China vs the
almighty dollar
By
Henry C K Liu
This article appeared in AToL on
July 23, 2002
The Italian Marxist thinker Antonio Gramsci, while under Fascist
imprisonment, developed the concept of cultural hegemony: control
people's minds, and their hearts and hands will follow. Gramsci
explained how one dominant class can establish its control over others
through ideological dominance. Whereas orthodox Marxism explains social
structure as shaped by economic forces, Gramsci adds the crucial
cultural dimension. He showed how, once ideological authority (or
"cultural hegemony") is established, the use of overt violence to
impose control can become superfluous.
Today, the world lives under the virtually undisputed rule of a
market-dominated, ultra-competitive (yet not fairly competitive),
globalized society with its cortege of manifold iniquities and
legalized violence. Many public and private institutions in all nations
that genuinely believe they are working for a more equitable world have
unwittingly contributed to the violent triumph of neoliberalism. Field
evidence, however, shows that perpetual prosperity for anyone, let
alone all, under market fundamentalism is merely an empty promise of
neoliberalism. And the time may be ripe for China, as Asia's largest
economy, to break free of a global market economy that nears collapse.
The chairman of the US Federal Reserve Board, Allan Greenspan, now
proudly uses the term "hegemony", in congressional testimony to
describe officially US financial preeminence and structural advantage.
Unlike ideology, politics deal not only with moral validity, but also
with power. The ideology of neoliberalism appears empirically operative
because it has the hegemonic power to construct a "real" world that
appears internally consistent and theoretically rational, with the aid
of "scientific" neoclassical economics theories. No matter how many
socioeconomic disasters the neoliberal globalized system of market
fundamentalism has visibly caused, no matter what financial crises
neoliberal free markets have engendered, no matter how many losers and
outcasts it has created, market fundamentalism is still promoted as
indispensable, like the word of God, as the only possible economic and
social order available for human salvation. Margaret Thatcher's TINA
(There Is No Alternative) explains it all. Economic slavery, though
unfortunate, is preferable to starvation, according to neoliberal
doctrine, which falsely poses slavery or death by starvation as natural
alternatives of human civilization. The World Bank has estimated that
neoliberal globalization has created 200 million newly poor people
around the world in the past decade. Yet claims of globalization's
contribution to global prosperity continue unabated.
Former US president Bill Clinton's claim at the 2000 Asia Pacific
Economic Cooperation (APEC) meeting that open economies have shown the
highest growth rate is part of this cultural hegemonic push. Clinton
had it backwards: it is the countries that have the highest growth
rates resulting from complex conditions of structural advantage that
are pushing for further selective openness in the poorer economies. The
most fundamental flaw in the neoliberal logic is that the selective
push for full and unregulated mobility for capital across national
borders is not accompanied with the same mobility for labor.
It is self-evident that capital cannot exist without labor. Without
labor, capital is merely an idle asset, unable to contribute to
productivity. Until labor can move freely in the globalized system,
there is no real openness. The current system is not true
globalization. It is merely a global expansion of US financial hegemony
through dollar hegemony: the domination of the global economy by the US
national currency.
Dollar hegemony is a structural condition in world finance and trade in
which the US produces dollars and the rest of the world produce things
dollars can buy. In 1971, the late US president Richard Nixon abandoned
the Bretton Woods regime of a gold-backed dollar and fixed exchange
rates to stop the gold drain from the US Treasury caused by chronic
lapses of US fiscal discipline. At that point, the dollar, as a fiat
currency, theoretically abdicated its reserve-currency status for world
trade. Yet for more than three decades since, the dollar has remained
the reserve currency for world trade despite continued chronic US
government and trade deficits and the transformation of the United
States into the world's most indebted nation. Notwithstanding its role
as the leading proponent of market fundamentalism, the United States
maintains a strong-dollar policy as a matter of national interest, in
defiance of market forces.
A reserve currency for world trade without the necessary disciplinary
backup is in reality a tax by the issuing sovereign on all other
sovereigns participating in world trade via that currency.
The State Theory of Money (Chartalism) holds that the acceptance of a
currency is based fundamentally on a government's power to tax. It is
the government's willingness to accept the currency it issues for
payment of taxes that gives the issuance currency within a nation. The
Chartalist theory of money, as summarized by economist Randall Wray,
claims that all governments, by virtual of their power to levy taxes
payable with government-designated legal tender, do not need external
financing and should be able to be the employer of last resort to
maintain full employment. The logic of Chartalism reasons that an
excessively low tax rate will result in a low demand for the currency
and that a chronic budget surplus is economically counterproductive
because it drains credit from the economy. The colonial administration
in British Africa learned that land taxes were instrumental in inducing
the carefree natives into using its currency and engaging in financial
productivity.
Thus, according to Chartalist theory, an economy can finance its
domestic developmental needs to achieve full employment and maximum
growth with prosperity without any need for foreign loans or
investment, and without the penalty of hyperinflation. But Chartalist
theory is operative only in closed domestic monetary regimes. Countries
participating in free trade in a globalized system, especially in
unregulated global financial and currency markets, cannot operate on
Chartalist principles because of the foreign-exchange dilemma. Any
government printing its own currency to finance domestic needs beyond
the size of its foreign-exchange reserves will soon find its currency
under attack in the foreign-exchange markets, regardless of whether the
currency is pegged to a fixed exchanged rate or is free-floating. Thus
all economies must accumulate dollars before they can attract foreign
capital. Even then foreign capital will only invest in the export
sector where dollar revenue can be earned. But the dollars that Asian
economies accumulate from trade surpluses can only be invested in
dollar assets in the United States, depriving local economies of needed
capital. The only protection from such attacks on currency is to
suspend convertibility, which then will keep foreign investment away.
Precisely to prevent such currency attacks, tight controls on the
international flow of capital were set up by the Bretton Woods system
of fixed exchange rates pegged to a gold-backed dollar after World War
II. Drawing lessons from the prewar 1930s Depression, economic thinking
prevalent immediately after the war had deemed international capital
flow undesirable and unnecessary. Trade was to be mediated through
fixed exchange rates pegged to a gold-backed dollar. The fixed exchange
rates were to be adjusted only gradually and periodically to reflect
the relative strength of the participating economies. Under principles
of Chartalism, foreign capital serves no useful domestic purpose
outside of an imperialistic agenda. Thus dollar hegemony essentially
taxes away the ability of the trading partners of the United States to
finance their own domestic development in their own currencies, and
forces them to seek foreign loans and investment denominated in
dollars, which the US, and only the US, can print at will.
The Mundell-Fleming thesis, for which economist Robert Mundell won the
1999 Nobel Prize, states that in international finance, a government
has the choice between (1) stable exchange rates, (2) capital mobility
and (3) policy autonomy (full employment/low interest rates,
counter-cyclical fiscal spending, etc). With unregulated global
markets, a government can have only two of those three options.
Through dollar hegemony, the United States is the only country that has
managed to defy the Mundell-Fleming thesis. For more than a decade, the
US has kept the dollar significantly above its real economic value,
attracted capital account surpluses and exercised unilateral policy
autonomy within a globalized system dictated by dollar hegemony. The
reasons for this are complex but the single most important reason is
that all major commodities, most notably oil, are denominated in
dollars, mostly as an extension of superpower geopolitics. This fact is
the anchor for dollar hegemony. Thus dollar hegemony makes possible US
finance hegemony, which makes possible US exceptionism and
unilateralism.
The Chinese economy is at a point where it also can defy the
Mundell-Fleming thesis and free itself from dollar hegemony.
China has the power to make the yuan an alternative reserve currency in
world trade by simply denominating all Chinese export in yuan. This
sovereign action can be taken unilaterally at any time of China's
choosing. All the State Council (the Chinese government's cabinet) has
to do is to announce that as of, say, October 1, 2002, all Chinese
exports must be paid for in yuan, making it illegal for Chinese
exporters to accept payment in any other currencies. This will set off
a frantic scramble by importers of Chinese goods around the world to
buy yuan at the State Administration for Foreign Exchange (SAFE),
making the yuan a preferred currency with ready market demand.
Companies with yuan revenue no longer need to exchange yuan into
dollars, as the yuan, backed by the value of Chinese exports, becomes
universally accepted in trade. Members of the Organization of Petroleum
Exporting Countries (OPEC), which import sizable amount of Chinese
goods, would accept yuan for payment for their oil.
In 2000, the United States exported US$781.1 billion (12.3 percent of
world exports - 11 percent year-to-year growth) and imported $1.2576
trillion (18.9 percent of world imports - 19 percent year-to-year
growth). Germany exported $551.5 billion (8.7 percent of world exports
- 1 percent year-to-year growth) and imported $502.8 billion (7.5
percent of world imports - 6 percent year-to-year growth). Japan
exported $479.2 billion (7.5 percent of world exports - 14 percent
year-to-year growth) and imported $379.5 billion (5.7 percent of world
imports - 22 percent year-to-year growth). France exported $298.1
billion (4.7 percent of world exports - 1 percent year-to-year decline)
and imported $305.4 billion (4.6 percent of world imports - 4 percent
year-to-year growth). The United Kingdom exported $337 billion (5.1
percent of world export - 5 percent year-to-year growth) and imported
$284.1 billion (4.5 percent of world imports - 6 percent year-to-year
growth).
China exported $249.3 (3.9 percent of world exports - 28 percent
year-to-year growth) and imported $225.1 billion (3.4 percent of world
imports - 36 percent year-to-year growth). Hong Kong exported $214.2
billion (3.2 percent of world exports- 19 percent year-to-year growth)
and imported $202.4 billion (3.2 percent of world imports - 16 percent
year-to-year growth).
China (including Hong Kong) exported more than $463 billion (7.3
percent of world exports) in 2000 and imported about $428 billion,
yielding a trade surplus of around $35 billion. If all Chinese exports
are paid in yuan, China will have no need to hold foreign reserves,
which currently stand at more than $200 billion. And if the Hong Kong
dollar is pegged to the yuan instead of the dollar, Hong Kong's $100
billion foreign-exchange reserves can also be freed for domestic
restructuring and development.
China's spectacular export growth has not reversed the shrinking of
world trade volume since 1997. Its growth has come at the expense of
the now wounded "tigers" of Southeast Asia. China is on the way to
becoming a world economic giant but it has yet to assert its rightful
financial power.
There is no stopping China from being a powerhouse in manufacturing.
With the Asian economies trapped in protracted financial crisis from
excessive foreign-currency debts and falling export revenue resulting
from predatory currency devaluation, the International Monetary Fund,
orchestrated by the US, has come to their "rescue" with a new agenda
beyond the usual IMF austerity conditionalities to protect Group of
Seven (G7) creditors. This new agenda aims to open Asian markets for US
transnational corporations to acquire distressed Asian companies so
that their newly acquired Asian subsidiaries can produce inside Asian
national borders. The United States, through the IMF, aims to break
down the traditionally closed financial systems all over Asia that
mobilize high national savings to serve giant national industrial
conglomerates, for massive investment in targeted export sectors. The
IMF, controlled by the US, aims at dismantling traditional Asian
financial systems and forcing Asians to replace them with a
structurally alien global system, characterized by open markets in
products and, crucially, in finance and financial services. The real
target is of course China. For the US knows: as China goes, so goes the
rest of Asia.
Trade flows under neoliberal globalization have put Asian countries in
a position of unsustainable dependency on foreign loans and capital to
finance export sectors that are at the mercy of saturated foreign
markets while neglecting domestic development to foster productive
forces and to support budding domestic consumer markets. In Asia,
outside the small circled of well-heeled compradores, most people
cannot afford the products that they produce in abundance for export or
the high-cost imports. An average worker in Asia would have to work
days making hundreds of pairs of shoes to earn enough to buy one
McDonald's hamburger meal for his family while Asian compradores
entertain their Western backers in luxurious five-star hotels with
prime steaks imported from Omaha. Markets outside of Asia cannot grow
quickly enough to satisfy the developmental needs of the populous Asian
economies. Thus intra-region trade to promote domestic development
within Asia needs to be the main focus of growth if Asia is ever to
rise above the level of semi-colonial subsistence.
The Chinese economy will move quickly up the trade-value chain, in
advanced electronics, telecommunications, and aerospace, which are
inherently "dual use" technologies with military implications.
Strategic phobia will push the United States to exert all its influence
to keep the global market for "dual use" technologies closed to China.
Thus "free trade" for the US is not the same as freedom to trade.
Still, China will inevitably be a major global player in the knowledge
industries because of its abundant supply of raw human potential. Even
in the US, a high percentage of its scientists are of Chinese
ethnicity. With an updated educational system, China will be the top
producer of brain power within another decade. As China moves up the
technology ladder, coupled with rising consumer demand in tandem with a
growth economy, global trade flow will be affected, modifying the "race
to the bottom" predatory competitive game of a decade of globalization
among Asian exporters.
Asian economies will find in China an alternative trading partner to
the United States, and possibly with more symbiotic trading terms,
providing more room to structure trade to enhance domestic development
along the path of converging regional interest and solidarity. The rise
in living standards in all of Asia will change the path of history,
restoring Asia as a center of advanced civilization, putting an end to
two centuries of Western economic and cultural imperialism.
The foreign-trade strategies of all trading nations in the decade of
neoliberal globalization have contributed to the destabilizing of the
global trading system. It is not possible or rational for all countries
to export themselves out of domestic recessions or poverty. The
contradictions between national strategic industrial policies and
neoliberal open-market systems will generate friction between the
United States and all its trading partners, as well as among regional
trade blocs and inter-region competitors. The US engages in global
trade to enhance its superpower status, not to undermine it. Thus the
US does not seek equal partners. With economic sanctions as a tool of
foreign policy, the US government is preventing, or trying to prevent,
an increasing number of US companies, and foreign companies trading
with the US, from doing business in an increasing number of countries.
Trade flows not where it is needed most, but to where it best serves
the US national interest.
Neoliberal globalization has promoted the illusion that trade is a
win-win transaction for all, based on the Ricardian model of
comparative advantage. Yet economists recognize that without global
full employment, comparative advantage is merely Say's Law
internationalized (Say's Law states that supply creates its own demand,
but only under full employment, a condition supply-siders conveniently
ignore). After a decade, this illusion has been shattered by concrete
data: 30 percent of the world's population live on less than $1 a day,
and global wages, already low to begin with, have declined since the
Asian financial crisis of 1997, and by 45 percent in Indonesia.
Yet export to the United States under dollar hegemony is merely an
arrangement in which the exporting nations, in order to earn dollars to
buy needed commodities denominated in dollars and to service dollar
loans, are forced to finance the consumption of US consumers by the
need to invest their trade surpluses in US assets (as foreign-exchange
reserves), giving the US a capital account surplus to finance its
current account deficit.
Furthermore, the trade surpluses are achieved not by an advantage in
the terms of trade, but by sheer self-denial of basic domestic needs
and critical imports. Not only are the exporting nations debasing the
value of their labor, degrading their environment and depleting their
natural resources for the privilege of running on the poverty
treadmill, they are enriching the US economy and strengthening dollar
hegemony in the process. Thus the exporting nations allow themselves to
be robbed of needed capital for critical domestic development in such
vital areas as education, health and other social infrastructure, by
assuming heavy foreign debt to finance export, while they beg for even
more foreign investment in the export sector by offering still more
exorbitant returns and tax exemptions. Yet many small economies around
the world have no option but to continue to serve dollar hegemony like
a drug addiction.
Japan provides the perfect proof that even a dynamic, successful export
machine does not by itself produce a healthy economy. Japan is aware
that it needs to restructure its domestic economy, away from its export
fixation and upgrade the living standard of its overworked population
and to reorder its domestic consumption patterns. But Japan is trapped
into helplessness by dollar hegemony.
Japan sees its sovereign credit rating lowered by international rating
agencies while it remains the world's biggest creditor nation. Moody's
Investor Service downgraded Japanese government bonds by two notches
recently to A2, or one grade below Botswana's, not to mention Chile and
Hungary. Japan has the world's largest foreign-exchange reserves: $446
billion; the world's biggest domestic savings: $11.4 trillion (US gross
domestic product was $10 trillion in 2001); and $1 trillion in overseas
investment. And 95 percent of the sovereign debt is held by Japanese
nationals, which rules out risk of default similar to Argentina. Japan
has given Botswana, where half of the population is infected with the
AIDS virus, $12 million in grants and $102 million in loans.
Why does the New York-based rating agency prefer Botswana to Japan? The
Botswanan government budget is controlled by the foreign diamond-mining
interests to protect their investment in the mines. Botswana does not
run a budget deficit to develop its domestic economy or help its
poverty-stricken people. Thus Botswana is considered a good credit risk
for foreign loans and investment. Japan, on the other hand, is forced
to suffer the high interest cost of a low credit rating because its
government attempts to solve, through deficit financing, the nation's
economic woes that have resulted from excessive focus on export. Dollar
hegemony denies a good credit rating even to the world's largest holder
of dollar reserves.
The Asia-Pacific trade system has been structured to serve markets
outside of Asia by providing low manufacturing production cost through
the use of cheap Asian labor. This enables the United States to consume
more without inflation and without raising domestic wages. Yet all the
trade surpluses accumulated by the Asian economies have ended up
financing the US debt bubble, which is not even good for the US economy
in the long run. Cheap imports allow the US to keep domestic wages low
and contribute to a rising disparity of both income and wealth within
the US where consumer purchasing power comes increasingly from capital
gain rather than rising wages. The result is that when the equity
bubble of inflated price-earning ratio finally bursts, wages are too
low to keep the economy from crashing from a collapse of the wealth
effect.
After thoroughly impoverishing the Asian economies with financial
manipulation of crisis proportions, the US now works to penetrate the
remaining Asian markets that have stayed relatively closed: notably
Japan, China and South Korea. Control of access to its markets has been
Asia's principal instrument for its sub-optimized trade advantage and
distorted industrial development. This strategy had been practiced
successfully first by Japan and copied with various degree of success
by the Asian tigers. Protectionism will survive in Asian economies long
after formal accession to the World Trade Organization (WTO).
China, with a giant integrated market composed of a fifth of the world
population, can swap market access for technology transfer from the
world's transnational technology corporations. Once free from dollar
hegemony, China can finance its domestic development without foreign
loans and capital. The Chinese economy then will no longer be distorted
by excessive reliance on export merely to earn dollars that by
definition must be invested in dollar assets, not yuan assets. The aim
of development is to raise wage levels, not to push wages down to
achieve predatory competitiveness. Yet export under dollar hegemony
requires keeping wages low, a prerequisite that condemns an economy to
perpetual underdevelopment.
Terms such as "openness" need to be reconsidered away from the
distorted meanings assigned to them by neoliberal cultural hegemony.
The contradiction between globalizing and territorially based national
social and political forces is framed in the context of past, present
and future world orders.
The emerging world order has always been, and will again be, the result
of a struggle for the direction of structural transformation of the
current order, involving economic, political and sociocultural changes.
The prevailing trend of the past two decades toward the marketization
and commodification of social relations has led to the argument that
socialism needs to be redefined away from the total visions associated
with Marxism-Leninism, and toward the idea of the self-defense of
society and social choice to counter the disintegrating and atomizing
effects of globalizing and unregulated market forces. But this is
precisely a Marxist-Leninist vision: that under globalization, national
sovereignty in the form of nation-states and governments will give way
to a pervasive socioeconomic order. In other words - the withering away
of the state.
The sole function of government is to protect the weak, because the
strong is itself government and needs no other. This truth gave birth
to monarchism: the king's function was to protect the peasants from
aristocratic abuse. So in modern terms, the government's function is to
maintain socialist/populists values in the context of capitalist market
fundamentalism. So the withering away of the state prior to the end of
economic exploitation is putting the cart before the horse.
The unwitting by-product of the rightist quest to get government off
the back of the people is a Marxist dialectic. The only flaw is the
economic structure. The right wants the withering away of the state
prior to the progressive transformation of capitalism into socialism.
The perpetual boom has not replaced the business cycle, new economy or
not. In the age of information and communication, the majority interest
will prevail - with luck, without violence. Despite US fixations,
majority interest does not necessarily spell capitalism, corporatism or
representative democracy. Socialism collapsed in the 1980s not because
its economic theories were inoperative, but because in defending the
authority to make socialist principles work, socialist governments had
to adopt a garrison-state mentality that overshadowed all other
potential benefits. On the other hand, capitalist market fundamentalism
appeared more desirable as long as this mutation of socialism was posed
as a false alternative. Now, as the sole surviving operative system,
capitalist market fundamentalism is faced squarely with its own
internal contradictions. Unregulated markets have produced the debt
bubble and financial manipulation and corporate fraud that impoverish
unsuspecting investors and workers who placed their pensions in the
shares of the companies that employed them. And the war on terrorism
runs the risk of instilling in the United States the same
garrison-state mentality that brought about the demise of the Soviet
bloc.
Finance capitalism may turn out to be the deadliest enemy of industrial
capitalism, and it may well be the last transformation of capitalism.
There are clear indications that insufficient demand is caused by the
abandonment of the labor theory of value and the wholesale acceptance
by neoliberalism of the theory of marginal utility. Lack of demand
caused by insufficient wages is more deadly to finance capitalism than
the fear of socialism. Technology has finally turned Charlie Chaplin's Modern
Times into reality. The rhetoric of the current political debate in
the United States on corporate fraud is more populist than those of the
New Deal, and the recession has yet to begin in earnest. Socialism, by
other names (the Wall Street Journal calls it mass capitalism), is now
about to be viewed as the vaccine against a catastrophic implosion of
the capitalist system in its home garden.
Globalization is not a new trend. It is the natural policy for all
empire building. Globalization under modern capitalism began with the
British Empire, marked by the repeal of the Corn Laws in 1846, five
years after the Opium War with China (I have written
on the historical parallel between the Corn Laws and WTO), and two
years before the Revolutions of 1848. Great Britain embarked on a
systemic promotion of free trade and chose to depend on imported food,
which gave a survivalist justification to empire. France adopted free
trade in 1860 and within 10 years was faced with the Paris Commune,
which was suppressed ruthlessly by the French bourgeoisie, who put to
death 20,000 workers and peasants, including children. Despite a
backlash movement toward protective tariffs in Britain, Holland and
Belgium, the global economy of the 19th century was characterized by
high mobility of goods across political borders. As Europe adopted
political nationalism, international economic liberalism developed in
parallel, until 1914. Only World War I, the 1929 Depression and World
War II caused a temporary halt of free trade.
Like the United States now, Britain was a predominantly importing
economy by the close of the 18th century. Despite the Industrial
Revolution's expanded export of manufacturing goods, import of raw
material, food and consumer amenities grew faster than export of
manufacturing goods and coal. The key factor that sustained this
imbalance was the predominance of the British pound, as it is today
with the US dollar and its impact of the trade deficit. British
hegemony of marine transportation and financial services
(cross-currency trade finance and insurance) earned Britain vast
amounts of foreign currencies that could be sold in the London money
markets to importers of Argentine meat and Canadian bacon.
International credit and capital markets were centered in London. The
export of financial services and capital produced the the returns which
serves as hidden surplus to cushioned the trade deficit. To enhance
financial hegemony, the British maintain separate dependent currencies
in all parts of the empire under pound-sterling hegemony. This
financial hegemony is now centered on New York with the dollar as the
base currency. When the Asian tigers export to the United States, all
they get in return are US Treasury bills, not direct investment in
Asia. Asian labor in fact is working at low wages mainly to finance the
expansion of the US economy.
Market fundamentalism, a modern euphemism of capitalism, is thus made
necessary by the finance architecture imposed on the world by the
hegemonic finance power, first 19th-century Great Britain, now the
United States. When the developing economies call for a new
international finance architecture, this is what they are really
driving at. Foreign-exchange markets ensure the endless demand for
dollar capital import by the poor exporting nations. John A Hobson and
Lenin identified the surplus of capital in the core economies and the
need for its export to the impoverished parts of the world as the
material basis of imperialism. For neo-imperialism of the 21st century,
this remains fundamentally true.
Then and now, the international economy rests on an international money
system. Britain adopted the gold standard in 1816, with Western Europe
and the US following in the 1870s. Until 1914, the exchange rates of
most currencies were highly stable, except in victimized, semi-colonial
economies such as Turkey and China. The gold standard, while greatly
facilitating free trade, was hard on economies that produced no gold,
and the gold-based monetary regime was generally deflationary (until
the discovery of new gold deposits in South Africa, California and
Alaska), which favored capital. William Jenning Bryan spoke for the
world in 1896 when he declared that mankind should not be "crucified
upon this cross of gold". But the 50-year lead time of the British gold
standard firmly established London as the world's financial center. The
world's capital was drawn to London to be redistributed to investment
of the highest return around the world. Borrowers around the world were
reduced to playing a game of "race to the bottom".
The bulk of economic theories within the context of capitalism were
invented to rationalize this global system as natural truth. The
fundamental shift from the labor value theory to the marginal utility
theory was a circular self-validation of the artificial characteristics
of an artificial construct based on the sanctity of capital, despite
Karl Marx's dissection that capital cannot exit without labor - until
assets are put to use to increase labor productivity, it remains idle
assets.
Mergers and acquisitions became rampant. Small business capitalism
disappeared between 1880 and 1890. Workers and small businesses found
that they were not competing against their neighbors, but those on
other sides of the world, operating from structurally different
socioeconomic systems. The corporation, first used to facilitate the
private ownership of railroads, became the organization of choice for
large industries and commerce, issuing stocks and bonds to finance its
undertakings that fell beyond the normal financial resources of
individual entrepreneurs.
This process increased the power of banks and financial institutions
and brought forth finance capitalism. Cartels and trusts emerged, using
vertical and horizontal integration to eliminate competition and
manipulate markets and prices for entire sectors of the economy.
Middle-class membership was mainly concentrated in salaried workers of
corporations, while the working class were hourly wage earners in
factories. The 1848 Revolutions were the the first proletariat
revolutions in modern time. The creation of an integrated world market,
the financing and development of economies outside of Europe and the
consequence of rising standards of living for Europeans were the
triumphs of the 19th-century system of unregulated capitalism. In the
20th century, the process continued, with the center shifting to the
United States.
Friedrich List, in his National System of Political Economy
(1841), asserted that political economy as espoused in England at that
time, far from being a valid science universally, was merely British
national opinion, suited only to English historical conditions. List's
institutional school of economics asserted that the doctrine of free
trade was devised to keep England rich and powerful at the expense of
its trading partners and that it had to be fought with protective
tariffs and other protective devices of economic nationalism by the
weaker countries. List influenced revolutionaries in Asia, including
Sun Yatsen, who until coming under the influence of Marx and Lenin
after the October Revolution was primarily relying on List in
formulating his policy of economic nationalism for China. List was also
the influence behind the Meiji Reform Movement in Japan.
The current impending collapse of neoliberal globalized market
fundamentalism offers Asia a timely opportunity to forge a fairer deal
in its economic relation with the West. The United States, as a
bicoastal nation, must begin to treat Asian-Pacific nations as equal
members of an Asian-Pacific commonwealth in a new world economic order
that makes economic nationalism unnecessary.
China, as the largest economy in the Asia-Pacific region, has a key
role to play in shaping this new world order. To do that, China must
look beyond its current myopic effort to join a collapsing global
market economy and provide a model of national domestic development in
which foreign trade is reassigned to its proper place in the economy
from its current all-consuming priority. The first step in that
direction is for China to free itself from dollar hegemony.
|