of the money supply, and the futility of using
monetary policy to regulate economic activity to cure unemployment and
recession. The conclusion was based on Keynes' theory of an absolute
preference for liquidity at low interest-rate levels - the case for the
liquidity trap. Keynes argued that either a liquidity trap or
interest-insensitive investment draught could render a monetary
expansion ineffective in a depression. Keynes stressed a new
non-monetary adjustment mechanism - the income multiplier. The chief
policy implication of the Keynesian income-expenditure analysis was
that fiscal policy would have a more powerful impact on income and
employment than would monetary policy.
Post-Keynesian
economists added to Keynes' contra-QTM arguments by
pointing out that inflation is predominantly a cost-pushed phenomenon
associated with non-monetary institutional forces, such as union wage
inelasticity, monopoly pricing, etc. Cheap money, Post-Keynesian
advocates assert, from expansionary monetary policy could be used to
keep interest rates at low levels, minimizing the burden of both
private and public debt, helping to keep unemployment at permanently
low levels. These positions depart from the neutrality proposition. The
Radcliffe Committee on British monetary reform in 1959 declared that 1)
money is an indistinguishable component of a continuous spectrum of
financial assets; 2) the velocity of money is devoid of economic
content; and 3) attempts to regulate spending via monetary control are
futile in a financial system that can produce a limitless array of
money substitutes. The Radcliffe Committee declaration is in fact an
update of the Banking School.
Then came
Milton Friedman, who remodeled the QTM into a theory of the
demand for money. It was based on the wealth effect, or the theory of
real balance effect, which argues that prices would fall in a
depression, thereby raising the purchasing power of wealth held in
money from. The price-induced rise in the real value of cash balances
would then stimulate spending directly until full capacity utilization
had been attained. As the wealth effect operates independently of
changes in interest rates, closure of the indirect channel could not
prevent the restoration of full employment. It follows that a rise in
the real balances and hence spending could be accomplished just as
easily via a monetary expansion, validating the potency of monetary
policy even in a depression.
This argument
offered an escape from the Keynesian liquidity trap and a
way of thwarting the interest inelasticity of the investment-spending
draught, thus contradicting the Keynesian doctrine of underemployment
equilibrium. Friedman suggested that the Keynesian view of the monetary
transmission mechanism was seriously incomplete. In denying that the
quantity theory was a theory of income determination, Friedman freed it
from the Keynesian criticism that it assumes full employment. In their A
Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960, Friedman and Anna
Schwartz showed that a rapid and large reduction in the money supply
played the dominant causal role in the Great Depression of the 1930s.
Their observation led to criticism of the Keynesian attribution of the
Depression to a collapse of demand.
Monetarists
argue that the quantity of money, rather than the level and
channels of interest rates, is the appropriate variable for the
monetary authority to regulate. Greenspan in essence applied this
theory to prolong economic expansion in the United States after 1997
and produced the biggest bubble since the 1920s.
Monetarists
regard monetary policy as having a powerful long-run impact
on nominal income as contrasted with fiscal policy. They regard income
policy as having a perverse long-term impact on economic activity.
Despite lip service paid to the notion of the direct effect of monetary
changes on commodity expenditure, modern monetarists acknowledge that
the transmission mechanism operates primarily through a complex
portfolio or balance-sheet adjustment process involving various
interest-rate channels and affecting a wide range of assets and
expenditures, generating shifts in the composition of asset portfolios,
thereby inducing prices and yields of existing financial and
non-financial assets relative to prices of current services and new
assets, albeit that the portfolio approach is not of monetary origin,
having been first developed by Keynes and J R Hicks in the mid-1930s
and subsequently elaborated by James Tobin and others. These asset
price and yield changes, in turn, generate changes in the demands for
service flows and new asset stocks and hence in the prices and output
of latter items.
The question of
the appropriate range of assets and interest rates to
be considered in the analysis of the transmission mechanism is a key
point in the monetarist-Keynesian controversy over the spending impact
of monetary changes. Keynesian models tended to concentrate on a
narrower range of assets and interest rates, forcing the transmission
process through a narrow channel, thus choking off some of the spending
impact of a monetary change.
Of course, in
Keynes' days, the financial architecture was primarily a
two-asset world: cash and bonds, fundamentally different from today's
infinite range of financial assets in the brave new world of structured
finance. Modern monetarists generally favor flexible exchange rates
without exchange control, whereas the Currency School advocated fixed
rates with exchange control.
Next:
The
European experience
|
|
|
|
|