|
G20 and New World Order
by
Henry C.K. Liu
Part I: How The G20 Saga Began
This article appeared in Atimes.com
on Octber 30, 2013
The unraveling of the global financial network and
trading system since the onset of the global financial crisis that
began in New York in mid 2007 has continued for more than five years
with no end in sight, despite coordinated, extended monetary easing by
many central banks of major economies around the world to shore up a
seriously impaired neoliberal global financial system that has been
disintegrating at the core from its own internal contradictions.
The primary reason for the ineffectiveness of aggressive monetary
response to induce economic recovery is that the large quantity of new
money created by central banks has been channeled into a global banking
system terminally infested with a fatal financial virus in the form of
a gigantic debt bubble.
The world's central banks all belong to a powerful ideological
fraternity that subscribes to the group-think of bankrupt doctrines of
monetarism promoted by the US Federal Reserve.
Since the onset of the 2008 credit crisis, central banks have morphed
from their original role of being lenders of last resort to prevent
cyclical panic bank runs from turning into a systemic crisis of no
confidence in the financial system under their separate jurisdiction,
to a new controversial role of being market-makers of last resort in a
hopelessly dysfunctional economic world order infested with an extreme
case of financial moral hazard and an unstable financial market
structure flooded with unmarketable troubled assets left by a collapsed
giant price bubble created earlier by excessive debt made available by
misguided central bank monetary laxative.
The world's under-capitalized, debt-infested, essentially
insolvent commercial banks of systemic significance have used the
new, basically cost-free money from central banks to avoid insolvency
through deleverage - unloading at face value their large holdings of
overpriced illiquid troubled asset with fallen market value onto the
balance sheets of central banks that have unlimited power to create
money out of thin air to drop as if from helicopters, not on the
economy at large as needed, but into the under-funded reserve accounts
these insolvent banks are required to keep at the electronic vaults of
central banks.
Thus central bank quantitative easing (QE) programs have not provided
macroeconomic stimulus and liquidity to the needy productive sectors of
the economy to kick start and accelerate economic recovery from an
debt-induced recession by moving the ailing economy towards full
employment with living wages to boost necessary consumer demand to soak
up the excess productive capacity that had been financed by excess debt
over past decades.
Instead, central bank QE measures have merely bailed out the
under-capitalized, insolvent banks from their heavily discounted debt
overload, leaving overcapacity in the economy in a worse state by
default. This overcapacity is exacerbated by central bank insistence on
a balanced government fiscal budget not from revenue growth in a robust
economy but by austerity fiscal measures to further dampen
demand.
The now more than five-years-old global recession caused by the
financial crisis that first broke out in earnest in 2008 after an
abrupt seizure of credit markets in mid 2007, triggered a new tradition
of Group of Twenty (G20) Leaders Summits which was initiated on
November 14-15, 2008 by outgoing US President George W Bush
(Republican) near the end of his second and final term, ten days after
Barack Obama (Democrat) won the 2008 presidential election to become
President Elect, to be inaugurated two-and-a-half months later on
January 20, 2009.
The first G20 Leaders Summit on Financial Markets and the World Economy
called by the White House tried to forge a coordinated global response
by separate sovereign nations to an impending melt-down of the world
financial system and to revive the seriously impaired world economy.
The financial crisis elevated the G20 from a perfunctory debating
society between rich and poor countries to a recognized international
institution of real promise, albeit by default.
On the occasion of the First G20 Leaders Summit of 2008, Paul Davidson
and I co-authored an Open
Letter to World Leaders dated November 7, a
week before the White House meeting. The Open Letter was co-signed by a
large number of other supportive economists worldwide. The Open Letter
recommended a new international financial architecture based on an
updated 21st century version of the Keynes Plan originally proposed at
Bretton Woods in 1944.
For economies subject to business cycles, the lower the present rate
of interest, the larger, ceteris
paribus, would be a future rise, the
larger the expected capital loss on securities, and the higher,
therefore, the preference for liquid cash balances. As an extreme
possibility, Keynes envisaged the case in which even the smallest
decline in interest rates would produce a sizable switch into cash
balances, which would make the demand curve for cash balances virtually
horizontal. This limiting case became known as a liquidity trap.
In his two-asset world of cash and government bonds, Keynes argues that
a liquidity trap would arise if market participants believed that
interest rates had bottomed out at a “critical” interest rate level,
and that rates should subsequently rise, leading to capital losses on
bond holdings. The inelasticity of interest rate expectations at
a critical rate would imply that the demand for money would become
highly or perfectly elastic at this point, implying both a horizontal
money-demand function and LM (liquidity preference/money supply)
curve. The monetary authority, then, would not be able to reduce
interest rates below the critical rate, as any subsequent monetary
expansion would lead investors to increase their demand for liquidity
and become net sellers of government bonds. Money-demand growth, then,
should accelerate when interest rates reach the critical level. Of
course, Keynes did not anticipate that central banks would resort to as
unconventonal measures as quantitative easing to buy up all the
government bonds market participants would sell.
Keynes argued that there were three reasons why market participants
hold money. They hold cash for pending transactions purposes, which is
what the quantity theory had always said. They also hold money for
precautionary reasons, so that in an emergency they would have a ready
source of funds. Finally, they hold money for speculative purposes. The
speculative motive arose from the effects of interest rates on the
price of bonds. When interest rates rise, the price of bonds falls.
Thus when people think interest rates are unusually low, they would
prefer to hold their assets in the form of money. If they invested in
bonds and the interest rate rose, they would suffer a loss. Hence the
amount of money market participants would want to hold should be
inversely related to the rate of interest. Market participants will
want to hold more money (liquidity) when interest rates are low than
when they are higher, despite a loss of interest income.
Keynes’ introduction of interest rate into the demand for money has
survived in modern finance, but not for the reasons he gave. Keynes was
thinking in terms of a two-asset world: money, which earned no interest
but which was liquid and had no danger of a capital loss except under
hyperinflation in which there would be a loss of purchasing power; and
bonds,
which earned interest but which were not as liquid and which has a risk
of capital loss. If one thinks not in terms of a two-asset world, but
in terms of the range of assets which actually exist in the current
financial world, there is no reason to hold cash balances for either
precautionary or speculative purposes. These are assets that are both
very liquid and interest bearing, such as money market accounts and
Treasury bills, plus all forms of options in structured finance.
Though Keynes' two-asset-class explanation of why interest rates
influence the demand for money is outdated by developments, his other
explanations are still sound. Money held for transactions purposes is
much like inventory which businesses hold. A rise in interest rates
will decrease the optimal amount of money as inventory, and a rise in
the cost of re-monetizing will increase the optimal amount. Modern
management has introduced just-in-time inventory which renders this
argument mute. Most chief financial officers have also perfected
just-in-time cash management schemes. The exception is that holders of
money can live on it, which is not true for holders of most other
inventories.
This new international financial architecture proposed in the Open
Letter will aim to create:
1) a new global monetary regime that operates without national currency
hegemony,
2) global trade relationships that support rather than retard domestic
development and
3) a global economic environment that provides incentives for each and
every nation to promote full employment and rising wages for its labor
force.
At that first G20 Leaders Summit hosted by out-going US President
George Bush in 2008, leaders of member sovereign states agreed to a
hastily drafted action plan based on orthodox macroeconomic doctrines
to try to stabilize the precarious global market economy and to prevent
recurrent crises in the future, resulting in the premier international
forum that acquired its current name and significance.
G20 leaders in 2008 reached general agreement on cooperation in key
areas to strengthen sustainable economic growth, and to deal with the
on-going global financial crisis that had first broken out in New York
in mid 2007. with focus on three key objectives:
1) Restoring global economic growth through globalized free trade;
2) Strengthening the international financial system of global market
capitalism;
3) Reforming supranational financial institutions to give more voice to
the emerging economy countries.
Objectives 1 and 2 were emergency Band-Aid solutions to deal with the
painful symptoms but not the dilapidating disease of dysfunctional
economic interactions that had caused the current financial crisis.
Neoliberal globalization has promoted the myth that the current terms
of international trade lead to win-win transactions for all
participating nations, based on a panglossian distortion of the
Ricardian notion of comparative advantage, win-win
transactions in international trade. In recent decades, international
trade has been conducted primarily through cross-border wage arbitrage,
driving down wages in both advanced and developing economies. Around
the world, unemployment has been the weapon of choice with which to
fight inflation induced by continuous central bank monetary easing.
Yet without global full employment with rising wages, Ricardian
comparative advantage is merely Say's Law internationalized.
Say's Law states that "supply creates its own demand", but only under
full employment, a pre-condition supply-siders conveniently ignore.
After two decades of substituting wage increases with consumer debt in
order to maximize return on capital by tilting the distributional
balance between capital and labor against labor to the benefit of
capital, and the detriment of demand, overlooking the structural
wage-price dynamics of Fordism that
built the US middle class, this win-win illusion of comparative
advantage in international trade without the prerequisite of global
full employment with rising wages has been shattered by concrete data:
relative poverty has increased worldwide and global wages, already low
to begin with, have declined since the Asian financial crisis of 1997,
and by 45% in some emerging market economies, such as that of
Indonesia. As wages failed to grow, demand was kept high by debt
unsustainable by low wages.
Under dollar hegemony, export to US markets is merely an arrangement in
which the exporting economies, in order to earn dollars to buy needed
commodities denominated in dollars and to service dollar loans
and direct investments, are forced to finance the US consumption
beyond the level supported by US wages, and by the need to invest their
trade surplus dollars in dollar assets as foreign-exchange reserves,
giving the US a rising capital account surplus to finance its rising
current account deficit.
Furthermore, the trade surpluses are achieved not by any advantage in
the terms of trade, but by sheer self-denial of basic domestic needs
and critical imports necessary for domestic development. Not only are
the exporting nations debasing the market value of their labor and the
exchange value of their currencies, degrading their environment and
depleting their natural resources for the privilege of running on the
poverty treadmill, they are enriching the dollar economy and
strengthening dollar hegemony in the process, and causing harm also to
the US economy.
Thus the exporting nations allow themselves to be robbed of needed
capital for critical domestic development in such vital areas as
education, health and other social infrastructure, by assuming heavy
debt denominated in foreign currencies to finance export, while they
beg for even more foreign investment in the export sector by offering
still more exorbitant returns, lower wages and generous tax exemptions,
putting increased social burden on the underdeveloped domestic economy.
Yet many small economies around the world have no option but to
continue to serve dollar hegemony like a drug addiction by hoping to
develop their domestic economies through export.
Japan provides clear evidence that even a dynamic, successful export
machine does not by itself produce a healthy economy. Japan is aware
that it needs to restructure its domestic economy, away from its export
fixation and upgrade the living standard of its overworked population
and to reorder its domestic consumption patterns. But Japan has been
and will continue to be trapped in helplessness by dollar hegemony.
Japan has seen its sovereign credit rating lowered by international
rating agencies while it remains the world's biggest creditor nation
unless China overtook it in that dubious honor in a few more years.
Moody's Investor Service downgraded Japanese government bonds (JGB) by
two notches in 2004 to A2, or one grade below Botswana's, not to
mention Chile and Hungary. Japan in 2004 had the world's largest
foreign-exchange reserves: $819 billion in July 2004; the world's
biggest domestic savings: $11.4 trillion (US gross domestic product was
$11 trillion in 2003); and $1 trillion in overseas investment. And 95%
of its sovereign debt is held by Japanese nationals, which rules out
risk of default similar to Argentina, or any eurozone country. Japan
has given Botswana, where half of the population is infected with the
AIDS virus, $12 million in grants and $102 million in loans.
Why do the New York-based rating agencies prefer Botswana to Japan? The
Botswana government budget is controlled by foreign diamond-mining
interests to protect their investment in the mining sector. Botswana
does not run any budget deficit to develop its domestic economy with
sovereign credit, or to help its poverty-stricken people with higher
wages because the foreign mining interests do not sell their products
inside Botswana. Thus Botswana is considered a good credit risk for
foreign loans and investment. Japan, on the other hand, is forced to
suffer the high interest cost of a low credit rating because its
responsive government attempts to solve, through deficit financing and
quantitative and qualitative easing, the nation's economic woes that
have resulted from excessive focus on export. Dollar hegemony denies a
good credit rating even to the world's largest holder of dollar
reserves.
As Fed Chairman Paul Volcker told his Japanese counterpart during the
Plaza Accord negoiations in 1985 to push the exchange rate of Japanese
yen up against the dollar to try in vain to reduce Japan's trade
surplus with the US: "The dolllar is our currency, but your problem."
It was a statement of exreme hubris and clear insight.
The Asia-Pacific trading system has been structured to serve markets
outside of Asia by providing low-wage manufacturing and extracting
natural resources at high environmental abuse to service US markets
paid in dollars. This enables the US to consume more without high
inflation and more than depressed domestic wages can afford. The bulk
of the trade surpluses accumulated by the Asian economies have ended up
financing the US debt bubble, which is not even good for the US economy
in the long run as events since mid 2007 have demonstrated.
Low-price imports made by outsourcing to low-wage economies allow the
US to keep domestic wages low without dampening consumer demand. Low
wages in the US are compensated by high consumer debt to keep demand
high.
These terms of international trade contribute to a rising disparity of
both income and wealth around the world and within the US where
purchasing power comes increasingly from debt-supported spending. High
return on capital is achieved by cross-border wage arbitrage to reward
investment offshore, while keeping domestic wages from rising. The
result is that when the equity bubble of inflated price-earning ratio
finally bursts, wages are too low to keep the economy from crashing
from a collapse of the wealth effect of the asset price bubble.
After continuously impoverishing the Asian economies by unregulated
financial manipulation of crisis proportions masked as innovative
"creative destruction", dollar hegemony now works to penetrate the
remaining Asian markets that have stayed relatively closed: notably
domestic market in Japan, China and South Korea. Control of foreign
access to its emerging markets has been Asia's principal defensive
strategy for its sub-optimized trade advantage based on low wages, high
pollution and distorted low-tech, labor-intensive industrial
development. This strategy had been practiced successfully first by
Japan and copied in various degree of success by the Asian Tigers.
Economic nationalism, which neoliberals label derogatorily as
protectionism, has been rising in many Asian economies long after
formal accession by these economies to the World Trade Organization
(WTO), particularly in the finance sector.
Once free from dollar hegemony, China will be able to finance its
domestic development without depending on foreign loans or capital. The
Chinese economy will then no longer be distorted by excessive reliance
on export merely to earn dollars that by definition must be invested in
dollar assets, not yuan assets. The more dollars the Chinese export
sector earns, the more will China become a financial colony of dollar
hegemony.
The aim of development is to raise wage levels, not to push wages down
to achieve predatory export competitiveness. Yet export under dollar
hegemony requires the export sector to keep wages low, a prerequisite
that condemns an economy to perpetual underdevelopment. Terms such as
“openness” need to be reconsidered away from the distorted meanings
assigned to them by neoliberal cultural hegemony. The contradiction
between globalizing and territory-based national social and political
forces is framed in the context of past, present and future world
orders.
Globalization is not a new trend. It is the natural policy for all
empire building. Globalization under modern capitalism began with the
British Empire, marked by the repeal of the Corn Laws in 1846, five
years after Britain's Opium War with China, and two years before the
Revolutions of 1848.
Great Britain embarked on a systemic promotion of free trade beginning
around the mid 19th century and chose to depend on imported food to
free up resources and energy for international trade. This national
choice provided a survivalist justification to economic empire.
France adopted free trade in 1860 and within 10 years was faced with
the revolutionary Paris Commune, which was suppressed ruthlessly by the
French bourgeoisie, who put to death 20,000 workers and peasants,
including children.
Despite a backlash movement toward protective tariffs in Britain,
Holland and Belgium, the global economy of the 19th century was
characterized by high mobility of goods across political borders. As
Europe adopted political nationalism, international economic liberalism
developed in parallel, until 1914. World War I, the 1929 Depression and
World War II caused a temporary halt of free trade.
The US “Open Door” policy for pre-revolutionary China, proclaimed by
John Hay in 1899, was part of a globalization scheme to preserve US
commercial interests by preventing the partition of China into spheres
of influence by European powers and Japan, after the US became a
late-comer Far Eastern power through the acquisition of the Philippines
after the Spanish-American War in the 1898 Treaty of Paris. The Open
Door policy was rooted in the "most-favored-nation" clause in the
unequal treaties imposed on China by Western imperialist powers.
Like the United States now, Britain, the predominant economic power in
the 19th century, was a predominantly importing economy by the close of
the 18th century. Despite the Industrial Revolution’s expanded export
of manufacturing goods, British import of raw material, food and
consumer amenities grew faster in value than export of manufacturing
goods and coal. The key factor that sustained this trade imbalance was
the predominance of the British pound, as it is today with the US
dollar and its effect on trade finance.
British hegemony of sea transportation and financial services
(cross-currency trade finance and insurance) earned Britain vast
amounts of foreign currencies that could be sold in the London money
markets to importers of Argentine meat, Canadian bacon and Chinese tea
and silk. International credit and capital markets were centered in
London. British export of financial services and capital produced
factor income that served as hidden surplus to cushion the trade
deficit. To enhance financial hegemony, the British maintain separate
dependent currencies in all parts of the empire under pound-sterling
hegemony. Currencies of the colonies were pegged to the pound-sterling
at fixed exchange rates, depriving the colonies of the prerogative of
sovereign credit.
This financial hegemony is now centered on New York with the dollar as
the reserve currency. When the Asian tigers export to the United
States, all they get in return are US Treasury bills and corporate
bonds, not money they can spend in their domestic economy. Asian labor
in fact is working at low wages, the "surplus value" of which go mainly
to finance the expansion of the global dollar economy, not their own
domestic economies.
Market fundamentalism, a modern euphemism of capitalism, is thus made
necessary by the finance architecture imposed on the world by the
hegemonic financial power, first 19th-century Great Britain, now the
United States.
When the developing economies call for a new international finance
architecture, this is what they are really driving at. Foreign-exchange
markets ensure that the endless demand for dollar capital by the poor
exporting nations will never be fully met. British economist John A
Hobson identified the surplus of capital in the core economies and the
need for its export to the impoverished parts of the world as the
material basis of imperialism. For neo-imperialism of the 21st
century, this remains fundamentally true.
Then as now, the international economy rested on an international money
system. Britain adopted the gold standard in 1816, with Europe and the
US following in the 1870s. Until 1914, the exchange rates of most
currencies were highly stable, except in victimized, semi-colonial
economies such as Turkey and China. The gold standard, while greatly
facilitating free trade, was hard on economies that produced no gold,
and the gold-based monetary regime was generally deflationary (until
the discovery of new gold deposits in South Africa, California and
Alaska), which favored capital. William Jenning Bryan spoke for the
world in 1896 when he declared that mankind should not be "crucified
upon this cross of gold". But the 50-year lead time of the British gold
standard firmly established London as the world's financial center. The
world's capital was drawn to London to be redistributed to investments
of the highest return around the world. Borrowers around the world were
reduced to playing a game of "race to the bottom" to compete for
capital.
The bulk of economic theoretical doctrines within the philosophical
context of capitalism were invented to rationalize this exploitative
global system as natural scientific truth. The fundamental shift from
the labor value theory to the marginal utility theory was a circular
self-validation of the artificial characteristics of an artificial
construct based on the sanctity of capital, despite Karl Marx's
dissection that capital cannot exist without labor - until assets are
put to use to increase labor productivity, it remains idle assets.
Mergers and acquisitions became rampant. Small business capitalism
disappeared between 1880 and 1890. Workers and small businesses found
that they were not competing against their neighbors, but those on
other side of the world, operating from structurally different
socio-economic systems. The corporation, first used to facilitate the
private ownership of large undertaking such as railroads, became the
organization of choice for large industries and commerce, issuing
stocks and bonds to finance its undertakings that fell beyond the
normal financial resources of individual entrepreneurs.
This process increased the power of banks and other financial
institutions and brought forth finance capitalism as the new core of
the economy. Cartels and trusts emerged, using vertical and horizontal
integration to eliminate competition and to manipulate markets and
prices for entire sectors of the economy.
Middle-class membership was mainly concentrated in salaried management
workers of corporations, while working class members were hourly wage
earners in factories. The 1848 Revolutions were the first proletariat
revolutions in modern time. This was the time when Marx and Engle wrote
the Communist Manifesto. The creation of an integrated world market,
the financing and development of economies outside of Europe and the
rising standards of living for Europeans were triumphs of the
19th-century system of unregulated capitalism. In the 20th century, the
process continued, with the center shifting to the US after two world
wars.
Friedrich List, in his National System of Political Economy (1841),
asserted that political economy as espoused in England at that time,
far from being a valid science universally, was merely British national
opinion, suited only to English historical conditions. List’s
institutional school of economics asserted that the doctrine of free
trade was devised to keep England rich and powerful at the expense of
its trading partners and that it had to be fought with protective
tariffs and other devices of economic nationalism by the weaker
countries. List’s economic nationalism influenced Asian leaders,
including Sun Yatsen of China, who proposed industrial policies
financed with sovereign credit. List was also the influence behind the
Meiji Reform Movement of 1868 in Japan. Alexander Hamilton, by
proposing the US Treasury using tax revenue to assume and pay off all
public debts incurred by the Confederation in his 1791 Report on Public
Debt, through the establishment of a national bank, provided the new
nation with sovereign credit in the form of paper money for development.
The current breakdown of neoliberal globalized market fundamentalism
offers Asia a timely opportunity to forge a fairer deal in its economic
relation with the rest of the world. The United States, as a bicoastal
nation, must begin to treat Asian-Pacific nations as equal members of
an Asian-Pacific commonwealth in a new world economic order that
renders economic nationalism unnecessary.
China, as the largest economy in the Asia-Pacific region, and
potentially the largest in the world, has a key role to play in shaping
this new world economic order. To do that, China must look beyond its
current myopic effort to join a collapsing global export market economy
and provide a model of national development in which foreign trade is
reassigned to its proper place in the economy from its current
all-consuming priority. The first step in that direction is for China
to free itself from dollar hegemony and embark on a domestic
development program with sovereign credit.
Yet neoliberals policy makers in developing economies continue to
ignore the insights of Friedrich List on the limitation of
international trade as a venue for national development, thus denying
their domestic economy the benefits of using sovereign credit instead
of foreign capital. (Please see my September 2004 series: Liberating Sovereign Credit
for Domestic Development - written three years before
the global market meltdown in July 2007)
Ooctober 20, 2013
Next: G20 as the Prime Forum for International Cooperation
|
|
|
|