|
Shifting
China’s
Export towards the Domestic Market
By
Henry C. K. Liu
Part I: Breaking Free
from Dollar Hegemony
Part II: Developing China with Sovereign Credit
Part III:
History of Monetary Imperialism
This article appeared in AToL
on September 26, 2008
Over the course of the 19th century, enough gold
was known to have been accumulated by Britain
to make it credible for the British Treasury to introduce paper
currency backed
by its gold to force the demonetization of silver in Europe
to advance British monetary imperialism. Many historians inaccurately
ascribe
to 19th century mercantilism as the policy of accumulating
gold for
a country through export of merchandise. The fact is that gold
accumulation can
only be achieved by a purposeful policy of monetary imperialism.
Mercantilism
under bimetallism gave a trade surplus country both silver and gold.
Only
monetary imperialism could cause an inflow of gold with an outflow of
silver.
Demonetization of
Silver turned Gold into a Fiat Currency
In reality, Britain
earned gold in the 19th century not from export of
merchandise
because buyers of British goods had a choice of paying in silver or
gold under
bimetallism. In reality, Britain
accumulated gold by overvaluing gold monetarily all through the 19th
century. This allowed Britain to force
the world to demonetized silver and to replace bimetallism with the
gold
standard after enough of the world’s gold had flowed into Britain to
enable the
pound sterling, a paper currency back by gold, but essentially a fiat
current
without bimetallism, to act as a reserve currency for world trade with
which to
finance Britain’s role of sole superpower after the fall of Napoleon.
With the pound sterling as reserve currency, British banks,
operating on a fractional reserve system backed by the Bank of England,
the
central bank, as lender of last resort, could practice predatory
lending all
over the world, sucking up wealth with boom and bust business cycles
instigated
by her predatory monetary policy of fiat paper currency. The strategy
worked
for more than a century until the end of World War I. Between 1800 and
1914,
the main British export was financial capital denominated in fiat pound
sterling disguised by the gold standard to be as good as gold. The
factor
income from banking profits derived from pound sterling hegemony paid
for the
wealth and luxury that Britain
enjoyed as the world’s preeminent power in the century between the fall
of
Napoleon in 1815 and the start of First World War in 1914, for a whole
century.
The demonetization of silver stealthily turned the gold
standard into a fiat paper money regime through the officially
gold-backed
pound sterling because the gold backing it was no longer priced in
silver at a
fixed rate, or any other metal of intrinsic value for that matter. Gold
and
only gold became a fiat unit of account set by the British Mint, a fact
that
made Britain monetary
hegemon of the age.
An asset that is priced by or in itself has no transactional
meaning, even if it is gold. This is because a transaction must involve
at
least two assets of different value, expressed with different prices in
exchangeable currencies. And there must be an agreed upon exchange
ratio at the
time of the transaction to effectuate a transactional outcome. Even in
barter,
an exchange ratio between the two assets to be exchanged needs to be
agreed
upon. For example, an ounce of gold can be exchanged for 15 ounces of
silver.
An ounce of gold that can be exchanged for another ounce of gold
carries no
information of transactional value.
Thus the pound sterling, even when backed by gold, was in
fact a fiat paper currency because the monetary value of gold is set by
fiat
devoid of any relationship to any other thing of intrinsic value beside
gold
itself. Without bimetallism, specie money cannot have any meaning of
transactional worth. Currency backed by gold turns into a fiat currency
if it
can be redeemed at its face value only in gold. The monetary value of
gold is
not separate from the commercial value of gold. Gold then can fluctuate
in
purchasing power due to any number of factors, including government
policy, but
is not fixed to any other metal of intrinsic value at an universally
agreed
upon ratio.
That a pound sterling is worth another pound sterling is no
different than an ounce of gold is worth another ounce of gold. And the
market
price of gold can be manipulated by the government who is in possession
of more
gold than any other market participant. This means that any unwelcome
speculator can be quickly ruined by the government. This is of course
how
central banks nowadays intervene in the foreign exchange market for
fiat
currencies. Central banks with sufficient dollar reserves, a fiat
currency, can
drive speculators against their national currencies toward bankruptcy.
Before silver was demonetized, the silver/gold ratio was set
monetarily at 15.5/1 in England
and 15/1 in France,
motivating speculators to buy silver with gold in England
and buy gold with silver in France
for an arbitrage profit of half an ounce of silver for each ounce of
gold so
transacted in the two countries. This caused a continuous flow of gold
to England independent
of international trade flows in other commodities. Even when Britain
incurred a trade deficit, gold continues to flow into Britain because
of the monetary hegemony of the pound sterling.
After silver was demonetized, gold could be exchanged at the
British Treasury only for pound sterling notes at the rate of 21
shillings or
£1-1s per ounce of gold fixed in 1717. The commercial price of
gold in England
was set by the British Treasury on par with its monetary value because
gold
price was denominated in pound sterling. The commercial price of silver
or any
other commodity in England
was also denominated in pound sterling which had a monetary value in
gold set
by the British Treasury by fiat.
After the demonetization of silver, no one
knew how much silver was worth as money
because it was no longer used as money anywhere. Thus there could not
be any
discrepancy between the commercial price of silver and its monetary
value
because silver ceased to have a monetary value. Silver then became a
commercial
commodity like any other commercial commodity, while only gold remained
a
monetary unit of account accepted in the British Treasury and in other
treasuries of countries which observed the gold standard. Countries
that
refused to join the gold standard saw their currency kept out of
international trade and had to pay a penalty of higher interest rates
on
loans
denominated in their non-gold-backed currency.
Further, the Bank of England could issue more pound sterling
notes by fiat based on the fractional reserve principle in banking. She
only
needs to keep enough gold to prevent a run on pound sterling notes for
gold at
the Bank of England. And since England
was in possession of more gold than any other country at the time, Britain
under the gold standard became the monetary hegemon, with more money at
her
disposal than justified by the amount of gold she actually held. Other gold standard country had to maintain a
much higher fractional reserve in gold than Britain
and therefore had less money with which to participate in international
capital
markets. The monetary hegemon could sustain a trade deficit with an
inflow of
gold cause by monetary policy.
Without a fixed exchange rate regime, each nation could
adopt a gold standard unrelated to other nations’ gold standard. For
example,
the US at $20.67 dollars per ounce of gold and Britain at £3-17s-10.5d per ounce of gold would
let the exchange rate between the
dollar and the pound sterling work itself out mathematically. This is
what a
fiat currency regime does, except instead of being valued by a gold
standard
based on the amount of gold held by the issuing government, the
exchange rate
of the currency is valued by each country’s monetary policy
implications and
financial conditions, such as interest rates, balance of payments,
domestic
inflation rate, fiscal budgets, trade deficits, etc.
The United States,
though formally on a bimetallic (gold and silver) standard, switched to
gold de facto in 1834 and de jure in
1900. In 1834, the United States
fixed the price of gold at $20.67 per
ounce, where it remained for a century until 1933, when President
Roosevelt
devalued the dollar to $35 per ounce of gold, but made it illegal for
US
citizens to own gold in amount more than $100. Before World War I,
Britain had fixed
the per ounce price of gold at £3-17s-10.5d, three times the original price of
gold set in 1717 which was at one Guinea or 21 shillings. The exchange
rate between
dollars and pounds sterling, the “par exchange rate”, mathematically
came to
$4.867 per pound during the period between 1834 and 1914. Between 1914
and
1933, the dollar/pound exchange rate mathematically rose to $2.214 per
pound
sterling.
On August 25, 2008,
a relatively uneventful trading day, the per-ounce market price for
silver was
$13.45 and that of gold was $829, yielding a silver/gold ratio of
61.6/1. This
was 4 times the historical British Mint ratio of 15.5/1. On that same
day, the
exchange rate between the dollar and the pound sterling, both free
floating
fiat currencies, was $1.853 per pound sterling, determined by monetary
policies
of their respective central banks. The exchange rate between the dollar
and the
pound sterling on that day was less than one third of the “par exchange
rate”
from 1834 through 1914. The British pound had lost more than a third of
its
exchange value against the dollar in 94 years while the dollar itself
had also
fallen against gold by 4,000%, from $20.67 to $829. The dollar had not
become
stronger, only the pound had become weaker against the dollar. This is
because
the pound, like all other fiat currencies in the world, has become a
derivative
currency of the dollar.
John Locke (1632-1704) and David Hume (1711-76) provided
considerable refinement, elaboration and extension to the Quantity
Theory of
Money (QTM), allowing it to be integrated into the mainstream of
orthodox
monetarist tradition. Locke developed the right of private property
based on
the labor theory of value and the mechanics of political checks and
balances
that were incorporated in the US Constitution. Locke, in 1661, asserted
the
proportionality postulate: that a doubling of the quantity of money (M)
would double
the level of prices (P) and half the value of the monetary unit.
Hume, in 1752, introduced the notion of causation by stating that
variation in
M (money quantity) will cause proportionate changes in P (price level).
Concurrently with Irish banker Richard Cantillon (1680-1734), Hume
applied to
the QTM two crucial distinctions: 1) between static (long-run
stationary
equilibrium) and dynamic (short-run movement toward equilibrium); and
2)
between the long-run neutrality and the short-run non-neutrality of
money. Hume
and Cantillon provided the first dynamic process analysis of how the
impact of
a monetary change spread from one sector of the economy to another,
altering
relative price and quantity in the process.
They pointed out that most monetary injection would involve
non-neutral distribution effects. New money would not be distributed
among
individuals in proportion to their pre-existing share of money
holdings. Those
who receive more will benefit at the expense of those receiving less
than their
proportionate share, and they will exert more influence in determining
the
composition of new output. Initial distribution effects temporarily
alter the pattern
of expenditure and thus the structure of production and the allocation
of
resources. This is how inflation causes income disparity.
Thus it is understandable that conservatives would be
sympathetic to the QTM to maintain the wealth distribution status quo,
or if
the QTM is skirted, to ensure that the mal-distribution tilts toward
those who
are more likely to engage in capital formation, namely the rich. This
is
precisely what happened in the past two decades and caused sharp rises
in
income disparity. Thus developing economies in need of capital
formation would
find logic in first enriching the financial elite while advanced
economies with
production overcapacity would need to increase aggregate demand by
restricting
income disparity, which free market fundamentalism has failed to do.
This is
the problem of central banking in market capitalism: it delivers money
to those
who need it least. This excess money is called capital.
Hume describes how different degrees of money illusion among income
recipients,
coupled with time natural and artificial delays in the adjustment
process,
could cause costs to lag behind prices, thus creating abnormal profits
and
stimulating optimistic profit expectations that would spur business
overexpansion
and employment during the transition period. These non-neutral effects
are not
denied by the adherents of QTM, who nevertheless assert that they are
bound to
dissipate in the long run, albeit often with great damage if the
optimism was
unjustified. The latest evidence of the non-neutral effects of money is
observable in expansion of the so-called New Economy from easy money in
the
past decades and the recurring collapse of its serial bubbles.
The QTM formed the central core of 19th-century classical monetary
analysis,
provided the dominant conceptual framework for interpreting
contemporary
financial events and formed the intellectual foundation of orthodox
policy
prescription designed to preserve the gold standard. The economic
structure in
19th-century Europe led analysts to acknowledge additional non-neutral
effects,
such as the lag of money wages behind the rise of prices, which
temporarily
reduces real wages; the stimulus to output occasioned by
inflation-induced
reduction in real debt burdens, which shifts real income from
productive debtor-entrepreneurs
to unproductive creditor-rentiers; the so-called “forced saving” effect
occasioned by price-induced redistribution of income among
socio-economic
classes having structurally different propensity to save and invest;
and the
stimulus to investment imparted by a temporary reduction in the rate of
interest below the anticipated rate of return on new capital.
Yet classical quantity theorists tended persistently to minimize the
importance
of non-neutral effects as merely transitional. Whereas Hume tended to
stress
lengthy dynamic disequilibrium periods in which money matters much,
classical
analysts focused on long-run equilibrium in which money is merely a
veil. Ricardo,
the most influential of the classical economists, thought such
disequilibrium
effects ephemeral and unimportant in long-run equilibrium analysis.
Gods, of
course, enjoy longer perspectives than most mortals, as do the rich
over the
poor. As John Maynard Keynes famously said: “In the long run, we will
all be
dead.”
As leader of the Bullionists who advocated immediate and
full-par resumption of convertibility of notes in gold, Ricardo charged that inflation in Britain
was solely the result of the Bank of England’s irresponsible over-issue
of
money, when in 1797, under financial stress from the Napoleonic Wars, Britain
left the gold standard for inconvertible paper. At that time, the Bank
of
England was still operating as a national bank, not a central bank in
the
modern sense of the term. In other words, it operated to improve the
English
economy rather than to strengthen the sanctity of international finance
by
protecting the value of money against inflation. Ricardo, by focusing
on long-term
equilibrium, discouraged discussions on the possible beneficial output
and
employment effects of monetary injection on the national level. Like
modern-day
monetarists, Bullionists laid the source of inflation, considered a
decidedly
evil force in international finance, squarely at the door of the
national bank.
Milton Friedman declared some two centuries after Richardo: “inflation
is everywhere a monetary phenomenon.” Friedman’s concept of “money
matters” is
the diametrical opposite of Hume’s view of money that most monetary
injection
would involve non-neutral distribution effects. This has been the
result of
Greenspan’s abusive use of liquidity to moderate the business cycle by
creating
price bubbles.
The historical evolution in 18th-century Europe
from a
predominantly full-metal money to a mixed metal-paper money forced
advances in
the understanding of the monetary transmission mechanism. After gold
coins had
given way to banknotes, Hume’s direct mechanism of price adjustment was
found
lacking in explaining how banknotes are injected into the system.
Henry Thornton (1760-1815), in his classic The Paper Credit of
Great Britain
(1802), provided the first description of the indirect mechanism by
observing
that new money created by banks enters financial markets initially via
an
expansion of bank loans, by increasing the supply of lend-able funds,
temporarily reducing the interest rate below the rate of return on new
capital,
thus stimulating additional investment and loan demand. This in turn
pushes
prices up, including capital good prices, drives up loan demands and
eventually
interest rates, bringing the system back into equilibrium indirectly.
The central issue of the doctrines of the British classical school that
dominated the first half of the 19th century was focused around the
application
of the QTM to government policy, which manifested itself in the
maintenance of
external equilibrium and the restoration and defense of the gold
standard.
Consequently, the QTM tended to be directed toward the analysis of
international price levels, gold flow, exchange-rate fluctuations and
trade balance.
It formed the foundation of mercantilism, which underpinned the
economic
structure of the British Empire via
colonialism, which
reached institutional maturity in the same period. But
it was the British who discovered that
gold flow was guided by Gresham’s
Law of bad money driving out good, and caused gold to flow into Britain
by purposefully overvaluing its monetary ratio to silver.
Bullionists developed the idea that the stock of money, or its currency
component, could be effectively regulated by controlling a narrowly
defined
monetary base, that the control of “high-power money” (bank reserves)
in a
fractional reserve banking regime implies virtual control of the money
supply.
High-power money is the totality of bank reserves that would be
multiplied many
times through the money-creation power of commercial bank lending,
depending on
the velocity of circulation. Under the gold standard, bank reserve can
take of
form of gold or bank notes.
In the three decades after Britain
returned to the gold standard in 1821, the policy objective focused on
the
maintenance of fixed exchange rates and the automatic gold
convertibility of
the pound. But the Currency School (CS) versus Banking School (BS)
controversy
broke out over whether the “Currency Principle” of making existing
mixed
gold-paper currency expands and contracts in direct proportion to gold
reserves
was sufficient to safeguard against note over-issuance, or whether
additional
regulation was necessary. This controversy grew out of the expansionist
pressure put on the supply of pound sterling by the rapid expansion of
the British Empire. Or rather, the increase in
the supply of pound sterling
allowed Britain
to finance the considerable expenses of creating and maintaining a
global
empire.
Members of the CS argued that even a fully, legally convertible
currency could
be issued in excess with undesirable consequences, such as rising
domestic
prices relative to foreign prices, balance-of-payments deficits,
falling
foreign-exchange rates, gold outflow resulting in depletion of gold
reserves
and ultimately forced suspension of convertibility. The rate of
reserves drain
often accelerated when the external gold drain coincided with internal
domestic
panic conversion of paper into gold in fear of pending depreciation.
Thus the
CS promoted full convertibility plus strict regulation of the volume of
banknotes to prevent the recurrence of gold drains, exchange
depreciation and
domestic liquidity crises.
The apprehension of the CS was fully justified by past actions of the
Bank of
England, which had been perverse and destabilizing by international
finance
standards. The destabilizing argument stressed the time lag on the
Bank's
policy response to gold outflow and to exchange-rate movements. The
inevitably
too little, too late measures taken by the national bank, instead of
protecting
gold reserves, merely exacerbated financial panics and liquidity crises
that
inevitably followed periods of currency-credit excess. The famous Bank
Charter
Act of 1844, in modern parlance, imposed a 100% reserve requirement,
with an
unabashed bias toward wealth preservation over wealth creation. The CS
also
asserts that money substitutes cannot impair the effectiveness of
monetary
regulation. Thus if banknotes could be controlled, there would be no
need to
control deposits explicitly, on the ground that money substitutes have
low
velocity and are of declining substitutional value in times of crisis.
By the end of the 19th century, bimetallism had
become a political issue in the US.
Newly discovered silver mines in the West caused an effective decrease
in the
value of money. In 1873, the US Congress passed the Fourth Coinage Act
that
demonetized silver, shrinking the money supply and caused severe
deflation,
which Silverites called “The Crime of ’73” as deflation caused farmers
to
default on their fixed rate mortgages while prices of farm produce
fell. The
similarity between the crime of 1873 and that of 2007 when the subprime
mortgage crises broke out is striking in many respects.
French Monetary
Regime
The French livre
was established by Charlemagne (747-841) as a unit of account equal to
one
pound of silver. From the crusades, Louis IX brought back to France
the idea of a
royal
monopoly on the minting of coinage.
He minted the first gold écu d’or and
silver gros d’argent, whose weights
(and thus monetary divisions) were roughly equivalent to the livre tournois, a standard used in Tours,
one of the richest town in France
at the time. Argent still means both
silver and money in modern French. Between 1360 and 1641, coins worth
one livre tournois were minted and known as francs. The first French paper money was
issued by Louis XIV in 1701 and was denominated in livres
tournois.
France,
then with the largest economy in Europe, had
been the
powerhouse anchor of silver/gold bimetallism since the time of Louis
XIV
(1643-1715). The silver/gold ratio of 15:1 was maintained because France
always stood ready to exchange gold into silver and back at that ratio.
Monetarily, French money was neutral, never good or bad in the Gresham
Law
sense because the French state kept the commercial price of silver to
gold also
at the fixed monetary ratio of 15:1.
The French franc was the national currency of France
from 1360 until 1641 and again from 1795 until 1999 (franc coins and
notes were
legal tender until 2002). The franc was also minted for many of the
former
French colonies, such as Morocco,
Algeria,
French West Africa, and
others. Today, after independence, many of these
countries continue to use the franc as their standard denomination.
The National Constituent Assembly during the French
Revolution issued a paper currency in 1790 known as Assignats,
based on the value of confiscated Church properties. Assignats were used
successfully toretire a significant portion of the public debt as they
were accepted as legal tenderby domestic and international creditors.
Lack of control over the amount to be printed soon pushed the face
value of the assignats to
exceed the market value of confiscated Church
properties, causing hyperinflation by 1792. Napoleon I reintroduced the
franc
to replace assignats in 1803 to the
new currency, by which time assignats
had become worthless. On December
31, 1998, transitioning to the European Monetary Union, the
value of
the French franc was locked to the euro at 1 euro to 6.55957 FRF.
Napoleon I in reviving the franc made the mistake of allowing Britain
to
continue to overvalue gold against silver monetarily. This mistake in
monetary
policy eventually cost France
her financial preeminence despite Napoleon’s Continental System,
declared on November 21, 1806
by the Berlin
Decrees, to blockade British trade with the continent so as to deny Britain
the ability to fund the wars waged against France
by British allies on the continent. French effort to enforce the
Continental
System was a key reason for the Peninsular War which drove Spain
into alliance with Britain
despite French liberation of Spain
from the unpopular reign of Charles IV. It
was also a key factor behind Napoleon’s
disastrous invasion of Russia.
British financial prowess played a significant role in her ability to
form the
Sixth Coalition with Austria,
Russia,
Sweden
and the Germanic states to defeat Napoleon I in the Battle of Nations
at Leipzig
in 1814 and again to support Austria
to defeat Napoleon III in the Franco-Prussian War in 1870. British
monetary
hegemony could have been prevented by France
if only Napoleon had matched the monetary silver-gold ratio of 15.5 to
1 to stop the flow of gold into Britain.
The Spanish Monetary
Regime
The Spanish dollar, know popularly as Pieces of Eight, was a
silver coin minted for use in the Spanish Empire after a Spanish
currency
reform in 1497. The coin was legal tender in the US
until Congress discontinued the practice in 1857. It was the first
world
currency accepted in Europe, the Americas
and Asia in the late 18th century.
Many
currencies in use today, such as the US
and Canadian dollars, and most Latin American currencies, the Chinese
yuan, the
Japanes yen and the Phillipine peso, were initially based on the
Spanish dollar
and 8 reales coins. Spain’s
adoption of the peseta and her joining the Latin Monetary Union meant
the
effective end for the last vestiges of the Spanish dollar in Spain
itself.
The Austrian Monetary
Regime
Following Spain,
Austria
introduced the Guldengroschen in 1486, a large silver specie coin with
high
purity. The Austrian coin eventually spread throughout the rest of Europe.
Wilhelm von Schröder (1640-1688) advocated a monetary
strategy to stimulate the Austrian economy in his 1886 book “Fürstliche
Schatz- und Rentkammer, nebst
einem notwendigen Unterrichte zum Goldmachen” (The Royal Treasury
and How
to Make Money), calling for the introduction of paper banknotes to
provide the
sovereign with “an unlimited and perpetual source of gold and
finance.”
It
is one of the three major works of Germanic cameralism, in the company
of Politische
Discurs of 1668 by Johan Joachim Becher (1635-1682) and Hoernigk’s Oesterreich
über alles of 1684. Cameralism is
a
Germanic version of mercantilism particularly concerned with the
political and
economic phenomena of the territorial states. Its aim was an efficient
and just
administration, via a fiscal policy and similar financial measures
designed to
fill the state’s treasury, marked by an active and paternalizing
interference
in society. Like the other mercantilist writers, the cameralists have
been
accused of the error of confusing money and wealth. Money is not
wealth, only a
measuring devise of wealth. One can have a lot of money and be poor, a
state
known as hyperinflation. Schroder held that “it is not the import and
export of
money, but the equilibrium of the different trades which causes the
wealth or
poverty of a country.” He was wrong
which explained why Austria
was left behind by a rising Britain.
In fact, Schroder was among the first of the German
mercantilists who distinctly supported the balance-of-trade theory. He
supported free trade which he regarded as “the principal and the best
means
whereby a country may become rich.” Keynes praised Schroder for his
arguments
against other mercantilists who advocated the accumulation of state
treasury as
a means for the enhancing of the power of the state. Schroder however
“employed
the usual mercantilist arguments in drawing a lurid picture of how the
circulation in the country would be robbed of all its money through a
greatly
increasing state treasury” (Keynes General theory, p.344). Schroder was
influenced by the view of Thomas Hobbes (1588–1679) on social contract
and
civil society, the theories of William Petty (1623-1687) on fiscal
contributions, national wealth, money supply, circulation and velocity,
value,
interest rate, international trade, government investment and above
all, the
importance of full employment. He was slso influenced by the scientific
views
of British chemist Robert Boyle (1627-1691) as well as the views of
Thomas Mun
(1571-1642) on the merits of mercantilist colonialism in empire
building.
Unfortunately, Austria
did not implement the proposal of Schröder. She resorted instead
to the
conventional path of raising taxes and to borrowing. During the regency
of
Charles VI’s (1711-1740), Austria
borrowed from her allies and sold sovereign debts to anyone who would
buy
them. The mercantilist reforms towards statist activism in
economic
policies in the first half of the 18th century required the
standardization of currency against increasing defacement of coinage.
Empress
Maria Theresa (1740-1780) introduced a new bi-metal coinage standard
which all
German lands joined except Prussia.
The Austrian coinage standard was extended to become Convention
Standard, and
remained in effect for more than a century to facilitate international
payments
until 1858. The Austrian standard, by fixing the monetary ration
of silver
/gold at 15 to 1, contributed to the flow of gold to Britain
where the ratio was 15.5 to 1.
The pretext for the War
of the Austrian Succession (1740-1748) was the
eligibility of
Maria Teresa of Austria
to succeed to the Habsburg throne, as Salic law precluded royal
inheritance by
a woman. Continuous war costs presented Austria
with a persistent financial problem. Foreign credit bridged budget
deficits
temporarily but interest costs exacerbated the state’s unsustainable
financial
deterioration. During the regency of Charles VI, the national debt
ballooned by
two-thirds to a total of over 54 million Austrian gulden.
The high premium on silver in the wake of the gold rushes in California
and Australia
triggered heavy outflows of European silver coins to the Americas
and to East Asia, particularly China
while gold flowed into Britain.
For many European countries, the switch to a gold standard appeared
attractive
because it provided borrowers of gold-back currency loans with lower
interest
rates..
To finance war debts, Maria Theresa in 1762 issued paper money for the
first
time in Austrian history while keeping the coinage standard. Wiener-Stadt-Banco, a bank that had
handled the national debt, was selected as the issuer of paper notes.
State
revenue was reserved as backing for 12 million gulden worth of
non-interest-bearing bank notes, known as Banco-Zettel,
declared as legal tender for any type of payment. Banco-Zettel
worth 200 gulden or more were also exchangeable
for
imperial bonds at 5% interest.
However, the banknotes were not tied to
the
coinage standard. The notes had a slight premium over coins at the
beginning,
but in later years, the notes fell in value relative to the coins until
their
value was fixed in 1811 at one fifth of their face value in coins. That
year,
the Priviligirte Vereinigte Einlösungs und Tilgungs Deputation
("Privileged United Redemption and Repayment Deputation") began
issuing paper money valued at par with the coinage, followed by the
“Austrian
National Note Bank” in 1816 and the “Privileged Austrian National Bank”
between
1825 and 1863.
In essence, Austria moved away from specie money to adopt a
regime of sovereign credit with a fiat currency based on the State
Theory of
Money, or Chartalism, later spelled out by Georg Friedrich
Knapp (1842-1926) in his 1918 book: The State Theory of Money.
While there was no obligation to accept Banco-Zettel
as legal tender outside of Austria,
there was no doubt that they would be redeemed for silver coin on
presentation,
so that the Banco-Zettel at times
even commanded a premium of 1% to 2 1/2% on silver coins. Banco-Zettel
were issued again in 1771 and 1785.
After the war against the Ottoman Empire
in 1788 and the war against Revolutionary France in 1792, Austria
was left in dire financial difficulties. Public expenditure, which had
come to
approximately 90 million gulden before the Ottoman war, skyrocketed to
572
million gulden in 1798. Emperor Francis II (1792 - 1835)
opted to
print more paper money. As the volume of paper money mushroomed,
gold and
silver coins grew scarce, following Gresham’s
Law of bad money driving out good.
Inflation resulting from the quantity theory of money reached dangerous
highs
between 1800 and 1806, after more paper money were repeatedly issued.
The
reparation payments imposed on Austria
by the Peace of Schönbrunn of 1809 fueled inflation further. In
1810, the
volume of Banco-Zettel in circulation exceeded 1 billion gulden. In
December
1810, the government imposed a moratorium on all payment obligations in
coin.
Just three months later, on February
20, 1811, Austria
had to declare national bankruptcy. The Banco-Zettel and the
Banco-Zettel
divisional coins were to be exchanged for exchange coupons also
referred to as
“Vienna currency” at a rate
of 1
coupon to 5 Banco-Settel notes.
The Consequence of
War
The state coffers were severely strained by wars and the
Congress of Vienna in 1814–15, making it necessary to issue paper money
once
again soon after the Banco-Zettel had been exchanged for Vienna
currency. The volume of Vienna currency exchange coupons made it
necessary to
call the new paper money issues “anticipation coupons”
(Antizipationsscheine),
as they were covered by tax revenue not yet collected.
Inflation was an inevitable consequence of war. The public lost 90% of
their cash
wealth from paper currency devaluation, the redistribution of incomes,
the
outflow of assets abroad, and the monetary reconstruction which
followed.
In May 1815 Austria
began to put her monetary system back on a sounder footing. The Privilegirte Oesterreichische
National-Bank was founded June
1, 1816,
modeled on the French and English national banks, as an independent
stock
company vested with the right to issue banknotes to stabilize the
monetary
system, to finance the chronic budget deficit and to manage the
expansion of
the money supply. By 1847, the Vienna
currency exchange coupons had been almost wholly exchanged for
Convention
coins, and after a 25-year pause, it became possible to mint gold and
silver
coins again.
Austria,
however, decided to keep its silver currency
and sought to join the German Zollverein, a customs union established
in 1834
among the majority of the states of the German Confederation during the
Industrial Revolution to remove internal customs barriers, although
upholding a
protectionist tariff system with foreign trade partners. The main
ideological
contributor behind the customs union was Friedrich List, an advocate of
economic nationalism. The Zollverein had excluded Austria
because of its highly protected industry. The
exclusion exacerbated the Austro-Prussian rivalry for dominance in
central Europe during the late 19th century.
The member states of
the Zollverein had already embarked on a unification of currency
systems with
the Agreement of Munich in 1837. Twenty years later, Austria
relinquished its Convention monetary standard
in the Vienna Monetary Agreement of 1857 and adjusted the Austrian
gulden to
the North German thaler, a silver coin used throughout Europe for almost four
hundred years. One and a half
Austrian gulden were equal to a Convention thaler. The coin weight unit
was the
“pound” of 500 grams, with 30 Convention thalers (45 Austrian gulden)
being
struck from 1 pound of fine silver. Under the decimal system that was
obligatory for the Zollverein currency, the Austrian gulden was
subdivided into
100 kreuzer. The Zollverein was effectively ended in 1866 with
outbreak of
the Austro-Prussian War. A new organization with the same name was
formed in
1867 when peace was restored.
After Prussia defeated Austria
at the Battle of Königgrätz in 1866, Austria
pulled out of the Zollverein and in 1867
oriented its coinage on the bimetallic standard of the Latin Monetary
Union
(LMU) founded by France, Belgium, Switzerland and Italy in 1865. In a nod to the LMU, Austria
minted gold coins of a value of 8 and 4 gulden,
which were the equivalent of 20 and 10 francs. However, Austria
never actually joined the LMU, a step it had
planned for 1870, because its monetary system remained in
disarray.
Monetary Impacts of the
Revolutions of 1848
After the successful consolidation of the monetary system of Austria,
the revolutions of 1848 represented a renewed disruption. The money
supply shot
up. In May, the redemption of banknotes in silver was suspended, making
paper money
legal tender, i.e. acceptance of paper money was declared a legal
obligation
(it was declared fiat, or fiduciary, money).
Whereas the state resorted to issuing banknotes to cover the cost of
quelling
the revolution and of the wars with Hungary
and Italy,
the
municipalities and citizens issued notgeld (emergency money) to cope
with the
lack of change. Tokens of brass, lead, tin, copper and even glass,
leather,
wood and cardboard were circulated. By prohibiting the acceptance of
such
privately-issued token coinages and by issuing sufficient amounts of
official
divisional coins, the imperial treasurer managed to regain control of
the
monetary system before the end of 1848.
Latin Monetary Union
The US Civil War ((1861–65) led to demonetization of silver
in the US
and
the rise of the Republican Party of big finance. After blocking the
Silver
Republicans from control of the party, the Grand Old Party established
the gold
standard and became closely linked to British banking interests and
shifted the
preserved union further from its founding focus of popular democracy.
As the US Civil War began to exercise upward pressure on the
market price of silver, Second Empire France
(1852-70) under Napoleon III launched a broad initiative to create
monetary
union in Europe based on standardized silver
coinage. It
came to be called the Latin Monetary Union (LMU), a forerunner of
today’s euro
which was established by the 1992 Maastricht Treaty on European
Economic and
Monetary Union. The LMU came into being in 1865 between France,
Italy,
Belgium
and Switzerland,
setting the silver/gold monetary ratio at 15.5/1. To conform to union
standard,
the alloy/silver content in the French franc was increased from 1/10 to
1/6.
Thereafter silver and gold coins of LMU member countries were accepted
as legal
tender in the whole union but token coins were legal only within
countries of
origin. Greece
joined the LMU in 1868, but Scandinavian countries withdrew in 1870 as
a result
of Franco-Prussian War. Other countries fixed their coinage to LMU
standard
without formal membership.
By 1873, the relatively high market value of silver in
relation to gold in Europe engineered by Britain’s overvalue of the
monetary
value of gold in England caused a wave of conversion from silver to
gold at the
LMU monetary rate of 15.5 ounces of silver to 1 of gold for easy profit
by
shipping the gold to England for silver to return to Europe to buy more
gold to
ship to England. In 1873, 154 million francs were exchanged for gold
for export
to England,
over 5 times the amount exchanged in the previous year. Fearing that a
massive
influx of silver coinage to Europe coupled with
a
massive outflow of gold to Britain
would destroy bimetallism, the LMU member nations agreed in Paris
on January 30, 1874
to
limit the free conversion of silver temporarily.
By 1878, with no stabilization in the commercial price of
silver in sight, minting of silver coinage was suspended entirely. From
1873
onwards, the LMU was on a de facto gold standard under British
monetary
pressure. The LMU was finally disbanded in 1927 since the gold standard
had
made it superfluous. Two years later, the gold standard caused the
crash of
1929 and brought on the Great Depression and eventually World War I.
Switzerland, a neutral nation still with honest banking, continued to
mint
Swiss silver and gold coins set to LMU bimetal standard until 1967.
The silver/gold bimetal standard adopted by the LMU at first
required little government intervention in foreign exchange markets
beyond
setting commonly agreed upon monetary standards among member states.
This
created a direct conflict with British strategy to demonetize silver
through
the overvaluing of the monetary ratio of gold to silver. After enough
gold had
flowed into England,
she began, as planned, to use the gold standard to financing the
expansion of
the British Empire by expanding pound sterling
money
supply without destabilizing international exchange rates. The LMU was
standing
in the way of this strategy by keeping bimetallism operating. England
needed to destroy the LMU by causing the commercial price of silver in Europe
to rise against gold and above the monetary silver/gold ratio set by
the LMU
bimetal regime, making seignoriage costly to LMU member governments.
French Second
Empire
The French economy modernized during the Second Empire
(1852-70) under Napoleon III (1808-73), the bourgeois
emperor who fashioned himself as a reformer and social engineer. The
industrialization of France
during this period was supported at first by both big business and
workers. Yet
Napoleon III mongered fear of social radicalism where his heroic uncle
promised
the vision of a new world order. Architecturally, he resurrected the
baroque
style of the counter-reformation and infested it with the cultural
obesity of
vulgarity and ostentatious exhibitionism of the Second
Empire.
Bonapartism, militarism, clericalism, conservatism and liberalism were
incorporated superficially in the new bourgeois political culture.
Napoleon III
faced a delicate balancing act between the legitimacy conferred by
parliamentary liberalism and the need to maintain a police state to
control
opposition. Napoleon III’s populist authoritarian style of empty
substance,
both political and esthetical, would since be imitated by every
subsequent pint-size
dictator.
Some of the supporters of the Second Empire
were Saint-Simonians who described Napoleon III as the “socialist
emperor.”
Saint-Simonians founded a new type of banking institution, in the form
of Crédit
Mobilier, which sold stock to the public and then used the money
raised to
invest in industrial enterprises in France.
This sparked a period of rapid economic development. It became the
model for
investment banking in modern times. The discovery of gold in California
in 1849
and in Australia soon after greatly increased money supply in Europe
which
fitted in with the rise of new credit institutions. The new investment
banks
built large scale projects, such as the Suez Canal
at
first through state-owned enterprises. With the appearance of private
banking,
large corporations followed to mobilize capital to build rail roads,
the new
transportation system that allowed development of landed interior,
breaking the
trade monopoly of coastal cities.
In 1863, a new law of limited liability was proclaimed by
which a stockholder would risk only the par value of his stock
regardless of
the scale of insolvency and outstanding debt carried by the company.
The
public, even those with no skill in business and finance, could now
invest in
enterprises that could operate at a scale beyond what individual
shareowners
could otherwise do separately. Financiers who were skilled in handling
money,
credit and securities assumed a new prominence in society. Some became
super
rich to rival dukes and princes of the feudal age. Industrial growth
was
accompanied by a decline in deep-rooted morals. The purpose of life
transformed
into a single-minded quest for easy money through speculation.
French capital went overseas to develop colonies. In the US,
it took the form of Credit Mobilier of America, the builder of the
Union
Pacific Railroad, which was later engulfed in a major scandal involving
the
bribing of members of congress with company stocks. The investment
company
charge $94 million for construction that cost less than $50 million to
pay
dividends of 348%, a hundred times more than convention.
Four merchants with names that history would
immortalize: Leland Stanford (Stanford
University),
Collins P Huntington,
Charles Crocker (Crocker National Bank) and Mark Hopkins (Mark Hopkins
Hotel in San Francisco) were part of Credit Mobilier of America.
High baroque was a style of vulgar exhibitionism preferred
by the Second Empire under Napoleon III.
George-Eugene
Haussmann (1809-91), the influential but insensitive city planner under
the
imperial dictator, with his wholesale clearance of historical Paris,
indiscriminately wiping out ancient picturesque quartiers of
uniquely
individual character and colorful past, destroyed much of the city’s
old charm,
not to mention historical landmarks, and replaced them with sterile and
brassy
monumental white elephants, linked by drab and mediocre avenues devoid
of human
scale. Armed with the blind zeal of a sanitation engineer, with as much
sensitivity for architecture as a circus producer, Haussmann's baroque
city
planning was also dominated by the political purpose of clearing the
rebel-infested urban quartiers in the old city, of the ease of
effectively deploying troops on the new, broad boulevards against
much-feared
popular uprisings, and of preventing the easy erection of revolutionary
barricades on narrow streets that had once frustrated government
authority in
the "Bloody June Days" of the democratic uprisings of 1848.
Unfortunately, Haussmann has since been much imitated by many egomaniac
city
planners worldwide in modern times, just as his patron, Napoleon III,
has been
imitated by every pint-size dictator. Washington
DC is a classic
example of Haussmann urban
design. The City beautiful Movement in US
city planning is strongly influenced by Haussmann. Victor Hugo
(1802-85), the
towering figure of French literature, poetry and drama, son of a
general under
Napoleon Bonaparte, opposed the regime of Napoleon III's Second
Empire and lived in exile in protest until after its
downfall in
1870. Emile Zola (1840-1902) documented in his series of social-realism
novels
the abuses suffered by the poor in France
during the Second Empire, as Charles Dickens
(1812-70)
did with the Industrial Revolution in England.
The sensational novels of Alexandre Dumas the younger, son of Dumas pere,
the best-known of which being Camille, mirrored the pitiless
emptiness
of Parisian life, while the operettas of Jacques Levy Offenbach, though
popularly acclaimed by society during the Second Empire, satirized the
mundane
values of their naive, applauding audiences.
The Paris Opera (begun in 1861 and opened in 1875), the crown jewel of
the
Second Empire, the piece de resistance de la Belle Epoque of
the
bourgeois emperor, was designed by Charles Garnier (1825-98), star
student of
the state-sponsored Ecole des Beaux-Arts, winner of the Grand Prix de
Rome. The
building, which would become the model for architecturally mundane
opera houses
all over the world, failed to herald any worthwhile movement of
architecture.
With its unabashed flaunting of banal stylistic ostentation, devoid of
originality, mindlessly confusing conspicuous consumption with
sophisticated
elegance, oozing with the vulgarity of the nouveau
riche, it was a bourgeois caricature of the much-admired style of
the
exquisite east facade of the Louvre designed by Claude Perrault
(1613-88).
Functionally, the horseshoe plan of the Paris Opera House condemned a
disproportionately large portion of the audience to obstructed sight
lines and
inferior acoustics while affording a few boisterous celebrities in the
side parterres
to compete with the stage for attention. The New York Metropolitian
Opera House
adopt a horseshoe plan, modified to accommodate 3,700 seats, more that
twice
the capacity of the Paris Opera, magnified the faults of the Paris
Opera while
diluting the intimate spatial quality of the horseshoe plan by its
oversize.
Conditions in the second half of the 19th century
were favorable for industrial expansion due to a confluence of factors.
Technology took a big leap forward from a sharp increase of the money
supply to
turn an eruption of scientific discoveries into new industrial
enterprises. The
gold rush in California,
and
later Australia,
increased the global money supply operating under the gold standard.
The steady
rise of prices caused by the increase of the money supply encouraged
the
forming of joint stock companies that provided respectable returns and
prospered from domestic and overseas investments. In France,
the mileage of railways in France
increased from 3,000 to 16,000 kilometers during the 1850s, and this
growth of
a new form of land transportation allowed inland mines and factories to
operate
at higher rates of productivity benefiting continental powers. The 55
smaller
rail lines of France
were merged into 6 major lines, while new iron steamships fueled by
coal
replaced wooden sail ships. Between 1859 and 1869, a French joint stock
company
with the government as the major share owner built the Suez
Canal,
opening a new chapter in global transportation and trade with Asia.
French Capitalism and
Imperialism
The connection of global finance with imperialistic
expansion made Britain
into a superpower even before the railway age because of the long coast
line of
the island nation. Following Britain’s
example, France
under Napoleon III adopted free trade in 1860 and took steps to
establish a
French colonial empire in Indochina.
In 1680, the French East India Company, which had been
chartered by Louis XIV in 1664 to compete with its British and Dutch
counterparts, opened a trading post in Pho Hien.
In 1858, Napoleon III launched a punitive naval expedition against the Vietnam
kingdom with the pretext of punishing Buddhist Vietnamese for their
resistance
to French Catholic missionaries and forced the Vietnam
king to accept a French presence in the country. An important factor in
his
decision was the belief that France
risked becoming a second-rate power by not expanding its influence in East
Asia. Also, the idea that France
had a civilizing mission was spreading beyond Europe
was
in the France
psyche. This eventually led to a full-out invasion in 1861. By 1862,
victory in
war created the French Empire in Indochina with
a
federation of four protectorates (Tonkin,
Annam,
Cambodia
and Laos)
and one directly-ruled colony (Cochin-China) with Nanoi as capital.
Three ports
were opened exclusively to French trade, with free passage of French
warships
up river, freedom of action for French missionaries. France
received a large war indemnity.
In China,
France
took
part in the Second Opium War in support of Britain,
and in 1860 French troops entered Peking along
side
British troops. China
was forced to concede more trading rights, allow freedom of navigation
of the Yangtze River, permit Christian
missionaries to operate on Chinese soil,
and give France
and Britain
huge war indemnity. This combined with the intervention in Vietnam
set the stage for further French influence in China
leading up to a sphere of influence over parts of Southern
China.
In 1866, French naval troops launched a failed attack on Korea
in response to the execution of French missionaries, which resulted in
the
eclipse of French influence in the region. In 1867, a French Military
Mission to Japan
was sent,
which played a key role in modernizing the troops of the Shogun
Tokugawa
Yoshinobu, and even participated on his side against Imperial troops
during the
Boshin war.
In Europe, the Franco-Prussian War (1870-71)
broke out over the issue of a German Hohenzollern prince for the vacant
Spanish
throne, a vestige of the Holly Roman Empire, following the deposition
of
Isabella II in 1868 against a background of historic hostility dating
back to
the defeat of Napoleon I at Waterloo
by a British-Prussian coalition. The war gave Britain
an opening to force the demonetization of silver in Europe
via its support of Prussia
whose Crown Prince was married to a princess daughter of Queen Victoria.
The liberal
democratic attempt to unify Germany had failed along with the 1848
democratic
revolutions. Prussian victory over France of Napoleon III paved
the way
for German unification on January
23, 1871 through conservative politics of blood and iron
engineered by
Otto von Bismarck, the welfare statesman who gladly paid the price of
demonetizing silver to buy British acquiescence. A unified Germany
would rise to challenge British hegemony, resulting in the First World
War in
1914.
The Paris Commune of 1871, its Suppression and
Political Implications
The Second Empire political culture
was a mixed bag of Bonapartism, adventurism, militarism, expansionism,
colonialism, clericalism, conservatism and liberalism, particularly in
trade
and finance. It could only be sustained by victory in foreign wars. The
Franco-Prussian War was France’s
response to rising Germen challenge against French hegemony in
continental Europe.
The fate of the Second Empire
depended on a continuing
train of victories in foreign war which unfortunately was derailed by
the
better-led Prussian army.
On September 4, 1870,
two days after Emperor Napoleon III surrendered to the Prussian army at
the
disastrous Battle of Sedan and allowed himself to be taken prisoner,
the French
emperor was deposed by republican forces in Paris.
The end to the Second Empire was proclaimed
along with
the creation of the Third Republic of France headed by Louis-Adolphe
Thiers.
On March 3, one month after the signing of the armistice
with Germany
by
the new Third Republic,
and seventy days before the official end to the war, German troops
marched into
a Paris of empty streets
and
shuttered windows, shut down in silent protest by the indignant people
of Paris.
The Parisians elected a municipal council - the Paris Commune -
consisting of moderate
republicans, Proudhon anarchists, Blanqui putschists and Marxist worker
association members.
On March 18, , to regain control of Paris from Communards,
Thiers attempted to seize the cannons of the National Guard, an armed
militia
of some 260 battalions organized earlier by the fallen government of
the Second
Empire to help defend Paris against the Prussian siege in the last days
of the
disastrous Franco-Prussian War, and to use them against the Communards.
But the
attempt was foiled by the Women of Montmartre who appealed to
government
soldiers, many of whom refused to fire on the people of Paris
and turned their muskets against Third
Republic
government forces in a
gesture of solidarity with the Commune. Within hours Paris
was in a state of insurrection, and the Mairies
of many arrondisements in the capital
came under the control of the National Guard. During these feverish
hours, an
angry mob seized two commanding government generals, one of whom having
been
involved in trying to capture the cannons against the people summarily
executed
them against the wall of a garden in Montmartre.
The
firing squad included members of the National Guard as well as
disgruntled
government troops.
Thiers and his provincial government fled to Versailles
to join the National Assembly under a majority of Monarchists from
previous
elections. The Central Committee of the National Guard occupied the
abandoned Hôtel de Ville and announced
preparations for new municipal elections. On March 26, the left
coalition
gained enough votes to establish a socialist-oriented ‘Commune’ - which
will
last until May 28. On March 28, the Commune installed itself at the Hôtel de Ville, and for the next two
months ran Paris to
implement a
program of social reform, while fending off a growing siege from the
Versaillais, who advance closer and closer in a singularly brutal war
fought on
the western edges of the capital.
During its short reign, the Paris Commune proclaimed the
separation of church and state and the nationalization of Church
property. On April 8, 1871,
it removed all
representations of religion from the schools of Paris.
The Communards tried to introduce a series of radical social measures,
e.g.,
separation of Church and State, establishing a lay education system,
opening
professional education for women, provision of pensions to unmarried
women
workers, abolition of night-work for bakers, etc.
On April 11, government troops sent by Thiers began a new
siege of Paris. Intense
fighting
continued into May. After the official end to the war with Prussia
on May 10, government troops, free from confronting a victorious enemy
that
their former emperor had surrendered to, broke through the people’s
defense and
entered Paris on May 21,
and for
eight days they overwhelmed Communard resistance street by street. This
period
was known in history as la semaine
sanglante - ‘the bloody week’. In a series of bloody attacks
against street
barricades across Paris,
before
finally eliminating the last blocks of Communard resistance in the
working
class 11th, 19th and 20th arrondisements.
In an orgy of reprisals, up to 20,000 workers
and peasants, including children, were killed by a French army under
the
direction of its most senior generals that had not shown similar élant against foreign enemy soldiers in
a foreign war.
Many have since viewed the Paris Commune as a monument of
struggle for liberation that provided a symbolic model for a political
system
based on grass-root participatory democracy. Several Chinese
revolutionaries,
such as Zhou Enlai and Deng Xiaoping, as young students in France
in 1920 inspired by the Paris Commune, formed the nuclear of what later
became
the Communist Party of China.
The collapse of the Paris Commune was another disappointment
on top of the failed Revolutions of 1848 for revolutionaries worldwide,
including Marx and Engels. Reactionary hostility to revolution helped
elect to
the new National Assembly delegates close to the Church and in favor of
restoring the monarchy, and in 1873 a monarchist majority forced Thiers
to
resign. However, with monarchists weakened by internal factional
division, moderate
Republicans won enough support in France’s
parliament to frustrate monarchist aims, and the Third
French Republic
was born in 1879 to survive until 1940.
Marx and Class
Struggle
After the failures of the democratic revolutions of 1848, socialist
movements went into abeyance for two decades, until Karl Marx published
his “Das
Kapital” in 1867 (first English trans.
in 1887, 4 years after his death, with Volume II and III, ed. by Engels
1884-94, Eng. trans 1907-9). The manuscript for the fourth volume was
edited by
Karl Kautsky and published in German as Theroien
uber den Mehrwert (3 parts, 1905-10). The full English translation
of the
1st part, A History of Economic Theories,
was not published until 1952. Selected
translations were published as Theories
of Surplus Value in 1951. Yet the spirit of 1848 echoed around the
world
among the oppressed.
Marx rejected utopian socialism and introduced scientific
socialism. Louis Blanc (1811-82), in his Organization
du Trvail, published 1840, from which sprung the famous “from each
according to his ability, to each according to his needs”, advocated
workers cooperatives
supported by the state, provided a link between utopian and scientific
socialism. Breaking with the tradition of natural rights as a basis for
reform,
Marx invoked “inevitable” laws of historical premises. Through
dialectic
materialism, which presumes the primacy of economic determinants in
history,
the premise of class struggle holds that a specific class can rule only
as long
as it represents the productive forces of society, and from this
historical
process, a classless society would eventually emerge.
Class struggle has nothing to do with promoting hatred
between classes, as capitalist propaganda fear-mongering would have the
world
believe. Class struggle leads to the demise of capitalism out of a
scientific
historical process by the nature of economic concepts such as the labor
theory
of value and the idea of surplus value. These concepts argue that the
value of
a commodity is determined by the amount of labor required for its
manufacture,
not by its exchange value in a market manipulated by capitalists. The
value of
the commodities meant for purchased by worker wages is set higher than
the value
of the commodities workers produce with their labor. The difference,
called
surplus value, is the profit for capitalists who own the capital. When
surplus
value becomes excessive, overcapacity and insufficient demand will
result
because workers who produce the products cannot afford to buy them with
their
low wages. Globalization of trade under dollar hegemony in the 21st
century via cross-border wage arbitrage to deny the labor theory of
value will
lead to the collapse of neo-liberal free market capitalism. It is a
scientific
phenomenon, unrelated to ideology or morality.
As productivity improves through industrialization, the
fruits of production are increasingly kept from the workers who
contribute most
to its production, through the exploitation of labor by capital via the
capitalistic structure in the economy. The workings of this artificial
structure are presented as economic laws of the market. If and when
these
exploitative features of market economy are removed, capitalism will be
replaced by socialism as feudalism, having lost its economic function,
had once
been replaced by capitalism.
It is when the capitalist class employs armed suppression of
this evolutionary development that makes revolution by the working
class
necessary. Socialist revolutionaries seek to destroy only the political
structure that insists on foiling the organic evolutionary process from
capitalism toward socialism. Capitalism by itself has already exhausted
its
socio-economic function in history and its demise needs no further
coaxing.
The collapse of the Paris Commune of 1871, suppressed with
bloody ferocity by the French bourgeoisie, consolidated a reactionary
backlash
that dissipated the First International, an international socialist
organization founded in 1864 which aimed at uniting a variety of
different
progressive political groups and trade union organizations that were
based on
advancing the cause of the working class through the theory of class
struggle. Marx
praised the Paris Commune and introduced the concept of the
dictatorship of the
proletariat as a defensive countermeasure against anticipated
capitalist reactionary
barbarism.
By 1880, a popular movement to restore protective tariffs
against British commercial dominance emerged, but tariffs were
impediments
rather than effective barriers, which were finally brought on by the
start of
the First World War in 1914. As with the
US today, Britain, the finance hegemon in the 19th century,
despite
the export of manufactured goods of the industrial revolution, consume
more
goods from abroad than its sent out, with import increasing by eight
folds
while import increased by ten folds between 1800 and 1900. In the
decades
before 1914 when the war started, Britain
enjoyed an annual import surplus of more than $750 million on average.
She was
able to do this because of pound sterling hegemony as the US
is able to do the same today because of dollar hegemony.
Trade Surplus
Denominated in Foreign Currency not a Plus
What many trade economists fail to understand is that a
trade surplus is not a plus for an economy when trade is denominated in
a
foreign currency even if that currency is backed by gold. When trade is
denominated in a fiat paper currency backed by military power, a trade
deficit
by that currency issuing country is pure monetary imperialism against
its trade
surplus partners. For the monetary hegemon, such as the US
after the Cold War, factor income from overseas investment more than
out
weights loss of domestic factor income from wages.
Council of Economic Advisers chairman Martin Feldstein, a
highly respected conservative economist from Harvard with a reputation
for
intellectual honesty, was not only among the first to understand the
obscure
relationship between trade deficits and the reserve currency for trade.
He was
also the first to propose it as US
national policy. He pointed out the benefits of a strong dollar in
President
Reagan’s first term, arguing that the loss suffered by US manufacturing
for
export was a fair cost for national financial strength derived from a
strong
currency that had the advantage of being the reserve currency for
trade. But
such sophisticated views were not music to the ears of the uninformed
chauvinistic Reagan White House, nor the Treasury under Donald Reagan,
former
head of Merrill Lynch, whose roster of clients included all major
manufacturing
giants which had yet to catch on to the escape valve of outsourcing
labor-intensive manufacturing to low-wage countries and that it was
more
profitable to import low price-goods from overseas than to export
non-competitive over-priced goods overseas. Feldstein, given the
brush-off by a
White House run by astrology, went back to Harvard to continue his
quest for
truth in theoretical global geo-economics after serving two years in
the Reagan
White House, where voodoo economics reigned.
Feldstein went on to train many influential economists who later would
hold key
positions in government, including Larry Summers, treasury secretary
under
president Bill Clinton and later a failed president of Harvard
University;
Lawrence Lindsey, dismissed Presidential Economic Advisor to President
George
W. Bush; and Gregory Mankiew, Chairman of the Bush White House Council
of
Economic Advisers, who sparked an uproar by saying, in the same
intellectual tradition:
“Outsourcing is a growing phenomenon, but it’s something that we should
realize
is probably a plus for the [US] economy in the long run.” Whether that
is true
depends of course on which part of the US
economy one is housed.
The Classical Gold
Standard Era
The gold standard was an international standard that determined
the value of a country’s currency in terms of other countries’
currencies
through the monetary value of gold as expressed in each currency.
Because
adherents to the gold standard maintained a fixed price for gold, rates
of
exchange between currencies tied to gold were necessarily fixed. For
example,
the United States
fixed the price of gold at $20.67 per ounce from 1834 until 1933; Britain
fixed the price at £3 17s 10.5d per ounce until WWI and restore
it in 1925. The
exchange rate between dollars and pounds—the “par exchange
rate”—necessarily came
to $4.867 per pound sterling during these periods.
Other major trading countries joined the gold standard in
the 1870s. The period from 1880 to 1914 is known as the classical gold
standard
era in monetary history. During that time, a majority of trading
nations
adhered in varying degrees to the gold standard. It was also a period
of
unprecedented economic growth with relatively free trade in goods,
labor, and
capital without being hampered by government or market exchange rate
manipulation. Between 1880 and 1914, the period when the United
States was on the gold standard,
inflation
averaged only 0.1 percent per year. This
was because the physical supply of gold was in sync with the rate of
economic
expansion, but because of the endogenous effect of the gold standard.
But the
demonetization of silver gradually destroyed the myth that the gold
standard
could keep the value of money stable without the anchor of bimetallism.
Also, stable currency was generally associated with the gold
standard partly because international trade during the classical gold
standard
era was a relatively small portion of all national economies. Trade for
Britain
was largely an intra-empire affair dominated by the pound sterling.
Today, for
nations that fall into the trap of excessively high foreign trade
dependency,
generally viewed as above 35% of GDP in total two-way trade, exchange
rate
issues related to a reserve currency denominated in foreign fiat
currency, such
as the dollar, can and will do great damage to their national economies
in
cyclical financial crises.
Gold Standard
Restoration Problems
As noted before, the commercial value ratio between silver
and gold was 61.6/1 on August
25, 2008
with the market price for silver at $13.45 and that of gold at $829.
The
commercial value of gold was four times higher than the monetary value
of gold
set by bimetallism. A return to the
historical gold standard now would drive any government bankrupt unless
gold is
set at a monetary value higher than its highest recorded commercial
value,
which is about $1,000 so far.
The US Treasury now owns 261 million ounces of gold. At its
peak in December 1941 it owned 650 million ounces. As of August 30, 2008, the US
National Debt was $9.65
trillion. Price of gold required to pay back the national debt with
gold held
by the US
would
have to be US$36,983 per ounce. The rise in the price of gold necessary
to keep
up with the rise in US
national debt at current rate is US$8.15 per ounce per day. There is no
free
market for gold. The price of gold is the most manipulated item of
government
intervention of the market. When there is no free market for gold,
there is no
free market for anything else. Free markets have never existed in
civilization
for that matter. Free market fundamentalism is merely a fantasy.
To restore the gold standard, gold price would have to
increase constantly even if there is no inflation because the rate of
physical
production of new gold is far below the accepted rate of economic
expansion in
modern time. The monetary inelasticity of gold is the strongest
obstacle to a
restoration of the gold standard.
World War I and the
Decline of Britain
Prior to World War I, Britain’s economy was the world’s
strongest, controlling 40% of the world’s investments and 80% of world
trade,
mostly due to its vast network of colonies. However, by the end of the
war, Britain
owed £850 million, mostly to the United
States,
with interest payment taking up 40% of the government’s budget.
Attempting to
protect her financial advantage against rising German challenge was a
fundamental cause of the war. British, spoiled by pound sterling
hegemony that
had reduced industrial productivity in the British Isles in favor of
financial
manipulation, having to reply heavily on exploiting the wealth of her
colonies,
fell into debtor nation status from war spending, allowing the US to
become the
world’s strong financial power. Even though the British
Isles
were also exempted from war destruction in WWI, British productivity
suffered
from the disruption of her network of far-flung colonies. The Federal
Reserve
under Benjamin Strong after World War I tried to help Britain
maintain the gold standard as a way to rebuilt Europe’s
war-torn economy under British leadership, a move that contributed
significantly to the 1929 crash on Wall Street.
The export of capital meant that an older and wealthier
country, instead of using its entire national income to raise the
standard of
living of its own people by raising wages and investing in better
houses and
more efficient factories, diverted increasing large portion of the
national
income for overseas investment to increase trade. Banks of rich
countries lend
money to banks of less developed countries not to improve the living
standard
of the borrowing countries, which in turn lent money to support foreign
trade
in those countries. Capital then came from profit from keeping both
domestic
and foreign wages low, creating a structural widening of income and
wealth
disparity both among nations and within nations. Workers of the world
over
forewent better income to support capitalist of the world.
In the US,
economic expansion from the 1850s on was largely finance by French
capital and
by British capital after the fall of Napoleon III.
By 1914, Britain
controlled $30 billion in foreign investment, about one quarter of her
national
wealth. France
controlled $8.7 billion, about one sixth of her national wealth, and Germany
controlled $6 billion of overseas investment, at a faster rising pace
than the
two leaders. It was this German threat to British/French overseas
investment
supremacy that led to the First World War by the end of which Britain
lost about one quarter of her overseas investment, France
about one third and Germany
the entire amount, all to the US.
Before 1914, world trade was denominated in currencies that
adhered to the gold standard anchored by the pound sterling, with London
as the preeminent financial center. Trade surpluses and deficits at
fixed
exchange rates caused inflow and outflow of gold across national
borders.
Exchange rates could not be manipulated by government or through market
forces
to correct imbalance of payments. After World War I, with massive gold
drained
from the British Treasury, Britain was forced to replace the gold
standard with
a new “gold exchange standard”, basing the pound sterling on the
gold-back
dollar instead of directly on gold held by Britain. The US,
being the world largest creditor nation as a result of war finance, saw
her
central bank becoming the world’s lender of last resort.
Historical data showed that when New York Fed President Benjamin
Strong leaned on the regional Feds to ease the discount rate on an
already overheated
economy in 1927, the Fed lost its last window of opportunity to prevent
the
1929 crash. Some historians claimed that Strong did so to fulfill his
internationalist vision at the risk of endangering the US
national interest.
While British restoration of the gold standard did not occur
officially until April 1925, the decision to re-join the gold standard
had
effectively been taken some seven years earlier. In the final months of
the WWI
in 1918, the Treasury and the Ministry for Reconstruction set up the
Cunliffe
Committee, headed by Lord Cunliffe, former Governor of Bank of England.
Committee members included Cambridge
neoclassical economist Arthur Cecil
Pigou (1877-1959), star student of Alfred Marshall (1824-1924)
and
intellectual heir to Marshallian orthodoxy of supply/demand and
marginal
utility. The Committee was to consider the problems of currency and
foreign
exchange during the reconstruction and “report upon the steps required
to bring
about the restoration of normal conditions in due course.” It was the
forerunner of the post-WWII Bretton Woods Conference.
The Cunliffe interim report in August 1918 concluded that
sterling should re-join the pre-war parity of £3 17s 10.5d per
ounce of gold,
equivalent to $4.86 at $20.67 per ounce of gold, saying “it is
imperative that
the conditions necessary to the maintenance of an effective gold
standard
should be restored without delay.”
But before the gold standard restoration decision was
implemented, wartime decontrols and pent-up post-war demand released a
happy boom
in England
and
the US
which
history referred to as the Roaring Twenties. British trade deficit
widened to
cause the exchange value of sterling to fall substantially. Fiscal
policy was
then tightened and interest rates were raised by the Bank of England to
slow
demand and support the pound sterling, turning the boom into the 1921
slump in
England, creating the steepest recorded recession in British economic
history
to that date, as unemployment climbed from 1.4% to 16.7% within a year
and wholesale
prices fell sharply with deflation. Britain,
adebtor nation by then, was in no position to go along with the US
on a liquidity joy ride.
The deflationary policy stance of the Bank of England brought British
prices
down towards US levels and put upwards pressure on sterling exchange
rate. And
the Bank of England felt comfortable enough with the strength the pound
sterling to lower interest rates in the summer of 1922 to below US
levels. But
by the following summer, with sterling again under downward pressure
and
monetary policy focused on restoring the parity exchange rate to $4.86,
interest rates had to be raised again. By 1924, UK
interest rates were above US levels.
This monetary policy squeeze achieved its dubious objective
of a strong pound sterling. Sterling
rose steadily from a low of $3.20 in February 1920 to $4.32 and then up
to the
pre-war parity of $4.86 in the ten months before the April 1925
decision to
re-fix, a 32% currency appreciation to restore the gold standard that
had been
demolished by the war. After adjusting for what was, despite the
post-slump
deflation, the relative inflation of wholesale prices, which rose by
60% in the UK
between 1914
and 1925 compared to 40% in the US,
this translated to a real exchange rate appreciation of well over 10%
since
1914.
Historian Robert Skidelsky records that there was general
consensus among monetary economists at the time that the gold standard
would
anchor the value of domestic money and prevent inflation. Bank of England
Governor Montagu Norman argued in his Evidence to Parliament that a
return to
the gold standard would prevent a “great borrowing by public
authorities.”
Also, the return to gold was seen as necessary to revive world trade
and
restore Britain’s
trading advantage by restoring the pound sterling as a reserve
currency.
Finally, opinion in the City, the financial heart in London,
was near unanimous in the view that a return to gold was necessary to
restore
it to its former position as the world’s leading banker, and sterling
to its former
position as the world’s leading currency. In hindsight, many now
suspect that
the British ruling circle knew that the gold standard without
bimetallism was
merely a fancy fiat currency regime, and that the gold standard was a
fraud.
Winston Churchill, as Chancellor of the Exchequer, said in
his April 1925 Budget statement: “If we had not taken this action
[restoring
the gold standard] the whole of the rest of the British
Empire
would have taken it without us, and it would have come to a gold
standard, not
on the basis of the pound sterling. But a gold standard of the dollar.”
For Britain,
the 1925 gold standard attempt was a final battle of sterling versus
dollar for
supremacy. It was Britain’s
monetary Waterloo. The
then young
John Maynard Keynes, later a key framer of the Bretton Woods regime
based on a
gold-backed dollar, was not against fixing the pound sterling at its
pre-war
parity with the dollar if circumstances had justified; but he argued
that it
should not be an object of policy and was especially opposed to a
deliberate
policy of deflation to bring it about. But Keynes at that time was only
a young
economist with a lone voice waiting for events to make his views
creditable
four years later when he was introduced to President Roosevelt by Felix
Frankfurter, then a Harvard law professor and later Supreme Court
Justice.
The 1925 return to the Gold Standard ended in failure with
sterling devaluation because Britain
suffered from the delusion of dealing from a position of strength but
in fact
was dealing from a position of hopeless strategic weakness.
International
monetary leadership was passing from London
to New York by larger
trends.
The Post-war Gold
Exchange Standard
Britain’s
post-war gold exchange standard called for Britain
to keep its monetary reserves not in gold, as it had before 1914, but
mainly in
gold-backed dollars, while the countries of continental Europe,
still in the depths of war-torn depression, would keep their reserves
in sterling
backed by dollars. The US
was persuaded by Britain,
her victorious but greatly wounded ally, to fund the recovery of
war-torn Europe
through the British pound sterling, because the US
was not interest in having too many dollars go overseas except to London.
After 1925, British pound sterling became a derivative
currency of the dollar and European currencies became derivative
currencies of
the pound sterling. The Federal Reserve lowered the Fed Funds rate
target to
encourage US banks to lend profitably to British banks backed by the
Bank of England
at rates lower than rates prevalent in Europe
so that
British banks could in turn lend to European borrowers at higher
interest rates
for “carry trade” profit. The Bank of
England in effect became a monetary agent of the US dollar after WWI
which was
the reason why post-war reconstruction of Europe
never
benefited the British economy and failed to restore Britain,
a victor in the war, to her pre-war glory. Most of the profit went to
Wall
Street.
The Finance Committee
of the League of Nations and the International Monetary Fund
The Finance Committee of the League of Nations,
dominated by British bankers, pressured European member states to
establish
central bank collaboration with the Bank of England, around the new
gold
exchange standard in which claims on gold were merely theoretical,
difficult to
exercise by non-government market participants.
European currencies holders could lay claim on the pound
sterling, after which they become pound sterling holders. But because
cross-border flow of funds was strictly controlled, they could not lay
claim on
the dollar because they did not hold British nationality. British
holders of
pound sterling had no claim on dollars or gold because Britain
was a debtor to the US.
Only central banks were able to transact foreign exchange
deals. This allowed all currencies to deface together without creating
volatility in exchange rates, providing the world economy with massive
liquidity without destabilizing the fixed exchange rate regime all
through the
1920s. The League of Nations Finance
Committee provided a model for the International Monetary Fund after
World War
II to allow issuer of the world’s reserve currency, namely the US,
to dominate global finance with dollar hegemony.
Finance
Internationalism verses Economic Nationalism
The return to the gold standard via the new gold exchange standard
in war-torn Europe in the 1920s was engineered
by a
coalition of internationalist central bankers on both sides of the Atlantic
as a prerequisite for postwar economic reconstruction. Benjamin Strong,
president of the New York Fed, and his former partners at the House of
Morgan
were closely associated with the Bank of England, the Banque de France,
the
Reichsbank, and the central banks of Austria,
the Netherlands,
Italy,
and Belgium,
as well as with leading internationalist private bankers in those
countries. The
supranational institution supervising the international arrangement was
the
Finance Committee of the League of Nations.
Montagu Norman, governor of the Bank of England from 1920-44,
enjoyed a long and close personal friendship with Benjamin Strong of
the New
York Fed as well as being ideological allies. Their joint commitment to
restore
the gold standard in Europe and so to bring
about a
return to “international financial normalcy” of the prewar years has
been well
documented. Norman
recognized that the
impairment of Britain’s
financial hegemony by war meant that, to accomplish postwar economic
reconstruction that would preserve residual British monetary advantage,
Europe
would “need the active cooperation of our friends in the United
States.” Not the distinction between
“our
friends in the United
States”, and not “our friend the United
States”.
Like other New York
bankers, Strong perceived World War I as an opportunity to expand US
participation in international finance, allowing New
York
to move toward coveted international-finance-center status to rival London’s
historical preeminence, through the development of a commercial paper
market,
known as bankers’ acceptances in England,
breaking London’s long monopoly. The Federal Reserve Act of 1913
permitted the
Federal Reserve Banks to buy, or rediscount, such paper and the NY Fed
has
since become the national agent for all six regional Reserve Banks.
This
allowed large US
money center banks in New York
to
play an increasingly central role in international finance in
competition with
the London money market.
Herbert Hoover, after losing his second-term US presidential
election to Franklin D Roosevelt as a result of the 1929 crash,
criticized
Strong as “a mental annex to Europe”, and
blamed Strong’s
internationalist commitment to facilitating Europe’s
postwar economic recovery for the US
stock-market crash of 1929 and the subsequent Great Depression that
robbed Hoover
of a second term. Europe’s return to the gold standard, with Britain’s
insistence on what Hoover termed a “fictitious rate” of US$4.86 to the
pound
sterling, required Strong to expand US credit by keeping the discount
rate unrealistically
low and to manipulate the Fed’s open market operations to keep US
interest rate
low to ease market pressures on the overvalued pound sterling. Hoover,
with justification,
ascribed Strong’s internationalist policies to what he viewed as the
malign
persuasions of Norman and other European central bankers, especially
Hjalmar
Schacht of the Reichsbank and Charles Rist of the Bank of France. From
the
mid-1920s onward, the US
experienced credit-pushed inflation, which fueled the stock-market
bubble that
finally collapsed in 1929.
Within the Federal Reserve System, Strong’s low-rate
policies of the mid-1920s also provoked substantial regional
opposition,
particularly from Midwestern and agricultural elements, who generally
endorsed Hoover’s
subsequent critical analysis. Throughout the 1920s, two of the Federal
Reserve
Board's directors, Adolph C Miller, a professional economist, and
Charles S
Hamlin, perennially disapproved of the degree to which they believed
Strong
subordinated domestic interest to international considerations.
The fairness of Hoover’s
allegation is subject to debate, but the fact that there was a
divergence of
priority between the White House and the Fed is beyond dispute, as is
the fact
that what is good for the international financial system may not always
be good
for a national economy. This is evidenced today by the collapse of one
economy
after another under the current international finance architecture that
all
central banks support instinctively out of a sense of institutional
solidarity.
The issue of government control over foreign loans also
brought the Fed, dominated by Strong, into direct conflict with Hoover
when the latter was Secretary of Commerce. HooverUS
government should have right of approval on foreign loans based on
national-interest
considerations and that the proceeds of US loans should be spent on US
goods
and services. Strong opposed all such restrictions as undesirable
government
intervention in free trade and international finance.
In July and August 1927, Strong, despite ominous data on
mounting market speculation and inflation, pushed the Fed to lower the
discount
rate from 4 to 3% to relieve market pressures again on the overvalued
British pound.
In July 1927, the central bankers of Great
Britain, the United
States, France,
and Weimar Germany
met on Long Island in the US
to discuss means of increasing Britain’s
gold reserves and stabilizing the European currency situation. Strong’s
reduction of the discount rate and purchase of £12 million, for
which he paid
the Bank of England in gold, not dollars, appeared to come directly
from that
meeting. French central banker Charles Rist reported that Strong said
that US
authorities would reduce the discount rate as “un petit coup de whisky
for the
stock exchange.” Strong pushed this reduction through the Fed despite
strong opposition
from Miller and fellow board member James McDougal of the Chicago Fed,
who
represented Midwestern bankers, who generally did not share New
York’s internationalist preoccupation. See my November 27, 2002 AToL article: Critique of Central Banking
Gold Exchange
Standard ended by the Great Depression
The gold standard broke down during World War I as major
belligerents resorted to inflationary war finance. Classical gold
standard was
causing deflation around that world that translated into a worldwide
depression
while mercantilism, the quest by nations for gold through exporting,
was
causing protectionist reaction in all countries. It was briefly
reinstated from
1925 to 1931 as the gold exchange standard. The idea of the need for
international cooperation in trade and for a new “gold exchange
standard” which
would make wider use of gold by supplementing it with an anchor
currency that
would be readily convertible into gold had been developed in the 1920
international conference in Genoa, Italy, but the participating
governments
failed to reach agreement on account not all were ready to accept
British
sterling hegemony. This idea was incorporated two and a half decades
later into
the Bretton Woods regime with a gold-backed dollar replacing the
British pound.
The challenge was to devise an operative international finance
architecture out
of fiat currencies anchored to a gold-backed dollar to accommodate
post-war
international trade.
The gold exchange standard version broke down in 1931
following Britain’s
forced departure from gold in the face of massive gold and capital
outflows. In
1933, President Roosevelt nationalized gold owned by private citizens
and
abrogated all contracts in which payment was specified in gold. On
April 5, Roosevelt
issued Executive Order No. 6102 requiring all US
citizens to exchange their gold and gold certificates to a Federal
Reserve Bank
for dollars at $35 per ounce, a currency devaluation of 69.3%, from
$20.28 per
ounce of gold. The public did not object as they were getting $35 for
the gold
that they only paid $20.28 to acquired, not realizing that they only
gained
dollars that were worth 69.3% less that they were worth a day earlier.
Possession of gold beyond $100’s worth after April 5, 1931 was punishable by a fine
of up to $10,000
and imprisonment for up to 10 years.
Birth and Death of
the Bretton Woods Monetary Regime
As WWII came to a close, Anglo-US economists came together
and devised a monetary system for the post-war era. The Bretton Woods
conference was attended by more than 700 delegates from 44 victorious
allied
nations. But the scheme that emerged was designed by the economists
from Western
countries led by the US,
for the benefit of their advanced economies which were expected to hold
up the
world economy as indispensable leaders and structural pillars, a
financial
version of the White Man Burden. The Bretton Woods twins of the IMF and
the
World Bank were given the roles of fire brigade and ambulance
respectively, the
former to police bankrupt poor nations to prevent credit abuse and the
latter
to keep systemic poverty from turning into political instability.
The Bretton Woods system operated for three decades by
getting member nations to deny their citizens the right to buy and own
gold.
Many Third World finance ministers were on the US
payroll directly or indirectly to keep the world network of central
banks
working smoothly under the banner of coordination. The key devices were
always
to not allow ordinary citizens to buy and own gold and ban the import
and
export of gold, under the high sounding name of a gold control policy.
Economic data were structured to show that the Bretton Woods
monetary regime as facilitating economic development and eradicated
poverty.
Yet a case can be made that such meager advances were made by
technological
progress and Cold War competition between the two superpowers. For the
West
where Bretton Woods regime governed, a more equitable monetary regime
might
have produced far superior results. After the demise of the Bretton
Woods
regime, neoliberalism obliterated even the meager progress under the
Bretton
Woods regime. The world economy is currently faced with crises more
serious
than any in history.
The Marshall Plan: a
Trojan Horse
The Marshall Plan, officially announce on June 5, 1947 as
the European Recovery Program, grew out of the Truman Doctrine,
proclaimed
three months earlier on March 12, 1947, stressing US moralistic duty to
resist
by force the establishment of communist governments worldwide. The
Marshall
Plan spent US$13 billion (out of a 1947 GDP of $244 billion or 5.4%,
equivalent
to $777 billion in 2008) to help Europe recover economically from World
War II
to keep it from communism. The amount is about one fifth of the
Treasury’s 2008
plan of nationalizing the liability of $4.5 trillion of Fannie Mae and
Freddie
Mac.
The Marshall Plan money actually did not come out of US
government budget, but out of US sovereign credit. The most significant
aspect
of the Marshall Plan was the US
government guarantee to US investors in Europe
to
exchange their profits denominated in weak European currencies back
into
dollars at guaranteed fixed rates, backed by gold at $35 an ounce. The
key
component of the Plan’s success rested on its monetary prowess based on
the
dollar. At the same time, the Marshall Plan marked the monetary
conquest of Europe
by the US.
At a time when the monetary regimes of Europe
laid in
ruin, the Marshall Plan helped establish the US dollar as the world’s
reserved
currency that anchored a fixed exchange rate regime established by the
IMF,
which had been created by the Bretton Woods Conference in July 1944.
The
Marshall Plan enabled international trade denominated in dollars to
resume
after the war, and laid the foundation for dollar hegemony for three
quarters
of a century, even after the dollar was taken off gold by President
Richard
Nixon in 1971. While the Marshall Plan did help the German economy
recover, it
was not entirely a selfless gift from the victor to the vanquished. It
was more
a Trojan horse for monetary conquest. It condemned Germany’s
economy to the status of a dependent satellite of the US
economy from which it has yet to free itself fully. For that matter,
all the
world’s trading economies have unwittingly become monetary satellites
of the US
because of dollar hegemony.
The Marshall Plan lent Europe the equivalent of
$777
billion in 2008 dollars. China’
foreign-exchange reserves were $1.8 trillion at the end of August 2008
and
still rising despite a marked slowing of the US
economy. Japan’s
were $1.1 trillion. In other words, China
was lending two and a half times more to the United
States in 2008 than the Marshall Plan
lent
to war-torn Europe in 1947. And the US
is anything but war-torn, albeit it is debt infested.
Both China
and Japan
fail
to get full benefits from their trade surpluses, because the loans to
the US
are denominated in dollars that the US
can print at will, and because dollars are useless in China
or Japan
unless
reconverted to yuan or yen. Trapped by dollar hegemony, Both China and Japan
have to buy the dollars they earn in trade with their domestic
currencies. This
causes a rise in the domestic money supply to create inflation and an
overheated economy. Yet both China
and Japan
also
cannot sell dollars for yuan or yen without reducing the yuan or yen
money
supply, causing the Chinese and Japanese economies to contract and the
yuan and
yen exchange rates to rise. Selling dollars will hurt China
and Japan,
both
heavily trade dependent, and cause them to lose export competitiveness.
So the
dollars that China
and Japan
earn
from export must be invested in US Treasuries or other
dollar-denominated
asset.
Between 1946 and 1971, trading countries operated under the
Bretton Woods regime under which countries settled their international
payments
balances in US dollars pegged to gold at $35 per ounce set since 1933
under a
relatively fixed exchange rate system. It was a trade regime of goods
and not
financial instrument because cross-border flow of funds was not
considered as
necessary or desirable for international trade. However, persistent US
balance-of-payments deficits steadily reduced US gold reserves,
reducing
confidence in the ability of the United
States
to redeem its currency in gold. It was becoming evident that capital
movements
across national borders, fixed exchange rates and independent national
monetary
policies simply could not coexist peacefully. A country can have only
two of
the three, as demonstrated by the Mundell-Fleming model which won the
authors
the 1999 Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences.
September 15, 2008
Next: Gold,
Manipulation and Domination
|
|
|
|
|