|
The Eurozone Sovereign Debt
Crisis
By
Henry C.K. Liu
Part I: The Eurozone Sovereign
Debt
Crisis
Part II: The Role of the
IMF/ECB/EC Troika
Part III: Supranational
Globalization vs Nation State Sovereignty
Part IV: Need
for an
Orderly Withdrawal Mechanism from the Euro and the Eurozone
Part V: EU Treaty
Reform
The conditional agreement reached by Germany
and France
on Monday, December 5, 2011
on reform of
the Lisbon Treaty of late 2009 that governs the constitutional basis of
the
European Union (EU) was hailed as good news in the press which had been
desperately waiting for positive news. The agreement proposes changing
the
inter-government structure of the Lisbon Treaty toward supranationalism
that
diminishes the national sovereign authority of member states in the
union on
the issue of fiscal policy.
If the German-Franco proposal of treaty reform is accepted
without changes by all the other 25 sovereign governments of the
27-member
European Union (EU), whose support is needed to modify the Lisbon
Treaty that
had entered into force on December
1, 2009, the supranational European Commission (Ecom) would be
given new
powers to impose fiscal austerity measures on 17 eurozone member states
and
also all those non-euro in the EU that deviate from the fiscal
criteria set by
the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP).
The SGP had been introduced in 1997 as a Protocol of the
Maastricht Treaty of 1992 to preempt subsequent need of fiscally
undisciplined
eurozone sovereign states for bailouts by supranational EU facilities
in the
framework of intergovernment agreement.
Giving the supranational Ecom power to impose fiscal regimes on
eurozone member
states in financial difficulty will dilute the target countries’
national
sovereignty over fiscal policy.
Germany and France Were First to Breach SGP Criteria to Stimulate Growth
The irony is that by 2003, three years after the euro became
common currency for the 17 countries in the eurozone, Germany
and France,
the
two largest economies, had been the first countries in the eurozone to
violate
SGP criteria. Germany
had been insisting on reforming SGP criteria to ease limits on national
fiscal
policy in the eurozone and the EU.
The reason many eurozone governments readily supported the
German request for less strict fiscal limits was understandable: SGP
criteria
depressed growth; and fiscal prudence would cause European economies to
fall
behind those in the US,
UK
and Japan,
not to mention the BRIC (Brazil, Russia, India, China) economies which
had been growing at 10%
annually. Such
growth could only come from government deficit spending to stimulate
the
economy by accumulating more sovereign debt. And expansion of sovereign
debt
from deficit spending would be benign because the GDP would grow to
keep the
ratio of sovereign debt to GDP constant.
Germany and France Lobbied for SGP Reform in 2005
With several eurozone national economies failing
to keep
to SGP criteria in the initial years after the limits came into force
in 1997, Germany
and France
lobbied for SGP reform in 2005 to allow eurozone member states more
flexibility
needed for counter-cyclical fiscal policy. Given the relatively poor
record in economic
performance of the eurozone’s centralized monetary policy, the failure
of the
original rigid SGP criteria to simulate growth attracted broad
criticism. There
was much sympathy to the German-Franco view of the need to reform the
SGP.
The Maastricht Treaty of 1992 set mandatory centralized
monetary and fiscal rules for member states of the Economic and
Monetary Union
(EMU): low inflation, low interest rates and controlled public debt and
government
spending, notwithstanding that many elements of these criteria
contradict one
another, such as low interest rates and low inflation, as a matter of
economic
logic.
The SGP, agreed to in 1997, required uniform fiscal rules be
applied along with the launching of the euro as a common currency for
eurozone
economies on January 1, 1999.
All EU member governments have since been required to keep within SGP
criteria: fiscal deficit not over 3% of GDP,
public debt not over 60% of GDP and inflation rate of not more than 1.5
percentage points higher than the average of
the three best performing (lowest inflation) member states of the EU.
For non-euro EU member states such as Britain,
SGP criteria also applied but their governments were not subject to SGP
penalties.
Since 1999, the only SGP criteria that eurozone governments managed to
meet was
keeping inflation rate low and this achievement was made possible by
recession
rather than government policy.
How SGP Works
The original SGP required all countries in the eurozone to
aim at keeping their annual budget deficit below
3% of GDP, total public debt below 60% of GDP
and inflation rate of not more than 1.5
percentage points higher than the average of the three best performing
(lowest
inflation) member states of the EU. If a member state broke the
rules, it
had to take measures to restore good standing by reducing its fiscal
deficit,
paying down it sovereign debt and reducing domestic inflation, albeit
that the
problem of how to fight inflation without monetary authority to raise
interest
rates was left unspecified. If a member government broke SGP rules in
three
consecutive years, the Ecom could impose a fine of up to 0.5% of GDP.
The SGP was not effective in preventing eurozone government
deficits from exceeding the 3% of GDP threshold. By
2003 France,
Germany,
Italy,
Portugal,
and Greece
had all violated SGP criteria, and the Netherlands
joined the list by 2004.
European Council
Modified SGP Criteria
In March 2005, at the urging of Germany
and France,
the
European Council agreed to reform SGP criteria. On the surface, the
reform kept
unchanged the key quantitative criteria on fiscal deficits, sovereign
debt and
low inflation, but the small print of the reform contained a list of
exemptions
for types of spending that would not be counted as part of the fiscal
deficit
or public debt. This list included government spending on education,
research,
defense, aid and spending associated with ‘the unification of Europe’.
However, the reforms of 2005 have been criticized and at the height of
the
global financial crisis in 2008 and during the ensuing recession, there
were
calls for the EU to do more to penalize states with fiscal deficits
that could
not be sustained by government revenue in the long run.
All Eurozone
Governments violated SGP Criteria by 2006
In 2006, at the height of world-wide
credit
bubble, a year before the global financial
crisis began in New
York in mid July 2007, Germany’s
sovereign debt reached 66.8% of GDP and Greece’s
was over 100%. In 2010, Germany’s sovereign debt reached over 78%;
Greece’s reached
over 120%, and France’s sovereign debt
reached over 80.3% of GDP, its highest ever level since the beginning
of the
euro regime in 1999. Sovereign debt of eurozone governments continued
to rise
until the crisis hit in 2008.
Arguments For SGP and Reform
The arguments for
keeping the SGP and reforming it are many. SGP helps eurozone
countries commit
to the common currency and to keep the euro as a strong currency. The
exemptions proposed in 2005 by Germany and France
would make SGP criteria more flexible and allow member governments to
adopt counter-cyclical deficit spending as stimulant for continuing
economic
growth.
SGP relieves cyclical political pressure on politicians and can
be a technical shield against domestic political attacks to allow them
to adopt
long-term policies of stability and sustainable growth with less
short-term political cost.
Augments Against SGP
While the initial SGP criteria were too rigid, the reformed version
has so many exemptions that it is in fact difficult for member
governments
to breach the new criteria. By failing
to impose penalties on Germany
and France
for
violating SGP criteria since 2005, the European Commission has shown
that there
are no
unbreakable SGP rules on government fiscal deficits or sovereign debt
in the eurozone.
The reformed criteria do not provide real solutions on
counter-cyclical fiscal
needs, and they encourage creative accounting through the use of
special
purpose vehicles to hide true levels of sovereign debt. The new
criteria also
fail to allow for deficit capital spending with a balanced current
account.
When government budget promises disbursements that regularly
exceed its tax receipts even in the boom phase of a business cycle fuel
by
debt, then the government, even under normal circumstances, will incur
a budget
deficit that will accumulate more sovereign debt that will implode in
the next
down phase in the cycle.
Europe’s
Fiscal Deficit Bias
A fiscal deficit bias has structural in European government finance
since the mid-1970s when fiscal deficit levels for most European
countries began
to grow. The fiscal deficit bias was due to ineffective and
insufficient
revenue collection in balance with high government obligation
that has become a permanent
feature of European democratic politics.
Most European tax regimes have a narrow tax base constructed on a
historical principle of using taxation as a means of equalizing income
and
wealth.
There are relatively few people who pay taxes because taxable income
threshold
is set too high, and tax exemptions are too liberal. The middle class
whose
members pay taxes demand their tax money be spent on social services on
and
subsidies for them. The average tax payer gets more social services
and benefits than their
tax payments could buy.
Most European tax regimes have very high graduated marginal
tax rates (the tax rate increases with increased income or profit),
leaving
high tax bills for those with high income or profit. This tends to
lower total tax
collection because of a marginal disincentive to maximize income from
work,
and to
encourage pervasive tax avoidance and even evasion. In order to avoid
paying
high taxes, many taxpayers devote enormous time and energy to hiding
their
taxable income from tax collectors,
raising the tax burden of those who actually pay. High income taxpayers
routinely seek cross-border tax arbitrage to relocate income and assets
to
lower tax locations.
Europe’s
Long History of Moving Toward Equality
Reversed
Also, Europe has a long history of government spending on
welfare state obligations and equalitarian wealth redistribution. In
contrast
to the US,
many
European nations over the course of their history of moving from
feudalism to
capitalism have
been moving from extreme disparity of income and wealth toward equality
until
recent recent decades during which disparity of income and wealth was
allowed
to increased in the name of competitiveness in global markets.
US Founding Principle of Equality Reversed
In contrast, equality of income and wealth had been a
founding democratic principle of the US, yet over history, disparity of
income
and wealth had gradually been allowed to increase after special
interest groups
captured government through the peculiar politics of representative
democracy
in a costly electoral process that favors the rich despite repeated
populist
upsurges
against excessive disparity of income and wealth after every recurring
financial crisis, the burden for which invariably was placed
predominantly on
the backs of the poor and the middle class. (Please see my articles in
the
March 2008 series: US Populism: Part I: The
Legacy of Free Market Capitalism
and Part II: Long-term Effect of
the Civil War)
Domestic Social Programs
Challenged by the Need for National Competitiveness
Most European countries provide free public health care
services to their citizens covering basic medical needs while the US,
the
richest nation in the world, continue to debate about the validity of
universal
health care insurance and to celebrate the merits of private education
under
the hypercritical banner of individual freedom of choice.
Most European governments own and operate large companies in
key sectors that have been nationalized to save them from bankruptcy
and to
keep
them afloat with heavy government subsidies. In many European
economies,
the
government heavily subsidizes key industries, specifically agriculture,
and
provide very liberal unemployment assistance and social security
benefits for
their citizens. And because of global cross-border wage arbitrage
having pushed
down wages in most economies engaged in world trade, many workers in Europe
have been pushed into government welfare trap to compensate for the
disappearance of living wages, similar to other parts of the worlds
except that
in Europe, welfare programs ae generally more
liberal
that adds to government fiscal imbalance.
SGP Intended for Preventing
Moral Hazard from Infesting Governments
Legislation that limits the size government fiscal deficits
to 3% of GDP in countries in the European Monetary Union (EMU) was put
in place
by the Maastricht Treaty of 1992 to prevent fiscal
moral hazard from infecting member
governments in the monetary
union, as well as to enforce monetary stability and to reduce the
deficit
bias.
If a eurozone member government violates the deficit to GDP ratio put
in place
by the SGP, it could face a series of fines from the supranational
European
Commission (Ecom) based on inter-government agreement. Under intense
pressure
from the offending member states, led by Germany
and France,
SGP
penalties were suspended in 2003 and no fines were issued since for
excessive
deficits. SGP then became a watchdog with no teeth.
In 2005 a reformed SGP
was adopted with new
criteria that allowed fiscal deficits to be temporarily larger than the
3% of
GDP deficit threshold calculated on an annual basis as long as medium
term
average stays within the 3% limit. The focus of SGP then turned toward
medium-term budgetary objectives.
Fiscal Deficit Made Structurally
Necessary by Loss of Sovereignty Over Monetary Policy
Fiscal deficit has been identified as one of the main causes
of and its elimination as one of the main solutions to the European
sovereign debt crisis
denominate in a
common currency the monetary policy of which has been voluntarily
surrendered
by eurozone sovereign states to the supranational European Central
Bank (ECB).
This means the fiscal discipline of eurozone governments on which the
soundness
of the common currency depends, must also be imposed by a supranational
authority. This is the logic of the German push for supranational
authority over eurozone and even EU member states.
Germany and Britain Battle Over Free Financial Markets in the EU
The fiscal problem created by the centralized monetary
policy of a common currency has led Germany to demand supranational
authority
over not only fiscal discipline for eurozone member states but also
over the
non-euro member states of the EU to replace the inter-government
structure of
the SGP with a supranational authority, in order to eliminate structural competitive disadvantage in the same single
market between economies with fiscal flexibility disparity. This is the
main
conflict between Germany
and the UK,
in
that German economic and financial competitiveness would face a
structural
disadvantage if German fiscal flexibility is more rigid than that of
the UK.
It is the main reason behind the UK
veto on the German proposal on treaty reform.
The treaty reform proposal by Germany
is by design a serious challenge to national sovereignty of EU member
states in
that it seeks to deprive governments of sovereign countries of their
fiscal
policy independence and prerogative. And
for Britain,
the loss of full sovereignty over fiscal policy and over associated
liberal
regulatory regime in the UK
financial sector would threaten the supremacy of the City in London
as a world financial center. If traders in the City are forbidden by
supranational EU treaty laws to speculate on European sovereign debt to
assert
market discipline on the global sovereign debt sector, including that
of the
eurozone, the investment banking firms in the City would have to
down size drastically,
and the loss of tax revenue from it would cause fiscal problem for the
British
government.
Contagion Hitting Strong
Core Economies in Eurozone
The countries that would have been affected immediately by
treaty reform are in the periphery of the eurozone, such Greece,
Ireland
and Portugal,
the so-called Club Med economies that are facing fiscal regimes of
extreme
austerity imposed by the governments of the stronger economies in the
EU, the
ECB and the IMF. Yet several core economies, such as those of Italy,
Spain
and France,
and in a worst case scenario, even Germany
could be in theory exposed to the same risk of impaired sovereignty, as
will
the 10 non-euro countries in the EU.
Different National
Reasons Behind SGP Violations
After the launch of the euro in 1999, different countries in
the eurozone for different national reasons had difficulty meeting the
SGP criteria.
For the weak economies, for whose economy the euro was an overvalued
currency,
government fiscal deficit beyond the SGP limit of 3% of GDP was needed
to
augment their stagnant economies suffering from a dysfunctional
overvalued
common currency.
At the same time, in the current world economic order of
neoliberal globalized trade, growth could be stimulated only with sharp
increases in the level of sovereign debt beyond the SGP limit of 60% of
GDP.
The current globalized neoliberal trade system requires trade
competitiveness
to be at the expense of domestic economic development through rising
wage
income. For the weak economies with below par domestic development, the
excessive reliance on international trade as the sole venue of growth,
denominated in an overvalued currency over which their governments
cannot
control, is particularly damaging. Much
of the socioeconomic problems faced by emerging economies, including China,
can be traced a low wages in the export sector to keep it
“competitive”. (Please
see my September 2004 article: Liberating
Sovereign Credit for Domestic Development)
SGP Criteria Hamper
Trade Competitiveness
Before the global financial crisis hit Europe,
even with SGP criteria violations, sovereign debt of even the weak
economies in
the eurozone found ready buyers in global credit markets due to high
investor
confidence in the euro as a eurozone common currency, which compensated
for
weakness in the national economies of several eurozone sovereign
borrowers.
Investors assumed that eurozone sovereign debt denominated in euro
would
ultimately be backed by the full faith and credit of the eurozone and
all
eurozone governments to protect the soundness of the euro as a common
currency.
Credit rating for the weak eurozone economies was lifted by the high
credit
ratings of the strong eurozone economies through the market's faith in
the
common currency. For many years, the
weak economies were getting a free ride on the credit ratings of the
strong
economies through their common currency.
SGP Criteria Hamper Domestic
Growth
For the strong economies, such as Germany
and France,
SGP
criteria handicapped their competitiveness in global financial markets
against
countries such as Britain,
the US
and Japan,
and even the BRIC economies, all with more flexible fiscal policies
than those
set by the SGP. The petition to the European
Council to
relax the way SGP criteria are measured focused on compliance within a
long
wave rather than annually to allow eurozone governments the important
and
necessary option of using fiscal measures to optimized long-term growth.
Supranational
Institutions of the EU
The European Council (ECoun) is the the EU institution where
the member states government representatives sit, i.e. the ministers of
each
member state with responsibility for a given area. When the Lisbon
Treaty came
in to force on December 1,
2009,
the ECoun became an
institution of the European Union although
its existence predates that of the EU. ECoun comprises the heads of
state or government
of EU member states, along with the President of the European
Commission
(Ecom), and the President of the European Council (ECoun).
Germany and France Ignored SGP Criteria by Policy
In 2003, the two largest economies in the eurozone, France
and Germany,
purposely
exceeded SGP criteria as a matter of policy to compensate for monetary
restriction
associated with a centralized monetary regime of a common currency. It
is a
rational hydraulics of economic policy that given a rigid monetary
policy,
fiscal policy must compensate to protect the economy from stagnation.
European Commission
Tolerance of German and French Violation of SGP
However, since the two countries with the largest economies
in the eurozone could be expected to be able to maintain SGP fiscal
targets on
average over the long term beyond cyclical fluctuations, the European
Commission
(Ecom) allowed them counter-cyclical fiscal flexibility to enhance
their
competitiveness in global financial markets. And in so doing, all other
eurozone
countries also must be allowed similar
flexibility as required by treaty.
But no danger was perceived as the two largest economies
were expected to keep the eurozone economy healthy enough to absorb the
fiscal
problems of the small economies to allow them to correct them at a pace
that
would not create political or social instability.
Strategy of Fiscal
Flexibility Made Inoperative by US Subprime Mortgage Crisis
Tolerance for the the strong eurozone economies to adopt
flexible fiscal standards was a reasonable strategy and was in fact the
key
advantage of a common currency. What eurozone policy-makers did not
foresee,
was the financial tsunami from across the Atlantic
epicenter in New York
that
rendered the eurozone strategy of growth through debt inoperative.
Supranational
Organization of the EU
The European Commission (Ecom) includes the institution
itself and the College of Commissioners,
which is composed of one commissioner from each of the 27 EU countries.
The
Ecom is the “guardian of the treaties” that created the European Union
and the
defender of the general interest of Europe,
with the
right of initiative in the lawmaking process to propose legislative
acts for
the European Parliament and the Council of the European Union to adopt.
The Council of the
European Union
(sometimes simply called the Council
and sometimes still referred to as the Council
of Ministers) is the institution in the legislature of the
European
Union (EU) representing the executives of member states, the other
legislative
body being the European Parliament. The Council is composed of 27
national
ministers (one per nation state). The exact membership depends upon the
topic;
for example, when discussing agricultural policy the Council is formed
by the 27
national ministers whose portfolio includes this policy area (with the
related
European Commissioner contributing but not voting).
The Presidency of
the Council rotates every six months between the governments of EU
member
states, with the relevant minister of the respective country holding
the
Presidency at any given time ensuring the smooth running of the
meetings and
setting the daily agenda. The continuity between presidencies is
provided by an
arrangement under which three successive presidencies, known as Presidency
trios, share common political programs.
SGP regulators underestimated the problem in a centralized
fiscal regime for a eurozone comprising different national economies:
that what
is good for the goose is not necessarily good for the gender. The SGP’s
one-size-fits-all criteria designed for the benefit of strong economies
are not
operational for the weak economies.
Effect of SGP
Criteria Modification on Weak Economies in Eurozone Periphery
The result of the German-Franco SGP criteria modification in
2003 was that weak economies such as Greece
and Portugal
were able to take on high levels of sovereign debt denominated in a
stable euro
as a common currency in excess of the ability of their economies to
assume even
in the boom phases of business cycles.
Eurozone economies were made to appear robust from the
benefits of a stable common currency while in reality these economies
were only
turbo-charged temporarily by unsustainable levels of sovereign debt
denominated
in a common currency the strength of which was derived not from the
strength of
the individual national economies of the sovereign borrowers but from
the
strength of eurozone economy as a whole.
And the euro is a currency over which these countries with
weak economies have no monetary authority. Under the common currency
regime,
the free spending profligate governments were getting a free ride on
the backs
of the fiscally prudent governments to sustain the soundness of the
common
currency, albeit the ability to get the free ride had been handed to
the
weak
economies by none other than Germany
and France,
the
two strongest economies in the eurozone, for their own geo-economic
reasons of
increasing their own competitiveness in global financial markets.
Further, the emergence of globalized structured finance
(securitization of debt which is hedged with derivatives) since the
late 1990s,
coupled with faulty financial advice from the likes of Goldman Sachs on
creative ways to exploit globalized finance deregulation regimes,
enabled
governments of weak economies to take on high levels of sovereign debt
in
Special Purpose Vehicles (SPV) designed to hide liability from the
balance
sheets of their central banks and treasuries in order to float more
sovereign
debt in global credit markets and to draw loans from the European
Central Bank
(ECB).
The lax in supervision and enforcement of modified SGP criteria
greatly weakened the effectiveness of the SGP as a
supervisory-disciplanary
body on national fiscal integrity in the eurozone.
In March 2005, the European Council (ECoun) agreed on a
reformed SGP that legalized fiscal violations by introducing new
flexible rules
and liberal definition of terms. Even these reforms were further
challenged as
too strict in August 2007 by France
when President Nicholas Sarkozy wanted to introduce new fiscal policies
of
deficit financing outside the SGP regime to ward off the effects of
contagion
on the French economy from the global consequences of the credit
crisis that
began in New York in
Mid July.
US Urged Europe to Adopt Emergency Proactive Fiscal Deficit Policies in 2008
By 2008, urged by US political leaders and finance officials
fearful of worldwide depression from the market meltdown that began in
New
York, EU member states had all adopted proactive fiscal deficit
stimulant
measures that violated SGP criteria in a frantic effort to deal with
the global
financial crisis caused by the bursting of the US
debt bubble of runaway subprime home mortgages, and to following the US
approach of emergency monetary and fiscal rescue measures to reverse a
sudden
and near fatal meltdown of global financial markets.
European Commission
Warning on Eurozone Public Debt
In 2010, the European Commission (Ecom) warned that average
public debt in the eurozone was approaching 84% of GDP and rising
further by
the month, breaching the 60% limit set by the SGP. The public debt
growth trend
was exacerbated by GDP shrinkage in the eurozone, pushing up the debt
to GDP
ratio sharply. The Ecom was particularly worried about levels of public
debt in Portugal,
Ireland,
Italy,
Greece,
and Spain,
the
so-called PIIGS, and even France.
The Crisis in Greece
But Greece’s
spiraling public debt presented the gravest immediate concern as
short-term
maturity dates of Greek government bonds were coming due at a time when
the
Greek government was having serious difficulties rolling them over or
selling
new bonds to retire maturing ones. And the Greek government has no
euros in
reserve to avoid defaulting the maturing bonds.
The Greek sovereign debt difficulties quickly affected
market confidence in the euro, leading to market speculation on the
ability of
the common currency to survive without massive intervention from EU
governments.
The strategy of carrying high levels of sovereign debt with high growth
suddenly became utopian, as the market could not see any prospect of a
short
recession. The eurozone was faced with a financial fire in Greece
that could jeopardize the stability of the euro and even the eurozone
without
an effective firewall or fire trucks to extinguish the financial fire
with
fresh euros.
Marcus Walker of the Wall Street Journal reported from Heraklio,
Greece
that two years
into the European sovereign debt crisis, suicides among the Greek
people
increased by 40% in the first five months of 2011 over same period in
2010,
doubling to 6 per 100,000 persons, according to the Health Ministry of
Greece.
While the bailout funds Greece
had received to date have gone to enabling the government to pay the
foreign
creditor banks, the Greek people had to pay for it with severe and
open-ended
austerity. Greek GDP in Q2 2011 was down 7% form a year before, amid
government
spending cuts and tax increases that equaled 20%% of GDP. Unemployment
reaches
16%, crime, homelessness, emigration and personal bankruptcy are on the
rise.
The decline in GDP increased the debt to GDP ration, making
Greek sovereign debt credit rating fall further. The
Greek people are paying for the failure
of the grand plan to unite Europe through a
common
currency called the euro.
The downward spiral of the economies in the eurozone,
particularly that of Greece,
is not expected to reverse anytime soon. The Greek people simply cannot
and
will not silently suffer the rising financial pain for a decade or more
that is
generally expected before the Greek economy can complete the process of
de-leveraging from debt capitalism before life can return to normal to
the way
it was before the crisis. Both Greece
and Italy
are
now run by technocrats appointed for their technical skill to appease
foreign
creditor banks rather than elected by the people who have confidence in
their
ability to protect the people's interest. These technocrats while
applauded by
foreign creditor banks, command no loyalty from those they have been
appointed
to govern.
The Legal Concept of
Lender Liability
Its time for the people of Greece
to demand the passage of a law based on the legal concept of lender
liability
that applies to the multinational banks that lent Greece more money
than the
country could possible afford.
I have proposed that highly indebted countries (HIC) in the Third
World should apply the legal concept of lender liability to
their
predatory bank lenders who pushed big loan denominated in petro-dollars
on
developing Third World governments whose
economies were obvious unable to afford or
absorb them.
The concept should also be applied to the US
home mortgage crisis ((Please see my September 14, 2002 article: Perils
of a Debt-Propelled Economy)
Ron Paul, the Republican congressman from Texas,
and now a presidential candidate, told Federal Reserve chairman Ben
Bernanke in
a congressional hearing hearing that the Federal Reserve is operating
as a
“predatory lender”. But he did not mention that by law, predatory
lenders
forfeit any right of collection.
In the United States,
although predatory lending is not defined by federal law, and various
states
define abusive lending differently, predatory lending usually involves
practices that strip equity away from a home-owing borrower, or equity
from a
corporate borrower, or that condemn the debtor into perpetual
indenture.
Predatory or abusive lending practices can include making a loan to a
borrower
without regard to the borrower's ability to repay, repeatedly
refinancing a
loan within a short period of time and charging high points and fees
with each
refinance, charging excessive rates and fees to a borrower who
qualifies for
lower rates and/or fees offered by the lender, or imposing new
unjustifiably
harsh terms for rolling over existing debt.
Perdition breaks the links between an economy's aggregate resource
endowment
and aggregate consumption and between the interpersonal distribution of
endowments and the interpersonal distribution of consumption.
The choice by some to be predators decreases aggregate consumption,
both
because the predators' resources are wasted and because producers
sacrifice
production by allocating resources to guarding against predators. Much
of
welfare economics is based on the concept of pareto optimum,
which
asserts that resources are optimally distributed when an individual
cannot move
into a better position without putting someone else into a worse
position. In
an unjust global society, the pareto optimum will perpetuate
injustice.
Why is the legal concept of lender liability not applied to stop
foreclosure of
homes with young children? In the US,
lender liability is embodied in common and statutory law covering a
broad
spectrum of claims surrounding predatory lending. If a lender knowingly
lends
to a borrower who is obviously unable to make reasonable beneficial
gain from
the use of the funds, or causes the borrower to assume responsibilities
that
are obviously beyond the borrower's capacity to manage, the lender not
only
risks losing the loan without recourse, but is also liable for the
financial
damage to the borrower caused by such loans.
For example, if a bank lends to a trust client who is a minor, or
someone who
had no business experience, to start a risky business that resulted in
the loss
not only of the loan but also the client trust account, the bank may
well be
required by the court to make whole the client.
The argument for home mortgage debt forgiveness contains large measures
of
concepts of lender liability and predatory lending. Debt securitization
allows
predatory bankers to pass the risk to global credit markets,
socializing the
potential damage after skimming off the privatized profits.
The housing bubble has been created largely by predatory lending
without any
lender liability. The argument for forgiving defaulted home mortgage
debt is applicable
to low- and moderate-income home mortgage borrowers in the US
as well.
Lender liability is embodied in common and statutory law
covering a broad spectrum of claims surrounding predatory lending. It
is a key
concept in environmental cleanup litigation.
Now, there is also a close parallel in most Third World sovereign debts
and
International Monetary Fund (IMF) rescue packages to the above
perdition
examples where sophisticated international bankers knowingly lend to
dubious
schemes in developing economies merely to get their fees and high
interest,
knowing that “countries don’t go bankrupt”, as Walter Wriston of
Citibank
famously proclaimed to rationalize his aggressive lending of petrol
dollars to
Third World economies. The argument for Third World
debt
forgiveness contains large measures of lender liability and predatory
lending.
Debt securitization allows these bankers to pass the risk to the credit
markets, socializing the potential damage after skimming off the
privatized
profits.
Paying Down Debt with
Debt is Just a Ponzi Scheme
Credit is reserved financial resources ready for deployment. Debt
basically is
unearned money secured with a promise to repay the principal sum plus
interest
with optimistically anticipated earned money in the future, assuming,
for
example, that the borrower will not become unemployed through no fault
of his
own or a business will not be adversely affect by unanticipated shifts
in
business paradigm, or an economy will not be destroyed by global
financial
contagion.
Paying down debt with new debt is a Ponzi scheme - the likelihood of
its
exposure is inversely proportional to its scale of operation. More and
more
critics are calling the Enron debacle a Ponzi scheme, in that the
company filed
for bankruptcy even though, for almost a decade up to a few weeks
before its
bankruptcy filing, many in high places were hailing Enron as the new
innovative
business model.
Krugman’s Enron “Love
Letter to Free Markets”
Neoliberal economist Paul Krugman publicly hailed Enron as a shining
example of
free market entrepreneurship in what he called "a love letter to free
markets". He served on its prestigious advisory board for a annual fee
of
US$50,000. Neoconservative Weekly Standard editor Bill Kristol received
$100,000
from the same Enron advisory board, while contributing editor Irwin
Stelzer
praised Enron for “leading the fight for competition”.
Greenspan Won the
Enron Prize Weeks before Eron Filed Bankruptcy Protection
On November 13, 2001, two weeks before Enron filed bankruptcy on
December 2,
the Baker Institute honored Alan Greenspan, Chairman of the Federal
Reserve
Board of Governors, with its Enron Prize, which the official press
release said
“gives recognition to outstanding individuals for their contributions
to public
service. The prize is made possible by a generous gift from the Enron
Corp ...
one of the world's leading electricity, natural-gas and communications
companies. Among the previous recipients of the Enron Prize are Colin
Powell,
current US
secretary of state; Mikhail Gorbachev, former president of the Soviet
Union; Nelson Mandela, the first black president of South
Africa; and Georgian President Eduard
Shevardnadze.”
Emergency EU Summit
of 2010
At an emergency EU Summit in February 2010, EU leaders pledged
firm commitment to maintaining the soundness of the euro as a common
currency
for the eurozone. It became evident that despite government promise of
tough
austerity fiscal measures that already caused social unrest and violent
demonstations, Greece
would need much stronger financial backing from the EU to avoid
imminent
sovereign default on some of its maturing debt.
Creation of ESM and
EFSF
On May 2, 2010,
eurozone member states and the International Monetary Fund (IMF)
announced
their agreement to create a European Stabilization Mechanism (ESM) –
that would
operated a fund to be known as the European Finance Stability Fund
(EFSF) structured
as a Special Purpose Vehicle (SPV) to raise funds in financial
markets to
issue low-interest loans to eurozone governments in financial distress
to avoid
sovereign default. The EFSF will be operational until 2013 unless
extended.
The eurozone countries provided €80 billion to the EFSF,
with a further €30 billion from the IMF. In a move to restore market
confidence
in the euro, EFSF low interest loans was made available to all Eurozone
members. Greece
withdrew the first loan on May
18, 2010.
The EFSF was
created by eurozone member states following the decisions taken on May
9, 2010
within the framework of the Economic and Financial Affairs
Council (Ecofin Council).
The Ecofin Council
The Ecofin Council, together with the Agriculture Council
and the General Affairs Council, is one of the oldest configurations of
the European
Council. It is composed of the economic and finance ministers of EU
member
states, as well as budget ministers when budgetary issues are
discussed. It
meets once a month.
The Ecofin Council covers EU policy in a number of areas
including: economic policy coordination, economic surveillance,
monitoring of
member states' budgetary policy and public finances, the euro (legal,
practical
and international aspects), financial markets and capital movements and
economic relations with third countries. It decides mainly by qualified
majority, in consultation or codecision with the European Parliament,
with the
exception of fiscal matters which are decided by unanimity.
The Ecofin Council also prepares and adopts every year,
together with the European Parliament, the budget of the European Union
which
is about €100 billion. The Eurogroup of the Ecofin Council,
composed
of the member states whose currency is the euro, meets normally the day
before
the Ecofin Council meeting and deals with issues relating to the
Economic and
Monetary Union (EMU).
The EMU is an informal body which is not a configuration of
the Ecofin Council since at the time of its configuration, the euro was
a
stable currency that required little monitoring. When the Ecofin
Council
examines dossiers related to the euro and EMU, the representatives of
the
member states whose currency is not the euro do not take part in the
vote of
the Council.
ESM Adopted by
European Council based on the Lisbon Treaty
On May 9 2010,
the European Council adopted a European
Stability Mechanism
(ESM) to preserve financial stability in Europe.
The ESM is based on Art. 122.2 of the Lisbon Treaty of late 2009 and an
inter-governmental agreement of eurozone member states, not a
supranational
body. Earlier, the Ecom held an extraordinary meeting to adopt its
proposal for
a Regulation under Article 122.
This ESM will grant financial assistance to a member
state of the EU in difficulties or seriously threatened with severe
difficulties caused by exceptional occurrences beyond its control. This
financial assistance shall take the form of a loan or of a credit line
granted
to the member state concerned.
EFSF as a SPV
Established By Inter-govenment Agreement
Within the framework of the ESM, the Ecom is allowed via the
facility created under Article 122 of the Lisbon Treaty to contract
borrowings
in the capital markets or with financial institutions on behalf of the
European
Union. This approach to providing financial
assistance is
inspired by the existing Medium-Term Financing Facility (the Balance of
Payments facility).
This particular lending arrangement
implies
that there is no debt-servicing cost for the European Union. All
interest and
loan principal is repaid by the beneficiary member state via the Ecom.
In
addition, the ESM envisages possible financial assistance to a
euro-area member
state via a special purpose vehicle (SPV) called European Financial
Stability
Fund (EFSF), which will be established by inter-governmental agreement
among
all euro-area member States.
Balance-of-Payments
Assistance
The EU can
provide mutual assistance to non-eurozone member states when a member
state is
in difficulties or is seriously threatened with difficulties as regards
its
balance of payments. Balance-of-payments (BoP) assistance is designed
to ease a
country's external financing constraints. This can take the form of
medium-term
financial assistance.
Although the framework of medium-term financial assistance allows
providing
loans solely by the EU, in recent practice the assistance has usually
been
extended in co-operation with IMF and other international institutions
or
countries.
Legal basis of
BoP Assistance
The possibility
of granting mutual assistance to a member state with difficulties as
regards
its balance of payments is laid down in Article 143 of the Treaty. The
facility
to provide medium-term financial assistance has been established by Council Regulation (EC) No
332/2002.
How BoP
Assistance Works
Step 1: Member
state request BoP Assistance and Council decision
The member state in
fiscal difficulties addresses itself to the European Commission (Ecom)
and
other member states, when seeking medium-term financial assistance. The
member
state in need presents a draft adjustment program designed to achieve a
sustainable balance of payments position - in support of its
application. The
request, backed by the adjustment program, is discussed within the
relevant
EU bodies and, if applicable, with other creditors.
When it is considered that a member state is in financial difficulty or
is
seriously threatened with financial difficulties as regards its balance
of
payments, the European Council, based on a recommendation by the Ecom,
makes a
decision whether to grant mutual assistance.
When it is
considered that this should take a form of medium-term financial
assistance,
the European Council decides (usually in the course of the same
meeting), on
the basis of an Ecom proposal and following an examination of the draft
adjustment program presented by the member state concerned:
- whether to grant a loan or appropriate financing
facility,
its amount and average duration (normally about five years), as well as
technicalities for disbursing the loan or financing facility;
- the economic policy conditions attached to the
medium-term
assistance.
2. Memorandum
of Understanding and Loan Agreement
On the basis of
these decisions, the Commission and the Member State concerned conclude
a
Memorandum of Understanding (MoU) and the Loan Agreement. The MoU
specifies
economic policy conditions that the Commission, in collaboration with
the
Economic and Financial Committee and other program partners, in
particular
the IMF, shall verify prior to a decision on the release of any further
installment. The Loan Agreement includes the technicalities of the
borrowing
process and the detailed financial conditions of the loan.
Economic policy
conditions usually involve an agreed path of fiscal consolidation,
governance
measures (for example, reform of taxation and tighter spending controls
at all
levels of government), as well as financial sector stabilization
measures (for
example, additional banking regulatory requirements) and structural
reform
measures to improve business environment and support growth (for
example,
increasing administrative capacity to absorb EU funds more
effectively). In
addition, conditions are included regarding safeguards against fraud.
This is
particularly important given that the default risk of these loans is
ultimately
borne by the Member States.
3.
Disbursement and Regular Review
Following
signature of the MoU and the Loan Agreement, and a request for
disbursement by
the national authorities, fund-raising on international markets takes
place and
first payment tranche is released. Subsequent installments of the loan
are
released once the EU institutions have assessed the member state’s
compliance
with the program conditions. Reviews are undertaken at regular
intervals to
ensure that the economic policies of the member state receiving
Community loan
comply with the adjustment program and the previously agreed
conditions.
Changing economic environment can necessitate modifications and
amendments to
previously adopted documents.
Financing
Aspects of BoP Assistance
The funds to be
extended to member states experiencing external financing constraints
are
raised by the European Commission (Ecom) on behalf of the EU on
international
financial markets. For each program there is a planned disbursement
schedule
attached, which is agreed by all program partners and corresponds to
the
estimated financing need of the country. The schedule is subject to
modification to be consistent with developments under the program.
‘AAA’ loan rates
obtained by the EU on international financial markets at the moment of
fund-raising
are passed on to the member states in need without adding any
additional
margin. They are among the most favorable rates available globally.
For
comparison, IMF’s market-related interest rate, known as the “rate of
charge”,
is based on the SDR interest rate and includes a margin; additional
surcharges
are applied on high, in relation to the country's quota, levels of
outstanding
credit.
The total
outstanding amount of loans to be granted to member states under the
medium-term financial assistance facility is limited to €50 billion in
principal. The maximum amount has been increased in response to the
financial
crisis, to €25 billion in December 2008 and further to €50 billion in
May 2009
(from €12 billion before).
The ECom has agreed to propose an increase to €50 billion in
the overall ceiling of a loan facility to help non-euro area countries
in the
European Union cope with balance-of-payments difficulties. The
present ceiling was increased by EU finance ministers already in
December
2010 to €25 billion, but the scope and intensity of the international
financial
crisis calls for another pre-emptive increase and to show solidarity
with
countries that do not yet benefit from the protective umbrella of the
euro.
On March 25, 2008,
Joaquín Almunia, European Economic and MonetaryAffairs
Commissioner, said: “This
shows that the EU solidarity mechanisms exist and can be made ever more
powerful at short notice to the benefit of its most vulnerable members.
Thanks
to the balance-of-payments assistance facility that is already
being
used for three countries, the considerable transfers under the powerful
EU
structural funds and other financial instruments and institutions, our
member states
should be able to withstand the pressures brought about by the economic
crisis
provided they contribute with stable and sound macro-economic
policies.”
The support will be provided in conjunction with the
International Monetary Fund (€13 billion) and the World Bank (€1
billion). The
European Bank of Reconstruction and Development and other multilateral
creditors will jointly provide a total of €1 billion, bringing the
total
to up
to € 20 billion over the period to the first quarter of 2011.
The financial assistance will be conditional on the
implementation of a comprehensive economic policy program. The
financial
assistance and the policy program are designed to enable the economy
to
withstand short-term liquidity pressures while improving
competitiveness and
supporting an orderly correction of imbalances in the medium term,
hence
bringing the economy back on a sound and sustainable footing.
In the financial sector, the program would seek to ensure
adequate capitalization of banks and to strengthen financial sector
supervision, including banking and liquidation/bankruptcy laws.
The deposit
guarantee
scheme would be further bolstered.
A sound management of the funds received is expected with a
strong role for independent and well functioning auditing and
anti-corruption
institutions.
A key element of the economic policy package is an immediate
and sustained fiscal consolidation to limit the budget deficit to 5.1%
of GDP
in 2009, falling further to below 3% of GDP in 2011. To support these
targets,
measures will be taken to improve budgetary policy credibility and
predictability, as also requested by the June 2008 Commission Policy
Advice to Romania.
The economic policy conditionality will be set in a
forthcoming Council decision and further spelled out in a Memorandum of
Understanding to be concluded shortly with the Romanian authorities.
The agreed
measures and targets will also be reflected in the forthcoming
Convergence
Program update. The Commission in collaboration with the Economic and
Financial Committee will monitor regularly and closely that the
economic policy
conditions attached to the financial assistance are fully implemented
and may
request additional measures when and if circumstances so require.
We also urge the financial institutions operating in Romania
to continue providing adequate funding of their operations there as
well as
appropriate financing of the economy. In this context we would very
much
welcome the confirmation of the long-term commitment of foreign parent
banks to Romania
and to
support their subsidiaries in the country.
EU Assistance Will Take Form of a BoP Loan
The proposed medium-term financial assistance to Romania
will be based on a Council Decision based on a Commission
recommendation to
grant this assistance. Such support is provided under Council
Regulation
332/2002 establishing a facility providing medium-term financial
assistance for
non-euro area EU Member States' balance of payments (BoP). The
Commission is
expected to adopt this recommendation for a Council Decision in the
coming
weeks. Following the Council Decision, the Memorandum of Understanding,
which
spells out the precise policy conditions, as well as the loan
agreement, will
be agreed between the European Commission and the Romanian authorities.
This support comes on top of the increase in advance
payments of structural funds from €0.5 billion to €0.8 billion for
2009, as
part of the European Economic Recovery Package. Romania
is also likely to benefit from the significant increase of the EIB
resources.
Background
The EU also agreed to grant a BoP loan to Hungary
of €6.5 billion and to Latvia
of €3.1 billion and an additional €2.2 billion is committed to Latvia
by some individual Member States. On a proposal by the Commission, the
Council
decided to increase early December 2008 the overall financial
assistance
ceiling to €25 billion from an original €12 billion (see
IP/08/1612). The European Council of 23 March 2009 has welcomed the suggestion by the
Commission to double the BoP facility to €50 billion.
In order to be able to react quickly to potential demand for
financial assistance from EU countries outside the euro area, the ECom
proposes
to increase to €50 billion the ceiling set in Regulation 332/2002
establishing
a facility providing medium-term financial assistance for member
states’
balances of payments. The present ceiling, revised in early December
2008, was
€25 billion.
The proposal follows the call by EU heads of government at
the March 2010 Summit for
a
doubling of the ceiling. The revised regulation needs to be adopted by
EU
finance ministers, which is expected to happen at their May 4, 2010 meeting,
following consultation with
the European Parliament and the European Central Bank.
Two countries presently benefit of medium-term
Balanceofpayments loans are Hungary with up to €6.5 billion and Latvia
with up
to €3.1 billion (see IP/08/1612,
IP/08/2045
and IP/09/323).
Following a
request by Romania, the ECom also recently announced, after consulting
with the
Economic and Financial Committee, its intention to provide up to €5
billion to
the Romanian authorities up to the first quarter of 2009 (see IP/09/475).
A formal
proposal to the European Council is expected later this month.
This leaves a total of €10.4 billion available under the
present ceiling. There are no other requests at present.
Drawing on the recent experience with the medium-term
financial assistance, the Commission also proposes some amendments with
a view
to clarifying the respective tasks and responsibilities of the European Commission (ECom) and of the member
state concerned, and to spell out some technical details. These cover
for instance
the conclusion of a MoU between the ECom and the member
state concerned detailing the conditions approved by the European
Council or
the possibility for the Court of Auditors to carry out audits.
The adopted ECom proposal is available at the web site of the
Commission's Directorate General for Economic and Financial Affairs at:
http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/thematic_articles/article14759_en.htm
An instrument to grant mutual assistance to an EU country in
difficulty or threatened with difficulties as regards its balance of
payments
was first created in 1988 (Regulation 1969/88, Official Journal L 178)
The EU
countries that have already adopted the euro do not qualify for
medium-term
financial assistance .But the regulation was kept and modified in 2002
(Regulation 332/2002, OJ L53) to meet the potential needs of other EU
countries
until they too adopt the euro. The ceiling was then set at €12 billion.
The assistance is financed through the recourse to the
capital markets, using the creditworthiness of the European Community,
the EU’s
legal entity. The European Community benefits from the unconditional
support of
all the member states. The money is lent under the same conditions
under which
it was borrowed (so-called back-to-back loans).
The assistance is granted in several installments, according
to a Loan Agreement that also sets the maturity, interest, modalities
of
disbursement and repayment...etc). The release of the installments is
conditional on terms agreed with the beneficiary country in a
Memorandum of
Understanding. See following web site for MoUs with Hungary
and Latvia
and
other documents related with the economic and financial crisis:
http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/focuson/focuson13254_en.htm
The European Community has carried out three euro bond issues
since last year to finance a first installment of €2 billion for
Hungary
(disbursed early December 2008), a second installment also to Hungary
and also
of €2 billion (disbursed late March) as well as a first installment of
€1
billion to Latvia (paid in February). The last issue, placed on 17
March and
due on November 7, 2014
(5-year maturity), was priced 3.25%.
The balance-of-payments assistance is generally granted in
conjunction with the International Monetary Fund and the budgetary and
macro-economic conditions are also coordinated with the IMF and other
international institutions.
A European Community
facility providing medium-term financial assistance is established,
enabling
loans to be granted to one or more member states experiencing
difficulties in
their balance of payments on current or capital account. Only those
member states
that have not adopted the euro may benefit from this facility. The
outstanding
amount of loans to be granted to member states under this facility is
limited
to €50 billion.
To this end, the European
Commission (Ecom) is empowered, on behalf of the European Community, to
contract loans on the capital markets or with financial institutions.
If member states
which have not adopted the euro call upon sources of financing outside
the European
Community which are subject to economic policy conditions, they must
first
consult the ECom and the other member states in order to examine the
possibilities available under the European Community medium-term
financial
assistance facility. Such consultations will be held within the
Economic and
Financial Committee.
The facility may
be implemented by the European Council on the initiative of either the
ECom
(pursuant to Article 119 of the Treaty establishing the European
Community), in
agreement with the member state concerned, or a member state
experiencing
difficulties.
To obtain
financial support in the medium term, the member state will carry out a
needs
assessment with the ECom and present to the ECom and the Economic and
Financial
Committee an adjustment program. After examining the situation in the
member state
seeking assistance, the European Council decides:
- whether to grant a loan or appropriate financing
facility,
its amount and its average duration;
- the economic policy conditions attached to the
medium-term
financial assistance with a view to re-establishing a sustainable
balance of payments situation;
- the techniques for disbursing the loan or financing
facility, the release or drawings of which are, as a rule, by
successive installments.
The ECom and the
member state concerned will then conclude a Memorandum of Understanding
which
details the conditions set by the European Council. The Memorandum is
then sent
to the European Parliament and the European Council.
In cases where
restrictions on capital movements are introduced or reintroduced
(Article 120
of the EC Treaty) during the period of the financial assistance, the
conditions
and arrangements governing financial assistance are re-examined.
At regular
intervals, the ECom, in conjunction with the Economic and Financial
Committee,
verifies that the economic policy of the member state receiving
assistance
accords with the commitments laid down in the adjustment program or
any other
conditions. The member state will make all the necessary information
available
to the ECom and cooperate fully with them. The release of further
installments
depends on the findings of such verification.
Loans granted as
medium-term financial assistance may be granted as consolidation of
short-term
monetary support made available by the European Central Bank (ECB)
under the
very short-term financing facility.
The borrowing and
lending operations are carried out in euros. They use the same value
date and
must not involve the European Community in the transformation of
maturities, in
any exchange or interest-rate risk or in any other commercial risk.
At the request of
the beneficiary member state, loans may carry the option of early
repayment.
At the request of
the debtor member state and where circumstances permit an improvement
in the
interest rate on the loans, the European Commission may refinance all
or some
of its initial borrowings or restructure the corresponding financial
conditions. These operations may not have the effect of extending the
average
duration of the borrowing concerned or increasing the amount of capital
outstanding. The costs incurred in concluding and carrying out each
operation
are borne by the beneficiary member state. The Economic and Financial
Committee
must be kept informed of these operations.
The european Council
decisions on this matter are taken by qualified majority on a proposal
from the
Commission made after consulting the Economic and Financial Committee.
The ECB
makes the necessary arrangements for the administration of the loans.
The beneficiary member
state shall open a special account with its national central bank for
the
management of the financial assistance. It is also required to transfer
the
payments due to an account with the ECB seven working days prior to the
corresponding due date.
The European
Court of Auditors has the right to carry out any necessary financial
controls
or audits. The European Commission and the European Anti-Fraud Office
can also
send officials to the Member State receiving financial support in order
to
carry out controls.
EFSF
Mandate
The mandate of
the EFSF is to safeguard financial stability in Europe by providing
financial
assistance to eurozone member states. The EFSF is authorized to use the
following instruments linked to appropriate conditionality:
Provide loans to countries in
financial difficulties;
Intervene in the debt primary and
secondary markets;
Intervention in the secondary
market will be only on the basis of an
European Central Bank (ECB) analysis recognizing the existence of
exceptional
financial market circumstances and risks to financial stability;
Act on the basis of a
precautionary program; and
Finance recapitalizations of
financial institutions through loans to
governments.
EFSF Authorized to
Issue Bonds
To fulfill its
mission, EFSF is authorized to issue bonds or other debt instruments in
capital
markets. EFSF is backed by guarantee commitments from eurozone member
states
for a total of €780 billion and has a lending capacity of €440 billion.
EFSF
had been assigned the best possible credit rating; AAA by Standard
& Poor’s
and Fitch Ratings, Aaa by Moody’s.
EFSF is a
Luxembourg-registered company owned by eurozone member states. It is
headed by
Klaus Regling, former Director-General for economic and financial
affairs at
the European Commission.
Klaus Regling
Regling is a
German economist trained at the University of Hamburg (BA 1971) and the
University of Regensburg, (MA 1975), worked at the research department
of the
IMF for 5 years. In 1980 he left and spent a year in the Economics
Department
of the German Banker’s Association before being hired as an economist
by the
German Ministry of Finance, where he worked in the European Monetary
Affairs
Division until 1985. That year he returned to the IMF and worked both
in
Washington as well as in Jakarta, Indonesia.
In 1991 Regling
left the IMF once again and returned to the German Ministry of Finance,
where
he was named the Chief of the International Monetary Affairs Division.
In 1993
he became the Deputy Director-General for International Monetary and
Financial
Relations and in 1995 the Director-General for European and
International
Financial Relations. He remained with the ministry until 1998, and the
following year entered the private sector as the Managing Director of
the Moore
Capital Strategy Group in London.
Regling was
appointed the Director General of the European Commission's Economic
and
Financial Affairs directorate in 2001 and remained there till June
2008. From
2008 to March 2009 he was part of the Issing Commission head by German
economist Otmar Issing, which was formed by Chancellor Angela Merkel to
advise
the government on financial regulatory reform. He also became chairman
of the
Brussels based KR Economics consultancy. On July 1, 2010 he became head
of the EFSF.
Otmar Issing
Otmar Issing has been, since 2007, Chairman of the Advisory
Board of the House of Finance (Goethe University of Frankfurt), and
President
of the Center for Financial Studies since 2006. He is also an
international
advisor to Goldman Sachs.
In 2008 Issing was appointed by Chancellor Merkel as Head of
the Advisory Group on the New Financial Order. He also was a member of
the
European Commission's High Level Expert Group on EU Financial
Supervision
chaired by Jacques de Larosière, and responsible for the De
Larosière report.
Issing was a member of the Executive Board of the European
Central Bank (ECB) since its creation in 1998 until 2006, responsible
for the
Directorate General Economics and the Directorate General Research. He
was
previously a member of the Board of the Deutsche Bundesbank (German
central
bank) with a seat on the bank’s Council.
Before that, Issing held chairs of economics at the
universities of Würzburg and Erlangen-Nürnberg, and was a
member of the Council
of Experts in Germany
for the Assessment of Overall Economic Developments from 1988 to 1990.
Issing is also a member of the Advisory Board of the
Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Dallas,
and honorary professor of the universities of Würzburg and Frankfurt.
He holds honorary doctorates from the universities of Bayreuth,
Frankfurt and Konstanz
and has received numerous prizes and honours. He is also the author of
numerous
articles and books, such as The birth of the euro (English
edition
published in 2008).
EFSF
The amount of loans or credit lines available via the EFSF
established under Article 122 was limited to the margin available under
the own
resources ceiling for payment appropriations of the EU budget. A volume
of up
to €60 billion was foreseen. The EFSF established by inter-governmental
agreement amongst euro area member states will guarantee on a pro-rata
basis
lending up to €440 billion.
The EFSF has been created to preserve the stability, unity
and integrity of the European Union. The facility provides assistance
to any
member state which is experiencing or is seriously threatened with a
severe
economic or financial disturbance caused by exceptional occurrences
beyond its
control. Financial assistance under the EFSF will be provided only to
euro area
member states. Non euro area member states remain also covered by the
Balance
of Payment facility. Under this facility, the Ecom has already granted
assistance to Latvia,
Hungary
and Romania.
The ESM would allow the provision of loans, not grants.
Loans have to be repaid with interest. As such it is compatible with
Art 125
TFEU. The Treaty
of Rome, officially the Treaty establishing the
European Economic Community, was an
inte-government agreement that led to the founding of the European
Economic
Community on January 1, 1958. It was signed on 25 March 1957 by Belgium,
France,
Italy,
Luxembourg,
the Netherlands
and West Germany,
the so-called “Inner 6”. The word Economic was deleted from the
treaty's
name by the Maastricht Treaty in 1993, and the treaty was repackaged as
the Treaty on the Functioning of the European
Union (TFEU) on the entry into force of the Treaty of Lisbon in
2009 and renamed as Treaty of European Union
(TEU)..
A eurozone member state seeking financial assistance under
the ESM shall discuss with the Ecom in liaison with the ECB an
assessment of
its financial needs. It shall submit a draft economic and financial
adjustment
program to the Ecom and the Economic and Financial Committee. Acting on
a
proposal by the Ecom, the European Council shall adopt a decision by
qualified
majority vote granting financial assistance.
This European Council decision shall include the maximum
amount, price and duration of the financial support, the number of
installments
to be disbursed and the main policy conditions attached to the support.
It
shall entrust the Ecom with the responsibility for
negotiating a Memorandum of Understanding (MoU) with the
country concerned detailing the conditionality.
The Ecom will closely monitor the respect of the policy
conditions by the beneficiary Member
State,
in liaison with the ECB, before installments of the loan are disbursed.
If it
concludes that the conditions are met, it proposes to the participants
to
disburse the installments.
The ESM is based on a European Council Decision adopted
under Article 122, which requires “qualified majority” at the Council
and the
Parliament to be informed and an intergovernmental agreement.
Having created
the EFSF following the decisions taken on May 9, 2010 within the
framework of
the Ecofin Council, Eurozone finance ministers agreed on
November 29
2010 on the terms and conditions to extend EFSF’s capacity by
introducing
sovereign bond partial risk participation and a Co-Investment approach.
The ministers also adopted amended EFSF guidelines
concerning intervention in the primary and secondary debt markets and
precautionary credit lines in order to use leverage. Klaus Regling CEO
of EFSF
commented: “Both options are designed to enlarge the capacity of the
EFSF so
that the new instruments available to the EFSF can be used efficiently”.
Under partial risk protection, EFSF would provide a partial
protection certificate to a newly issued bond of a eurozone member
state. The
certificate could be detached after initial issue and could be traded
separately. It would give the holder an amount of fixed credit
protection of
20-30% of the principal amount of the sovereign bond. The partial risk
protection is to be used primarily under precautionary program and is
aimed at
increasing demand for new issues of eurozone member states and lowering
funding
costs.
Under option two, the creation of one or more Co-Investment
Funds (CIF) would allow the combination of public and private funding.
A CIF
would purchase bonds in the primary and/or secondary markets. Where the
CIF
would provide funding directly to Member States through the purchase of
primary
bonds, this funding could, inter alia, be used by Member States for
bank
recapitalization. The CIF would comprise a first loss tranche which
would be
financed by EFSF.
Chris Frankel CFO and Deputy CEO of EFSF commented:
“Following extensive discussions with investors covering all types and
geographical regions, a number of them have given their positive views
and
signaled their willingness to participate.”
EFSF will now implement these two approaches to be ready
early in 2012 to use them effectively in the context of the guidelines
for the
new instruments on market interventions.
EFSF will be able to use both leverage options
simultaneously. The final amount of “firepower” achieved through the
use of the
options will depend upon the concrete use and mix of the instruments
and
particularly the exact degree of protection between 20% and 30%. EFSF
has
currently a lending capacity of €440 billion and firm commitments
regarding IrelandPortugal
totaling €43.7 billion.
EFSF is also expected to finance a second aid program for Greece
and fulfill tasks such as financing recapitalization of financial
institutions
in non-program countries. Without knowing the exact amounts needed,
EFSF
should be able to leverage its own resources of up to €250 billion.
Deployment
of either instrument using leverage will only be made following a
request from
a eurozone member state. Any support from the EFSF will be linked to
strict
policy conditionality, monitoring and surveillance procedures.
On November 7, 2011
EFSF placed a €3 billion 10-year benchmark bond maturing on February 4, 2022 to fund the
EFSF’s
second disbursement as part of the financial assistance program to Ireland.
The issuance spread at reoffer was fixed at mid swap plus 104 basis
points.
This implies a reoffer yield for investors of 3.591%. In spite of the
recent
market volatility, the issue was met with solid demand with orders
received in
excess of €3 billion from real money investors around the world.
Klaus Regling, CEO of EFSF said: “I am pleased that the EFSF
has again attracted investors from all over the world with a
satisfactory
overall amount despite a difficult market environment”.
Following Ireland’s
request, the funds for an amount of €3 billion was disbursed to Ireland
on November 10. This was the first issue made following the
ratification of the
amendments to the EFSF’s framework which include an improved credit
enhancement
structure.
Barclays, Credit Agricole CIB and J.P. Morgan acted as lead
managers for this issue and Deutsche Finanzagentur acted as Issuance
Agent.
Christophe Frankel, Deputy CEO and CFO said: “since our first launch in
January
of this year, EFSF has established itself as a high quality issuer with
a solid
investor base”.
On October
31, 2011 EFSF announced the appointment
of Barclays, Crédit Agricole CIB and JP Morgan as joint lead
managers for its
next issue due to be launched shortly, subject to market conditions.
The
proceeds would be used in conjunction with the financial assistance
program for
Republic of Ireland. The three institutions were selected from the 47
banks
that comprise the EFSF Market Group. Christophe Frankel, Deputy CEO and
CFO of
EFSF said: “as a relatively new issuer, we need to continue building
long-term
demand”. The next issue is expected to be a €3 billion (no grow)
10-year
benchmark bond.
EFSF made its
inaugural issue in January 2011 when it placed a €5 billion 5-year
benchmark
bond in support of Ireland. It placed two subsequent benchmark bonds in
support
of the financial assistance program for Portugal.
Following the
official entry into force of the Amendments to the EFSF Framework
Agreement on
October 18, 2011, all three credit rating agencies affirmed the best
possible
credit rating – Standard & Poor’s “AAA”, Moody’s “(P)Aaa” and Fitch
Ratings
“AAA” – to the EFSF on October 29, 2011.
All three agencies also assigned the highest quality short term rating
to the
EFSF – Standard & Poor’s “A-1+”, Moody’s “(P)P-1” and Fitch Ratings
“F1+”.
In reaction to
the potential increase funding volumes that could arise to take into
account
the new tasks assigned to the EFSF, its funding strategy will
consequently
become more flexible and diversified. It is expected that the EFSF will
implement a short-term funding strategy which could be structured
around a Bill
program. Klaus Regling, CEO of EFSF said: “Confirmation of the highest
possible
credit rating shows the confidence in the strategy of the eurozone to
restore
financial stability. The amendments to the EFSF will allow it to
contribute in
more ways to implement this strategy”.
Under the amended
EFSF, the guarantee commitments have been increased to €780 billion and
effective lending capacity is now be €440 billion. The scope of
activity of the
EFSF has also been enlarged and it is now authorized to:
Intervene in the debt primary and
secondary markets.
Act on the basis of precautionary
programs
Finance recapitalizations of
financial institutions through loans to
governments including in non-program countries
All assistance to
eurozone member states would be linked to appropriate conditionality.
EFSF has placed 3
benchmark issues this year for a total of €13 billion in support of the
programs for Ireland and Portugal which total €43.7 billion (€17.7
billion for
Ireland; €26 billion for Portugal). Christophe Frankel, EFSF Deputy CEO
and CFO
said: “EFSF is fully operational and stands ready to perform all duties
to
which it is assigned”.
EFSF intends to
issue a €3 billion benchmark bond for Ireland in the near future market
conditions permitting.
Following
parliamentary approval by Slovakia on October 13, 2011, the amendments
to the
EFSF’s Framework Agreement have now been ratified by all 17 eurozone
member
states. EFSF stood ready to implement its new scope of activity once it
received the amendment confirmations by all eurozone member states in
writing.
Klaus Regling,
CEO of EFSF said: “After the successful completion of all political
approval
procedures the EFSF and its Board will finalise quickly all necessary
guidelines
and procedures to be able to use the new instruments in the near
future.”
The new EFSF will
have an effective lending capacity of €440 billion through guarantee
commitments from eurozone member states of €780 billion including an
over-guarantee of up to 165%. Relying solely on guarantees, a cash
reserve and
a loan specific cash buffer will no longer be required as credit
enhancement.
The amendments to
the EFSF, based on unanimity, also include the authorisation to use the
following instruments linked to appropriate conditionality:
Intervene in the debt primary and
secondary markets;
Intervention in the secondary
market will be only on the basis of an ECB
analysis recognizing the existence of exceptional financial market
circumstances and risks to financial stability act on the basis of a
precautionary program;
Finance recapitalizations of
financial institutions through loans to
governments including in non-program countries.
The technical
details regarding the new EFSF instruments are will be announced when
finalized. EFSF would use the new tools only upon request of a eurozone
member
state.
Regarding the
discussion about potential leveraging of the EFSF, Christophe Frankel,
Chief
Financial Officer of EFSF said: “Any decision to use EFSF’s capacity
more
efficiently will not lead to an increase in guarantee commitments from
the member
states and there will therefore be no consequence on the EFSF’s triple
A credit
rating”.
Under the new
structure EFSF is planning to issue one benchmark bond for Ireland for
€3
billion before end of 2011. Ireland was granted financial assistance on
November 28, 2010, the terms and conditions of the financial assistance
package
were agreed by the Eurogroup and the EU’s Council of Economics and
Finance
Ministers.
The issues
initially scheduled in Q4, 2011 in support of Portugal's financial
assistance
program could now be issued in early 2012. Details will be disclosed in
due
time.
In addition, the
EFSF stands ready to implement decisions that are expected to be taken
in
December 2011 on the second Greek adjustment program.
On Dec. 6, 2011,
Standard & Poor’s placed the ‘AAA’ long-term credit rating on the
European
Financial Stability Facility (EFSF) on CreditWatch with negative
implications.
At the same time, S&P affirmed the ‘A-1+’ short-term credit rating
on EFSF.
On December 9, 2011
Standard & Poor’s Ratings Services said that it would assign its
‘A-1+’
short-term debt rating to the European Financial Stability Facility's
(EFSF;
AAA/Watch Neg/A-1+) proposed short-term debt issuance. The rating is
based on
the final terms and conditions.
EFSF’s scope of activity was broadened in March and July
2011 to allow it to intervene in the debt primary market; act on the
basis of a
precautionary program; recapitalize financial institutions through
loans to
governments, whether or not they are program countries; and intervene
in the
secondary markets.
To allow the EFSF to exercise its wider mandate efficiently,
it now proposes to issue short-term debt under its €55 billion
guaranteed debt issuance
program. This short-term funding program is initially expected to focus
on
three-, six-, and 12-month bills.
By late 2010, Ireland
was suffering financial problems, and the eurozone countries agreed to
a €11.7
billion bailout from the EFSF. May 2011 saw Portugal
also receive a bailout of €78 billion. Greece's
second loan was requested in June 2011.
The EFSF
enlargement process of 2011 proved to be challenging to several
Eurozone member
states, who objected against assuming sovereign liabilities in
potential
violation of the Maastricht Treaty no bailout provisions. On October
13, 2011,
Slovakia approved EFSF expansion 2.0 after failed first approval vote.
In
exchange, the Slovakian government was forced to resign and call new
elections.
On October 19, 2011,
Helsingin Sanomat, the largest newspaper in Finland and the Nordic
countries,
reported that the Finnish parliament passed the EFSF guarantee
expansion
without quantifying the total potential liability to Finland. It turned
out
that several members of the parliament did not understand that in
addition to
increasing the capital guarantee from €7.9 billion to €14.0 billion,
the
Government of Finland would be guaranteeing all of the interest and
capital
raising costs of EFSF in addition to the issued capital, assuming
theoretically
uncapped liability.
Helsingin Sanomat
estimated that in an adverse situation this liability could reach €28.7
billion, adding interest rate of 3.5% for 30-year loans to capital
guarantee.
For this reason the parliamentary approval process on 28 September 2011
was
misleading, and may require a new Government proposal.
The Lisbon Treaty which had come into force on December 1, 2009 was amended so that
the EFSF will be replaced by a permanent stability mechanism in 2013.
December 20, 2011
Next: German Dominance
|
|
|
|