|
The Eurozone
Sovereign Debt Crisis
By
Henry C.K. Liu
Part I: A Currency
Union Not Backed by Political
Union
The Eurozone
sovereign debt crisis is rooted in the dysfunction of a monetary union
without
political union. The fundamental cause for the crisis lies in the
arrangement
under which the euro is legal tender for all member states in the
eurozone, yet
monetary policy for the eurozone is the exclusive responsibility of the
European
Central Bank, for which common representation of all member states,
governance and
fiscal policy union in support of currency union does not formally
exist. This
essentially makes sovereign debt of eurozone member states denominated
in euro
foreign currency debts. Since individual eurozone member states do not
have
sovereign authority over their common currency, they are deprived of
the option
of solving their sovereign debt problem with monetary measures, such as
devaluing their common currency or lowering interest rates.
The eurozone, also
known as euro area
(EA17), is an economic and monetary union (EMU) of
17 out
of the 27 member states of European
Union (EU27) that have adopted the euro (€) as their common currency
and sole legal
tender that is freely convertible at market exchange rates. The euro is
also
legal tender in a five other non-EMU European political entities
(Montenegro, Andorra,
Monaco, San Marino and Vatican City) and the disputed territory of
Kosovo.
The euro is the
common currency used daily by some 332 million Europeans and their
separate
governments. Additionally, over 175 million people worldwide use
currencies
which are pegged to the euro, including more than 150 million people in
Africa.
A Political Crisis
with Financial Dimensions
The European
sovereign debt crisis is at its base a intergovernmental political
crisis in the
eurozone-17 with financial and economic dimensions that reaches beyond
the
eurozone to all its trading partner regions as well as financial and
trading
markets in the entire world. The crisis is centered around the
difficulty in
achieving policy consensus among all eurozone member states and the
inability
of any eurozone member state under financial distress from sovereign
debt
difficulties to employ monetary measures individually, such a currency
devaluation or interest rate measures, to solve its euro denominated
sovereign
debt problems, since no member state has individual authority to set or
revise
monetary policy or exchange rate value for the euro to address its
public
finance problems. Furthermore, the economic and public finance problems
of
eurozone member states are not congruent, thus giving rise to varying
and often
contradicting political incentives in different member states, pitting
the
political dynamics of richer economies against those of poorer
economies.
Debt Crisis of a Rich
Economy
On many levels,
the eurozone (EA17) is a very rich economy. It has a population of 320
million
with a 2010 GDP of €9.2 trillion ($12.2
trillion), albeit with an wide range of per capita GDP, ranging from €30,600
in Austria to €19,700 in Romania. Little Luxembourg's per capita GDP
was
€70,000
in 2010. Despite of the fact that
eurozone membership involves only 17 of the 27 member state of the
EU27,
the
eurozone is essentially the economic and financial core of the EU,
which has
the highest GDP ($16.2 trillion in 2010) in the world, larger that the
US GDP
($14.7 trillion). A sovereign default in any eurozone member state will
put in
doubt the continuance of the euro as a common currency in the eurozone
and as
prime reserve currency for international trade.
Collapse of Aggregate
Demand
The reason why a
rich economy like that of the eurozone suffers such a sudden collapses
in
aggregate demand caused by a banking sector and sovereign debt crisis
around a
common currency lies squarely on a breakdown of political consensus
among
eurozone member state governments. The sovereign debt crisis in the
eurozone
began with the global economic recession that began in mid 2007 in New
York,
caused by a massive meltdown in electronically linked credit markets in
all
major open economies due to excessive private and public debts to
compensated
for decades of low wages.
This global
recession has thus far stubbornly
resisted all coordinated efforts by governments and central banks of
trading
economies around the world to stimulate a quick economic recovery
through the
injection of liquidity via aggressive central bank interest rate policy
and
massive quantitative easing. The penalty for direct government bailout
of
too-big-to-fail financial entities to defuse a market meltdown will be
a decade
of slow growth for the world economy, because the debt crisis that had
been
caused by low wages is being solved with government austerity measures
that
will push wages further down. Slow economic growth is highly
problematic for
countries with high levels of sovereign debt. And for any country whose
sovereign debt is denominated in currency not subject to the monetary
authority
of its central bank, the problem can be
fatal.
The reason for
the long and weak recovery in global economy is that the excessive debt
in the
global economy has not been extinguished by government bailouts. The
debt has
only been shifted from the private sector to the public sector, from
the
balance sheets of distressed commercial and investment banks to the
balance
sheets of central banks. The penalty for this liquidity play on the
part of
central banks to save insolvent financial institutions from collapse
will be an
extended anemic global economy in which banks, companies and households
are all
trying to deleverage from undistinguished debt with the new liquidity
of
no
economic substance released by central bank quantitative easing. Also,
government austerity programs needed to secure more debt will further
reduce
wage income and exacerbate further fall in aggregate demand in a
downward
vicious cycle.
ECB Quantitative Easing
A look at the way
the Federal Reserve has dealt with the debt propelled recession since
mid 2007
is instructive on what the ECB will likely also do to deal with the
European
sovereign debt crisis of 2011.
Central bank
monetary policy ammunition of low interest rate has long been exhausted
ever
since the Federal Reserve lowered the target for the short-term Fed
funds rate
to between 0% and 0.25% on December 16, 2008, and keeping it there
open-ended,
by now for almost three years, and possibly has to for another year or
two
more. When central bank inflation targeting is finally put in place,
the Fed
funds rate will go negative.
In the
accompanying statement on the zero interest rate move on December 16,
2008,
already a year and a half into the
recession, the Fed said:
“Since the last Open Market
Committee meeting (August 5, 2008), labor
market conditions have deteriorated, and the available data indicate
that
consumer spending, business investment, and industrial production have
declined. Financial markets remain quite strained and credit conditions
tight.
Overall, the outlook for economic activity has weakened further.
“Meanwhile, inflationary
pressures
have diminished appreciably. In light of the declines in the prices of
energy
and other commodities and the weaker prospects for economic activity,
the
Committee expects inflation to moderate further in coming quarters.
“The
Federal Reserve will employ all
available tools to promote the resumption of sustainable economic
growth and to
preserve price stability. In particular, the Committee anticipates that
weak
economic conditions are likely to warrant exceptionally low levels of
the
federal funds rate for some time.
“The
focus of the Committee's policy
going forward will be to support the functioning of financial markets
and
stimulate the economy through open market operations and other measures
that
sustain the size of the Federal Reserve's balance sheet at a high
level.
“As
previously announced, over the
next few quarters the Federal Reserve will purchase large quantities of
agency
debt and mortgage-backed securities to provide
support to the mortgage
and
housing markets, and it stands ready to expand its purchases of agency
debt and
mortgage-backed securities as conditions warrant. The Committee is also
evaluating the potential benefits of purchasing longer-term Treasury
securities.
“Early
next year (2009), the Federal
Reserve will also implement the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan
Facility (TALF)
to facilitate the extension of credit to households and small
businesses. The
Federal Reserve will continue to consider ways of using its balance
sheet to
further support credit markets and economic activity.”
Term Asset-Backed
Securities Loan Facility (TALF)
On November 25,
2008, not waiting until 2009 as announced, The Fed launched TALF “to
support
the issuance of asset-backed securities (ABS) collateralized by student
loans, auto
loans, credit card loans, and loans guaranteed by the Small Business
Administration (SBA).” The on-going
record of the ineffectiveness of TALF will give some idea of what the
ECB swill
face since it is now being pushed to take similar measures by US
Treasury
Secretary Geithner, even though TALF was designed to deal with
commercial and
consumer debt while the ECB is facing a crisis of sovereign debt.
The Fed said in
2008 that under TALF, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York (NY Fed)
would lent
up to $1 trillion (originally planned to be $200 billion) on a
non recourse
basis to holders of certain AAA-rated ABS backed by newly and recently
originated consumer and small business loans. As TALF money did not
originate
from the Treasury, the program did not require congressional approval
to
disburse funds, but a new act of Congress forced the Fed to reveal how
it
actually spent the money.
The Fed explained
the reasoning behind the TALF as follows:
“New issuance of ABS declined
precipitously in September and came to a halt
in October. At the same time, interest rate spreads on AAA-rated
tranches of
ABS soared to levels well outside the range of historical experience,
reflecting unusually high risk premiums. The ABS markets historically
have
funded a substantial share of consumer credit and SBA-guaranteed small
business
loans. Continued disruption of these markets could significantly limit
the
availability of credit to households and small businesses and thereby
contribute
to further weakening of U.S. economic activity. The TALF is designed to
increase credit availability and support economic activity by
facilitating
renewed issuance of consumer and small business ABS at more normal
interest
rate spreads”
According to the
plan, the NY Fed would spend up to $200 billion in loans to spur the
market in
securities backed by payments from loans to small business and
consumers. Yet,
the program closed after only funding the purchase of $43 billion in
distress
loans.
Under TALF, the
Fed lent $1 trillion to banks and hedge funds at nearly interest-free
rates.
Because the money came from the Fed and not the Treasury, there was no
congressional oversight of how the funds were disbursed, until an act
of
Congress forced the Fed to open its books. Congressional staffers then
examined
more than 21,000 transactions. One study estimated that the subsidy
rate on the
TALF’s $12.1 billion of loans to buy Commercial Mortgage-Backed
Securities
(CMBS) was 34 percent.
Special Purpose
Vehicle – Financial Neutron Bomb
TALF money was
designed not to go directly to targeted small businesses and consumers,
but to
the institutional issuers of asset-backed securities (ABS). The NY Fed
would
take the securities as collateral for more loans to the issuers of ABS.
To
manage the TALF loans, the NY Fed created a Special Purpose Vehicle
(SPV) that
would buy the assets securing the TALF loans. The function of a SPV is
to
isolate risk from the creator, in this case the NY Fed, as a device to
hide
debt from the balance sheet of the creator. In the case of TALF, the
SPV
creator is ultimately the NY Fed's parent, the Federal Reserve, the
nation’s
lender of last resort to banks.
SPVs are
financial neutron bombs, used in war to kill enemy population without
causing
damage to physical assets, thus saving reconstruction time and cost in
captured
enemy territories. A neutron bomb is a fission-fusion thermonuclear
weapon
(hydrogen bomb) in which the burst of neutrons generated by a fusion
reaction
is intentionally allowed to escape from the weapon, rather than being
absorbed
by its containing components. The weapon’s X-ray mirrors and radiation
case,
normally made of uranium or lead in a standard bomb, are instead made
of chromium
or nickel so that the neutrons can escape to kill enemy troops and
civilians,
leaving empty undamaged cities for occupation by the winner in a
battle.
SPV to Skirt Basel II
Capital Requirements
In a
May 14, 2002 AToL
article: The BIS vs National Banks,
I
warned about Special Purpose Vehicles (SPV) five years before the
credit crisis
broke out in July 2007:
“While Third
World banks that do
not meet BIS capital requirements are frozen from the global interbank
funds,
BIS rules have been eroded by so-called large,
complex banking organizations (LCBOs) in advanced
economies
through
capital arbitrage, which refers to strategies that reduce a bank’s
regulatory
capital requirements without a commensurate reduction in the bank’s
risk
exposures. One example of such arbitrage is the sale, or other
shift-off, from
the balance sheet, of assets with economic capital allocations below
regulatory
capital requirements, and the retention of those for which regulatory
requirements are less than the economic capital burden.
“Aggregate regulatory capital thus
ends up being lower than the economic risks require; and although
regulatory
capital ratios rise, they are in effect merely meaningless statistical
artifacts. Risks never disappear; they are always passed on. LCBOs in
effect
pass their unaccounted-for risks onto the global financial system. Thus
the
fierce opponents of socialism have become the deft operators in the
socialization of risk while retaining profits from such risk
socialization in
private hands.
“Set for 2004, implementation of the new Basel II
Capital Accord is
meant to
respond to such regulatory erosion by LCBOs. “Synthetic securitization”
refers
to structured transactions in which banks use credit derivatives to
transfer
the credit risk of a specified pool of assets to third parties, such as
insurance companies, other banks, and unregulated entities, known as
Special
Purpose Vehicles (SPV), used widely by the likes of Enron and GE. The
transfer
may be either funded, for example, by issuing credit-linked securities
in
tranches with various seniorities (collateralized loan obligations or
CLOs) or
unfunded, for example, using credit default swaps. Synthetic
securitization can
replicate the economic risk transfer characteristics of securitization
without
removing assets from the originating bank’s balance sheet or recorded
banking
book exposures.
“Synthetic securitization may also
be used more flexibly than traditional securitization. For example, to
transfer
the junior (first and second loss) element of credit risk and retain a
senior
tranche; to embed extra features such as leverage or foreign currency
payouts;
and to package for sale the credit risk of a portfolio (or reference
portfolio)
not originated by the bank. Banks may also exchange the credit risk on
parts of
their portfolios bilaterally without any issuance of rated notes to the
market.”
Central Bank uses SPV
to Hide Expansion of Balance
Sheet
The Treasury's Troubled
Assets Relief Program (TARP) of the Emergency Economic Stabilization
Act of
2008 would finance the first $20 billion of troubles assets purchases
by buying
distressed debt in the NY Fed’s SPV. If more than $20 billion
in assets
are bought by the SPV through TALF, the NY Fed will lend the additional
money
to the SPV. Since a loan is treated in accounting as an asset, the NY
Fed, by
providing the funds to buy distress debt, actually expands it balance
sheet
positively while its SPV assumes more liability.
Troubled Assets Relief
Program (TARP)
TARP allows the
US Treasury to purchase or insure up to $700 billion of
“troubled assets”, defined as:
A) residential or commercial
mortgages and any securities, obligations, or
other instruments that are based on or related to such mortgages, that
in each
case was originated or issued on or before March 14, 2008, the purchase
of
which the Secretary determines promotes financial market stability; and
B) any other financial instrument
that the Secretary, after consultation
with the Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System,
determines the purchase of which is necessary to promote financial
market
stability, but only upon transmittal of such determination, in writing,
to the
appropriate committees of Congress.”
TARP allows the
Treasury to purchase illiquid, difficult-to-value assets at full face
value
from banks and other financial institutions. The targeted assets can be
collateralized
debt obligations (CDO), which were sold in a booming market until July
2007,
when they were hit by widespread foreclosures on the underlying loans.
TARP is intended
to restore liquidity of these assets in a failed market with no other
buyers,
by purchasing them using secondary market mechanisms, thus allowing
participating
institutions to stabilize their balance sheets and avoid further losses.
TARP does not
allow banks to recoup losses already incurred on troubled assets, but
Treasury
officials expect that once trading of these assets resumes, their
prices will stabilize
and ultimately increase in value, resulting in gains to both
participating
banks and the Treasury itself. The concept of future gains from
troubled assets
comes from the hypothesis in the financial industry that these assets
are
oversold, as only a small percentage of all mortgages are in default,
while the
relative fall in prices represents losses from a much higher default
rate. Yet the low default rate was not
produced by
economic conditions, but by the Fed’s financial manipulation. Thus the
banks
are saved, but not the economy as a whole, which ultimately still has
to pay
off the undistinguished debt.
The Emergency
Economic Stabilization Act of 2008 (EESA) requires financial
institutions
selling assets to TARP to issue equity warrants (a type of security
that
entitles, but without the obligation, its holder to purchase shares in
the
company issuing the security for a specific price), or equity or senior
debt
securities (for non-publicly listed companies) to the Treasury. In the
case of
warrants, the Treasury will only receive warrants for non-voting
shares, or
will agree not to vote the stock.
This measure is supposedly
designed to protect taxpayers by giving the Treasury the possibility of
profiting through its new ownership stakes in these institutions.
Ideally, if
the financial institutions benefit from government assistance and
recover their
former strength, the government will also be able to profit from their
recovery.
Another important
goal of TARP is to encourage banks to resume lending again at levels
seen
before the crisis, both to each other and to consumers and businesses.
If TARP
can stabilize bank capital ratios, it should theoretically allow them
to
increase lending instead of hoarding cash to cushion against future
unforeseen losses
from troubled assets.
The Fed argues
that increased lending equates to “loosening” of credit, which the
government
hopes will restore order to the financial markets and improve investor
confidence in financial institutions and the markets. As banks gain
increased
lending confidence, the interbank lending interest rates (the rates at
which
the banks lend to each other on a short term basis) should decrease,
further
facilitating lending. So far, this goal has not been achieved as bank
merely
used TARP money to deleverage rather than increase lending.
TARP will operate
as a “revolving purchase facility”. The Treasury will have a set
spending
limit, $250 billion at the start of the program, with which it will
purchase
the assets and then either sell them or hold the assets and collect the
“coupons”. The money received from sales and coupons will go back into
the
pool, facilitating the purchase of more assets.
The initial $250
billion can be increased to $350 billion upon the president's
certification to Congress
that such an increase is necessary. The remaining $350 billion may be
released
to the Treasury upon a written report to Congress from the Treasury
with
details of its plan for the money. Congress then has 15 days to vote to
disapprove the increase before the money will be automatically
released. The
first $350 billion was released on October 3, 2008, and Congress voted
to
approve the release of the second $350 billion on January 15, 2009.
One way that TARP
money is being spent is to support the “Making Homes Affordable” plan,
which
was implemented on March 4, 2009, using TARP money by the Treasury.
Because “at
risk” mortgages are defined as “troubled assets” under TARP, the
Treasury has
the power to implement the plan. Generally, it provides refinancing for
mortgages held by Fannie Mae or Freddie Mac. Privately held mortgages
will be
eligible for other incentives, including a favorable loan modification
for five
years.
The authority of
the Treasury to establish and manage TARP under a newly created Office
of
Financial Stability (OFS) became law October 3, 2008, the result of an
initial
proposal that ultimately was passed by Congress as H.R. 1424, enacting
the Emergency
Economic Stabilization Act of 2008 and several other related acts.
Collateral assets
accepted by TARP include dollar-denominated cash ABS with a long-term
credit
rating in the highest investment-grade rating category from two or more
major
“nationally recognized statistical rating organizations (NRSROs)” and
do not
have a long-term credit rating below the highest investment-grade
rating
category from a major NRSRO. Synthetic ABS (credit-default swaps on
ABS) do not
qualify as eligible collateral. The program was launched on March 3,
2009.
Zero Interest Rate and
Quantitative Easing
As interest rates
cannot go below zero, central banks are forced to resort to
quantitative easing
to inject money into the financial system which allows insolvent
financial
institutions to deny the disastrous reality of insolvency from the
collapse of
the market value of collaterals to pretend that the global financial
market is
merely facing a temporary liquidity problem and that massive liquidity
injection from the central bank would allow an orderly restructuring of
the
massive overhanging distressed private debt by shifting it to the
public sector
with no borrower defaults and therefore no “haircuts” for exposed
creditors.
The price for
this strategy of short-term crisis resolution of excessive private
sector debt
by increasing public sector debt is the long-term stagnation of the
global
economy. This is because private sector deleveraging with public sector
money
drains economic vitality that will take a long time to work through.
The Cure Worse than
the Disease
It is now
becoming clear that notwithstanding the Fed’s assertion that its
bailouts
prevented a systemic melt down of global financial markets, the cure of
saving
the banking sector at the expense of the economy is looking more like a
cure
worse than the disease. A faster recovery might have been the net bonus
if the
banks were left to go belly up on their own.
As it happened,
the panic rescue by central banks left the global economy a fate of a
lost
decade. This is critical because economic recovery and the existing
international financial architecture depends on a high rate of growth.
And
three years after the outbreak of the global financial crisis that
began in mid
July 2007, the global economy is still plagued by high unemployment and
stagnation despite massive amount of liquidity injection by center
banks.
Sovereign Debt
Denominated in Foreign
Currency
To make matters
worse, all trading economies, particularly the exporting emerging
market
economies, that denominate their debts in one of the two prime reserve
currencies for international trade, such as the dollar and the euro,
will find
critically needed counter cyclical monetary measures unavailable to
their
governments because their central banks cannot issue dollars or euros,
thus
have to earn more dollars or euros from the global trading system at a
time
when the global economy has been condemned to suffer demand deficit
with a
decade of economic decline engineered by central bank monetary measures
to save
the banking sector in the advanced economies. These emerging economies
also
cannot borrow more dollars or euros from global capital and debt
markets
because their credit ratings are being cut by suddenly less-permissive
credit
rating agencies. They invariably become financial wards of the stronger
economies and prisoners of the International Monetary Fund (IMF)
conditionalities.
A Complex Rescue Plan
for Europe with
a Special Purpose Vehicle
A European official told CNBC on the sideline of the IMF
meeting in Washington on
Saturday,
September 17, 2011 that the
EU is working on a detailed plan aimed at shoring up the stability of
European
banks.
The plan appears to involve a complex flow of funds. It
would involve money from the European Financial Stability Facility
(EFSF), a
bailout vehicle created in 2010 to alleviate the sovereign
debt crisis in Europe,
to
capitalize a special purpose vehicle (SPV) that would be created by the
European Investment Bank (EIB),
the
European Union’s finance institution. EFSF shareholders are the 27
member
states of the EU, which have jointly subscribed its capital. The Board
of
Governors of the EIB is composed of the finance ministers of these 27
member
states.
The role of the
EIB in this plan is to provide long-term financing in support of
investment
projects. The SPV serves the purpose of
isolating the parent (EIB) from financial risk of the plan, a device
commonly used in complex financing to separate different layers of
equity
infusion.
The EIB’s SPV would issue bonds to investors and use the
proceeds to purchase sovereign debt of distressed eurozone member
states from
their state central banks. The hope is that this would alleviate the
pressure
on the financially distressed member states and on the eurozone banks
(primarily French and German banks) that hold a lot of the distressed
sovereign
debt. The bonds issued by EIB’s SPV could then be used by the EIB as
collateral
for borrowing from the European Central Bank (ECB), allowing the member
state central
banks to make loans to commercial banks faced with liquidity shortages.
Banks loaded down with distressed eurozone sovereign debt
would be able to sell the debt to the EIB’s SPV financed by the ECB
with the
distressed sovereign debts as collaterals at full face value so that
eurozone
commercial banks can access the liquidity facilities of the ECB.
Although the structure is complex, the underlying objective
is relatively simple. Banks would essentially be allowed to exchange
their distressed
sovereign debt at face value for debt issued by a special purpose
vehicle
created by the EIB capitalized with funds from the EFSF.
In some ways, this resembles the original plan for the
Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) used by the Federal Reserve on
2008. As
originally conceived, the TARP would have purchased “toxic securities”
from
banks. (This plan was abandoned when U.S.
regulators concluded that it was too difficult to price the securities
and that
the plan would take too long to implement.) In the European case, the
“toxic
securities” would be distressed sovereign debt rather than securitized
mortgage
bonds.
Plan to Stabilize
Banks Holding Eurozone Sovereign Debt
Over the weekend of September 17, finance leaders from
around the world met in the annual IFM/World Bank conference in Washington
to discuss the global economic state of affairs. At this meeting
European finance
ministers said that they would take bolder steps to fight the sovereign
debt
crisis, which is plaguing recovery of the global economy.
A focal point for the European officials is the stabilization
European commercial banks, which have been under a heavy market
pressure.
European commercial banks, particularly French and German banks, hold
significant amounts of sovereign debt from the peripheral eurozone
member
states, know as PIIGS (Portugal,
Italy,
Ireland,
Greece
and Spain).
Concern over Greek sovereign default is threatening a European banking
crisis.
European TARP
Suggestions have surface for Europe to deal with this
possible banking crisis by creating a plan similar to that of the US
TARP
program of 2008, following the collapse of the US housing market and
the
bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers, “Troubled Asset Relief Program” (TARP)
was
created by the US government to strengthen financial institutions.
Under TARP
$700 billion of capital was injected into US banks.
For a EuroTARP, it is estimated that at least $202 billion of capital
will need
to be injected into the European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF) to
purchase
distressed sovereign debt from the European commercial banks. The hope
is that
this would alleviate the pressure on the peripheral European member
states and
on the European commercial banks.
Ambereen Choudhury, an analyst at JP Morgan
Cazenove, a leading investment bank
focused on mergers &
acquisitions, debt and equity placements and equity research and
distribution
based in the UK, wrote in a report issued on September 26, 2011 that eurozone banks need at least €150 billion ($202 billion) of
capital provided through a Europe wide Troubled Asset Relief Program
akin to
the U.S. plan.
“We assume Euro-Tarp rather than specific support only for
the most distressed institutions, as we believe a general solution is
required
to restore general confidence and reopen the funding markets for all
institutions,” Choudhury said in the report. Goodman Sates president
Gary Con said
that modeling a European financial rescue on TARP “would be a good
solution.”
Higher Leverage as
Cure for High Leverage
One question is what the JP Morgan Cazenove approach would
mean for the balance sheet of the EFSF, which already carries committed
emergency
loans to Ireland,
Portugal
and Greece.
It is expected to provide over €100 billion ($134.9 billion) in
additional
funding for a Greek bailout. After committed loans, the Fed’s war
chest will
be down to about €298 billion ($402 billion). German Finance Minister
Wolfing
Schaeuble said on Monday, September 19, that there is no plan to expand
the
EFSF.
This plan will catapult the EFSF into the category of a highly
leveraged fund, which borrows more than its equity capital provided by
EU
member governments. No official plans have been released. Details of
the structure
will change as European policymakers fight over the best course of
action from
the perspective of their different national interest.
Many of the proposed options to expand further the €440
billion ($596 billion) European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF)
have problems,
including opposition from countries like Germany, which fears a replay
of its
disastrous inflationary monetary policies of the 1920s during the
Weimar
Republic.
Meanwhile, euro zone officials played down rumor on Monday,
September 19, of emerging plans to cut by half Greece’s sovereign debts
and to
recapitalize European banks to cope with the fallout, stressing that no
such
scheme is on the table yet.
Rough calculations suggest the EFSF, which borrows its funds
from credit markets backed by guarantees from eurozone member states,
might
cope with a bailout of Spain
but that it would not have enough financial power if Italy
needed help.
The EFSF is already committed to providing €17.7 billion ($24
billion) in emergency loans to Ireland
and €26 billion ($35.3 billion) to Portugal.
In addition, the EFSF takes over the remainder of Europe’s
contribution to an initial bailout of Greece,
which is likely to require around €25 billion ($34 billion), and is
expected to
provide two-thirds of a €109 billion ($147.7 billion) second bailout of
Greece.
Taken together, the EFSF’s current commitments total at
least €142 billion ($193 billion), leaving it €298 billion ($405
billion). A
package for Spain
might top €290 billion ($395 billion), while a rescue bill for Italy
could total almost €490 billion ($666 billion).
If Greece
defaults on its sovereign debt, contagion will spread to cause
sovereign
defaults by all the other PIIGS governments and a massive failure in
financial
markets world wide.
Some suggest doubling the funding of EFSF, while others talk
of boosting it to “several trillion”. But the way to restore
confidence, which
will be determined by the reaction of already stressed markets, goes
beyond
simple mathematics.
Greece only a Detonator of European Sovereign Debt Bomb
The sovereign debt default haunting Europe
has its detonator in Greece,
one of the smallest yet most heavily indebted economies in Europe.
Greece,
while
not a poor country, desperately needs a next aid payment of $11 billion
to
avoid running out of cash within weeks, but negotiations between the
Greek
government and the “troika” of the European Union, European Central
Bank, and
International Monetary Fund have stalled. The problem is no one
believes that
the next payment of $11 billion will by itself solve Greece’s
sovereign debt problem. Considered unthinkable not too long ago, a
Greek
default now seems imminent — a subsequent exit from the eurozone no
longer
improbable.
Orderly Default
Option
Talks of a potential “orderly default” of Greek sovereign
debt have emerged, even suggestions of a Greek exit from the eurozone
as a
possible scenario. Time is running out for continuing indecision and
denial. In
the end, the governments of the stronger economies, such as Germany and
France,
will have to step up to the plate, as their economies had the most to
lose from
a wave of falling dominos of sovereign debt default in the eurozone.
French and German
Responsibility
In many ways, France
and Germany
were responsible for the sad state of affair facing eurozone
governments today.
Financial stability in the eurozone had been guaranteed by the euro
convergence
criteria as spelled out in the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) are:
1. Inflation rates:
No more than 1.5 percentage points higher than the average
of the three best performing (lowest inflation) member states of the
EU.
2. Government finance:
Annual government fiscal deficit:
The ratio of the annual government fiscal deficit to GDP
must not exceed 3% at the end of the preceding fiscal year. If not, it
is at
least required to reach a level close to 3%. Only exceptional and
temporary
excesses would be granted for exceptional cases.
Government debt:
The ratio of gross government debt to GDP must not exceed
60% at the end of the preceding fiscal year. Even if the target cannot
be
achieved due to the specific conditions, the ratio must have
sufficiently
diminished and must be approaching the reference value at a
satisfactory pace.
3. Exchange rate:
Applicant countries should have joined the exchange rate
mechanism (ERM II) under the European Monetary System (EMS) for two
consecutive
years and should not have devaluated its currency during the period.
4. Long-term interest rates:
The nominal long-term interest rate must not be more than 2
percentage points higher than in the three lowest inflation member
states.
Had these criteria set by the Stability and Growth Pact
(SGP) been observed, it is unlikely that eurozone governments would
face
any sovereign debt crisis today. Ironically, the watering down of the
SGP, which led to the current sovereign debt crisis in the
eurozone, had
been at the request of Germany
and France, two of the strongest of the then 16 eurozone member states.
Eurozone financial markets had been imitating the rush to phantom
wealth
creation through synthetic structured finance and debt securitization
invented
by fearless young traders in New York
and London working with
money
provided by loose monetary measures of all central banks led the
Federal
Reserve.
In March 2005, the EU’s Economic and Financial Affairs
Council (ECOFIN), under the pressure of France
and Germany,
relaxed SPG rules to respond to criticisms of insufficient flexibility
and to
make the pact more enforceable. Permissiveness infested the European
theoretical regulatory framework, following the US
example.
ECOFIN, one of the oldest configurations of the Council of the European
Union,
is composed of the Economic and Finance Ministers of the 27 European
Union
member states, as well as Fiscal Budget Ministers when budgetary issues
are
discussed.
The EU Council covers a number of EU policy areas, such as economic
policy
coordination, economic surveillance, monitoring of member state
budgetary
policies and public finances, the shape of the euro (legal, practical
and
international aspects), financial markets and capital movements and
economic
relations with third countries. It also prepares and adopts every year,
together with the European Parliament, the budget of the European Union
which
is about €100 billion ($136 billion).
The Council meets once a month and makes decisions mainly by qualified
majority, in consultation or co-decision with the European Parliament,
with the
exception of fiscal matters which are decided by unanimity. When the
ECOFIN
examines dossiers related to the euro and EMU, the representatives of
the
member states whose currency is not the euro do not take part in the
vote of
the Council.
At the urging of Germany
and France,
the
ECONFIN agreed on a reform of the SGP. The ceilings of 3% for budget
deficit
and 60% for public debt were maintained, but the decision to declare a
country
in excessive deficit can now rely on certain new parameters: the
behavior of
the cyclically adjusted budget, the level of debt, the duration of the
slow
growth period and the possibility that the deficit is related to
productivity-enhancing procedures. The pact is part of a set of Council
Regulations,
decided upon the European Council Summit 22-23 March 2005.
Greece a Victim of Structured Finance
Greece fell into the euro debt trap by yielding to the
temptation of structured finance, the instruments of which were first
developed
in the US and adopted by US transnational financial institutions such
as
Goldman Sachs, Citibank, JPMorgan Chase and Bank of America to generate
phenomenal profit for them in deregulated global markets fueled by
floods of
dollar-denominated liquidity release by the Federal Reserve, the US
central bank, through the virtual transaction of synthetic derivatives
known as
synthetic collateralized debt obligations (CDO).
This new game of phantom wealth creation was soon joined by
copycats in Europe such as Barclay,
Société Générale,
Deutsche Bank and ING. Such synthetic instruments were designed to,
among other
things, help banks hide their liabilities by pushing them off their
balance
sheets and thus lowering their capital requirement to increase profit
from
expanded loan-making to yield higher return on capital.
(Please see my May 9, 2007 AToL article: Liquidity
Boom
and Looming Crisis, written and published two months before the
credit
crisis first imploded in New York in July 2007.)
Later, expanding from the private sector, such schemes were sold to EMU
member
governments to help them mask their true public debt levels to skirt
strict EMU
rules, in order to engage in permanent monetary easing. Across the
eurozone, in
obscure and opaque over-the-counter (OTC) derivative deals that traded
directly
between counterparties off exchanges between “special purpose vehicles”
(SPV),
and designed to help governments legally skirt EMU criteria,
transnational
banks provided Eurozone governments with cash upfront in return for
future
payments by government. Such payments would reduce government fiscal
revenue
since the revenue from collateral assets has been pledged to investors
of CDOs.
The liabilities were taken off their national balance sheets to present
a
healthy picture of national finance, until the government is forced to
make up
the revenue shortfall in a recession.
Thus it is hypocrisy of the extreme for Germany to hold
Greece hostage with demand of severe fiscal austerity that will lead to
socio-political instability, by asserting disingenuously that Germans
work
harder than Greeks, and that the German government is fiscally more
responsible
than the Greek government, and that Greece cannot expect German
taxpayers to bail
out Greece from a decade of poor public finance, made possible by
German
influence on diluting the criteria of the SPG.
Goldman Doing God’s
Work Again
Wall Street is directly responsible for Greece’s
public finance predicament. In 2005, Goldman Sachs, doing what its
chairman told
Congress as “God’s work”,
sold interest rate swaps it created to the
National
Bank of Greece (NBG), the country’s largest bank. In 2008, Goldman
Sachs helped
NGB put the swap denominated in euros into a legal special purpose
vehicle
(SPV) called Titlos. National then
retained the bonds that Titlos issued
as collateral to borrow even more euros from the European Central Bank
(ECB)
and in turn from international banks. The swap will be costly and
unprofitable
for the Greek government through its long contract term, while Goodman
profited
handsome in fees up front.
Appropriately, in Greek manuscripts, the titlo was
often used to mark the place where a scribe accidentally skipped the
letter, if
there was no space to draw the missed letter above. SPV Titlos
performed the special purpose of skipping the sovereign
liability Greece
had assumed in order to get more loans from the ECB and international
banks
than was permitted under SPG criteria. Such SPV deals were not made
public even
though Titlos obligations are among
the weak links in Greek public finance in 2010. Information on them
finally
trickled out only through government investigations and media
investigative
reporting.
Der Spiegel reported in early January 2010 that
Goldman Sachs two years
earlier had helped the government of Greece
cover up part of its huge fiscal deficit via a currency swap deal name Titlos, which used artificially high
exchange rates. A report commissioned by the Greek Finance Ministry
released on February 1, 2010,
revealed
that Greece
had
used swaps to defer interest repayments by several years.
On February 15, 2010,
Bloomberg reported a Greek government inquiry uncovered a series of
swaps
agreements with securities firms that allowed it to mask its growing
public
debts. The document did not identify the securities firms Greece
used. But the former head of Greece’s
Public Debt Management Agency told Bloomberg that the government turned
to
Goldman Sachs in 2002 to obtain $1 billion through a swap agreement.
(Please see my AToL series on GLOBAL
POST-CRISIS ECONOMIC OUTLOOK:
Part XII: Financial Globalization and
Recurring Financial Crises
Part XI:
Comparing Eurozone Membership
to Dollarization of Argentina
Part X: The Trillion Dollar
Failure
Part IX: Effect of the Greek
Crisis on German Domestic Politics
Part VIII: Greek Tragedy
Part VII: Global Sovereign Debt
Crisis
Part VI:
Public Debt and Other
Issues
Part
V: Public Debt, Fiscal Deficit and Sovereign Insolvency
In these articles, I warned against the danger of SPVs that
would eventual put Greece
into a disastrous sovereign debt crisis.)
Political Hurdles
The fundamental decisions over the future
of the European monetary
union will be politically difficult, and they will be costly for the
richer
economies. The costs of not acting decisively now, however, are going
to be
even higher. The urgency in bailing out Greece
is the contagion on Spain
and Italy
should Greece
defaults, and through these economies to the US
and Asia.
This fact is
validated by the blunt warning from US Treasury Secretary Timothy
Geithner on
Friday, September 16 to eurozone
finance ministers at a closed meeting of in Wroclaw, Poland. Geithner
told the
Europeans to stop political bickering and take control of the financial
aspects
of the debt crisis
that has brought “catastrophic risk” to global financial markets.
Geithner Warns Europe
Mr. Geithner reportedly said on the sideline of the
ministerial meeting: “What’s very damaging is not just seeing the
divisiveness
in the debate over strategy in Europe but the
ongoing
conflict between countries and the [European] central bank”, adding
that
“governments and central banks need to take out the catastrophic risk
to
markets.”
Geithner’s presence at the meeting of EU financial ministers underlined
the
concerned of the US
government about the danger of financial contagion from the eurozone
sovereign
debt and banking crisis and its negative
effect on the fragile economic recovery in the US
and other parts of the world, including Asia.
In a blunt
warning that reflected Washington’s growing concern, Secretary Geithner
urged
European leaders to halt a months-long clash with the European Central
Bank and
argued that the EU’s growing reliance on foreign lenders would imperil
the zone’s
ability to control its own destiny.
“What is very
damaging [in Europe] from the outside is not the divisiveness about the
broader
debate, about strategy, but about the ongoing conflict between
governments and
the central bank, and you need both to work together to do what is
essential to
the resolution of any crisis,” Mr Geithner said on the sidelines of a
meeting
of eurozone finance ministers in Wroclaw, Poland on Friday, September
16.
“Governments and
central banks have to take out the catastrophic risk from markets… [and
avoid]
loose talk about dismantling the institutions of the euro,” he added.
Mr Geithner’s
comments came as the Europe’s finance ministers agreed to withhold an
€8 billion loan
payment to Greece, a move that could leave Athens scrambling to satisfy
its
lenders before it runs out of cash.
European Response
George Osborns,
UK chancellor, echoed Mr Geithner’s comments, telling Sky news on
Saturday,
September 18, that “people know that time is running out, that the
eurozone
needs to show it can get a grip on the situation.”
However, some
eurozone finance ministers hit back at Mr Geithner’s comments,
questioning the
usefulness of his visit. “I found it
peculiar that even though the Americans have significantly worse
fundamental
data than the eurozone, that they tell us what we should do and when we
make a
suggestion ... that they say no straight away,” said Maria Fekter,
Austria’s
finance minister.
Sweden’s Anders
Borg said: “we need to make progress, but it’s quite clear the US has a
big
debt problem and the situation would be better if the US could show a
sustainable way forward.”
The eurozone’s
more fiscally prudent governments – particularly Germany and the
Netherlands -
are keen to prove to their voters that they were forcing Greece to
comply with
the deep fiscal budget cuts and other reforms it promised when it
accepted a
€109 billion rescue package last year.
Several eurozone
ministers also dismissed a US suggestion to give additional flexibility
to the
eurozone’s €440 billion rescue fund, re-opening trans-Atlantic fissures
over
fiscal
and economic policy.
Markets Respond
Negatively to EU Postponement on
Decision
Finance ministers
of the EU extended the time frame to approve a revamp of the €440
billion rescue
fund that was agreed by heads of member state in July. After predicting
that
all 17 governments of eurozone member states would ratify the changes
by the
end of this September, they are now expecting the process to drag on
until
mid-October.
Some eurozone ministers expressed unhappiness with Mr Geithner’s
comments about Europe ending divisions as such
comments actually opened
up new divisions.
Austria's
Finance Minister Maria Fekter, one eurozone politician at the meeting
who
voiced her objection to Mr Geithner's comments, said: “I found it
peculiar that
even though the Americans have significantly worse fundamental
[economic] data
than the eurozone, that they tell us what we should do.” She was
referring to US
high national debt and the recurring trade and fiscal deficits, not
mentioning
the political standoff in Congress over the increase of the national
debt
ceiling.
Joe
Quinlan & Peter Sparding in
Real Clear World gave the following analysis on Impact of a Eurozone
Default on the Transatlantic Economy. Joe Quinlan is a Transatlantic
Fellow at the German Marshall Fund. Peter Sparding is a Program Officer
with the Economic Policy Program of the German Marshall Fund in
Washington.
Yet
the September 17 weekend meeting of the 17 eurozone
finance ministers in Poland,
instead of calming markets, only increased market concerns. The meeting
produced little in the way of concrete proposals to deal with Greece’s
acute funding issues and the risks of financial contagion.
Too Little, Too Late
Only two months after a second bailout was agreed to by
European leaders, and amid new data indicating that the Greek economy
is
shrinking at a faster rate than expected, the size of rescue packages
currency
being discussed already seems to be inadequate. Furthermore, a number
of
indicators suggest the markets have already begun to discount a default
—
yields on Greek bonds have soared to record highs, while the price for
credit-default swaps to insure Greek debt has rocketed. Many hedge
funds are
poised to make a killing on a Greek sovereign default.
Despite these punishing moves by investors who react with
incomplete and unsubstantiated information, markets may still be
under-pricing
the total cost of a Greek default. A default on this scale is
unprecedented,
and its potentially widespread ramifications are unknown. Markets can
limit
some of their risk, but it is far from certain that an actual default
would not
lead to further panic and turmoil.
Life After Default
Scenarios for a Greek default could include a run on banks
in Greece
and
in the rest of the world. Capital, people, goods, and other
transportable
assets would likely leave Greece
and the eurozone. Hoarding of physical cash and delays in payments
among international
banks and multinational corporations could be expected.
A Greek exit from the monetary zone might become an
unavoidable next step. The risk of redenomination of government debt
and
currency depreciation would then result in higher borrowing costs or
even being
frozen out of debt and capital market. With the cost of capital very
high over
the medium term, or capital and credit
unavailable at any price, the new/old
currency likely being extremely weak and thus highly inflationary, a
painful
and prolonged period of no or negative economic growth for Greece and
the
eurozone seems unavoidable.
The pain would also be felt elsewhere in the eurozone as
suspicion and mistrust on credit worthiness among banks would curtail
lending.
Other perceived weak economies, such as Portugal,
Ireland,
or
even Spain
and Italy
would swiftly be “tested” by financial markets. Despite what some in
the
creditor countries might hope for, Greece’s
default and/or exit from the common currency would thus not signal the
end of
the crisis, but instead would add even more pressure on stronger
countries to
come up with a “Big Bang” solution.
Impact on the US
For the US,
developments in Europe should be reason for
serious
concern. While not as heavily invested in Greek debt, US banks are
somewhat
more exposed in Ireland
and Spain.
The US
would have to try to insulate its financial system from shocks in Europe
in order to protect its own already battered banking sector and its
economy. To
avoid a potential default-induced financial crisis, the Federal Reserve
has
already expanded its swap operations with the European Central Bank,
and it may
have to do more. (end of analysis)
On September 18, 2011,
the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) authorized a $180 billion
expansion of
its temporary reciprocal currency arrangements (swap lines).
According to the Fed’s press release, the changes allow for
“increases in the
existing swap lines with the ECB and the Swiss National Bank”
and for
“new swap facilities…with the Bank of Japan, the Bank of England, and
the Bank
of Canada.” These measures “…are designed to improve the liquidity
conditions
in global financial markets,” the release said.
An underlying aspect of a currency swap is that banks (and businesses)
around the world have assets and liabilities not only in their home
currency,
but also in dollars. Thus, banks in eurozone need funding in dollars as
well as
in euros. However, Europeans banks recently have been reluctant to lend
to one
another. Some observers believe this reluctance relates to uncertainty
about
the assets that other banks have on their balance sheets or because a
bank
might be uncertain about its own short-term cash needs. Whatever the
cause,
this reluctance in the interbank market has pushed up the premium for
short-term dollar funding and has been evident in a sharp escalation in
LIBOR
rates.
The currency swap lines were designed to inject liquidity, which can
help
bring rates down. The bottom line is that the Fed, by exchanging
dollars for
foreign currency, has helped to provide liquidity to banks around the
world.
This effort can help to bring interbank rates back down at a time when
restrictively high rates can choke off access to financing that
European banks
and other businesses need to operate. The swap might also be needed to
provide
Federal Reserve dollars for US branches of European banks and jawbone
US banks
and money market funds to not withdraw their funds from Europe.
However, even if the U.S.
financial sector somehow managed to insulate itself from the risk of
financial
contagion, the impact on corporate America
would be severe. Europe accounts for over
one-fifth of
world GDP and one-quarter of global personal consumption. Just over
half of
corporate America’s
non-US revenue comes from Europe.
Geithner Warns Europe
Against this backdrop, it is no wonder that U.S. Treasury
Secretary Timothy Geithner warned this weekend of “catastrophic risks”
if Europe
failed to rise to this challenge. Indeed, the time to find a “good”
outcome for Europe’s crisis has passed. It is
time to acknowledge
that any solution now will be costly. In the short term, this includes
strengthening European banks and extending further support to
distressed
countries.
Another failure to act decisively contains unforeseeable
risk and is likely to come at a much higher price — and not only for Europe.
Secretary Geithner did not mince words. The fallout from a Greek
default, the
risks of the eurozone disintegrating, the systemic risks of a European
banking
crisis, the aftershocks to the U.S. economy — any or all of these
events could
ultimately prove catastrophic for an already fragile transatlantic
economy and
transatlantic partnership.
Turning EFSF into a
Bank
The Centre for European Policy Studies, a think tank in Brussels,
proposed increasing EFSF’s funding by is to turn it into a bank. This means the Luxembourg-based entity could
lend money to financially distressed eurozone member with loans from
the ECB to
refinance such loans rather than having to rely solely on its limited
capital
base.
As a bank, the EFSF could lend up to ten times its capital
even in this difficult market, which would mean the €440 billion of
capital in
the facility could in theory be transformed into more than €4 trillion
of bailout
funds.
But the reality is more complex. The EFSF would raise funds from
the ECB relative to the quality of the collateral it puts up. Such
collateral
financial instruments are distressed government bonds that have low
ratings
because of high risk of default. This means that by definition, the
EFSF can
never raise sufficient bail out funds based on the distressed sovereign
debts
without a market discount plus a haircut imposed by the ECB. An
under-funded
EFSF that cannot buy distressed debt as face value cannot perform its
role as a
restorer of market confidence.
But it is political opposition rather than financial
obstacles that poses the biggest and perhaps insurmountable difficulty.
German
Bundesbank chief Jens Weidmann has expressed his concern that the ECB
itself may
already be overextending.
The eurozone’s central banks and the ECB have a combined
capital base of €82 billion. It has already lent €535 billion to banks
and
bought a further €150 billion of government bonds to prop up the
depressed market.
Opposition from Germany and
ECB
So far, Germany,
the euro zone’s deep pocket funding source, and the ECB, the lender of
last
resort, are both opposed to the idea of turning the EFSF into a bank,
suggesting the idea has little chance of becoming reality.
By Sunday, September 25, German finance minister Wolfgang
Schaeuble said he was looking into alternatives to the EFSF-bank
option. One alternative
would be to use the EFSF to insure investors against losses from buying
Italian
or Spanish banks. The EFSF would issue “credit enhancements” for new
bonds that
could cover potential losses, cutting the risk for bondholders.
EFSF as Insurer
Such a scheme would not help Greece,
said Sony Kapoor, a financial expert who advocated the model, but would
set up
a contagion “firewall” for Italy
and Spain
that
would allow them tap money markets even if Greece
were to default.
“This could take the form of the EFSF offering insurance
against, say, the first 20 percent of any losses on these ... and would
enable
the EFSF to bring down the borrowing costs for Italy and Spain for the
next 3
years or more,” Kapoor, the managing director of think tank Re-Define
told CNBC.
“Lowering the borrowing costs for Italy
and Spain
is a
necessary step before any restructuring of Greek debt can be seriously
contemplated, said Kapoor, “The options being discussed are primarily
about
policymakers, who believe that Italy
and Spain
are
fundamentally solvent, calling the markets’ bluff that they are not.”
Unlike the EFSF as it is currently constituted, the European
Stability Mechanism (ESM) is permanent and has a pool of capital of €80
billion
($108.8 billion), paid in by countries in the same way as they do with
the ECB.
Starting the ESM in July 2012, rather than July 2013 as
planned, could reassure investors because it provides a second lever to
support
markets alongside the ECB. However, German chancellor Angela Merkel and
other
leaders have to convince eurozone member state legislators to back
their pledge
to allow the EFSF to extend loans to eurozone member state whose
sovereign
bonds faces default or to buy sovereign bonds to prop up struggling
eurozone
member states.
Merkel’s Domestic
Political Problem
German Chancellor Angela Merkel said on Sunday (September
18): “Allowing Greece to default on its debt now would destroy investor
confidence in the euro zone and might spark contagion like that
experienced
after the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers in 2008. We need to take steps
we can
control,” Merkel said, drawing a parallel between the Greek situation
and that
of Lehman, whose bankruptcy helped trigger the global financial crisis,
“What
we can’t do is destroy the confidence of all investors mid-course and
get a
situation where they say that if we’ve done it for Greece, we will also
do it
for Spain, for Belgium, or any other country. Then not a single person
would
put their money in Europe anymore.”
In a one-hour interview on the euro zone crisis with popular
German talk show host Guenther Jauch, Merkel said she relied on the
view of the International Monetary Fund when
assessing how to handle Greece.
“As long as the IMF was convinced Greece’s
debt was sustainable, then she supported that position,” she said.
Merkel also made clear that she did not view a parliamentary
vote in Germany
on Thursday (September 15) on the euro
zone’s rescue mechanism as “make-or-brake” for her government. Because
opposition parties support giving new powers to the European Financial
Stability Facility (EFSF), passage is not in question.
But some German politicians have suggested that if Merkel
fails to win a majority with the conservative parties in her coalition
— known
in Germany
as a
“chancellor majority” — she should dissolve parliament and call new
elections.
"We are talking about a law here, a completely normal
law. The government needs a majority. The chancellor majority is what
you need
when you are voted in as chancellor, or in other special personnel
cases,” Merkel
said. "I want my own majority and I will fight for this.” She also said
she
was “appalled” at a lack of progress from the Group of 20 countries in
forging
a consensus on regulating banks and dealing with the "too big to
fail" problem.
Christian Wulff,
who owes his job as Germany’s president to Mrs Merkel, complained that
the
financial markets are pushing governments around. Politics must “regain
its
ability to act,” he demanded.
The euro crisis
is Merkel’s trial by ordeal. She has tried to help indebted euro
members states
while refusing to write blank cheques on German tax money. But the
markets have
repeatedly tested that approach, requiring ever larger and more
elaborate
bail-outs. Now, Germany’s increasingly skeptical Bundestag (lower house
of
parliament) is about to weigh in. This month (September) it will
consider
legislation to approve expanded powers for the European Financial
Stability
Facility (EFSF), a temporary fund for helping the indebted euro
countries.
After that it will vote on a second bail-out of Greece, worth about
€109
billion ($157 billion), and then on a permanent successor to the EFSF.
Resistance, much
of it from Mrs Merkel’s coalition, is stiffening. Dissenters have two
main
worries. The first is that the Bundestag will be stripped of its right
to
determine how taxpayers’ money is spent. They expect encouragement on
September
7th from a ruling by the constitutional court on the legality of the
first Greek
bail-out and the EFSF. The court is not expected to overturn the
measures, but
may reinforce the Bundestag’s authority over budgetary matters. The
trick will
be to do that without paralyzing the institutions being set up to deal
with
euro crises.
The second fear
is that Germany will end up pouring even more money into countries that
are
unwilling or unable to solve their own fiscal problems. The rescue
measures
“will certainly buy time,” says Wolfgang Bosbach, a CDU leader in the
Bundestag
who is normally loyal to Mrs Merkel. “But I fear they won’t solve the
problem
permanently, so there will have to be more aid.” Greece’s problem is
not lack
of credit; it is lack of competitiveness, he believes.
There are enough
pro-rescue votes in the Bundestag to pass the legislation (the main
opposition
parties favour even more generous measures, such as issuing Eurobonds
jointly
guaranteed by euro-zone governments). The question is whether the
“chancellor
majority” will suffice to enact the package without opposition votes.
If the
majority buckles, Mrs Merkel would be weakened, perhaps fatally. The
government
could collapse, two years before elections are scheduled. But this
seems
unlikely. None of the coalition parties is keen to face elections now.
The FDP,
which harbors some vocal skeptics, might not even re-enter the
Bundestag. Mr
Bosbach expects the chancellor’s majority to hold up, though he does
not plan
to join it.
Belatedly, Mrs
Merkel is starting to counter the threat. She will try to placate the
CDU’s
base in a series of regional meetings and has set up a commission to
fashion a
party consensus on the euro. Her rhetoric now sometimes throbs with
un-Merkel-like fervor. “Europe is the most important thing we have,”
she says
(though not in Schwerin). Other CDU leaders are sounding Europhile
notes not
heard for some time (without providing much detail or any timetable).
Ursula
von der Leyen, the labor minister, calls for a “United States of
Europe”.
Mrs Merkel may
recover from her mid-term slump. Though CDU traditionalists grumble
about her
leadership, they have no one capable of challenging her. Rising stars
like Mrs
von der Leyen are modernisers like the chancellor herself. “There is no
alternative centre of power” within the party, says Gerd Langguth of
the
University of Bonn. With luck, Mrs Merkel will have two years to
persuade
voters, also, to see the brighter side of things.
Geithner Pushed Europe
Again
Treasury Secretary Timothy Geithner told European government
officials bluntly on Saturday,
September 24, 2011, to eliminate the threat of a
catastrophic
financial crisis by teaming up with the European Central bank to boost
the
continent’s bailout capacity.
Geithner, in his most explicit language to date, said fiscal
authorities should work more closely with the ECB to ensure that
euro-area
governments with sound policies have access to affordable financing and
to
ensure that European banks have adequate capital and liquidity to
weather the
crisis.
"The threat of cascading default, bank runs, and
catastrophic risk must be taken off the table, as otherwise it will
undermine
all other efforts, both within Europe and
globally.
Decisions as to how to conclusively address the region's problems
cannot wait
until the crisis gets more severe," Geithner said.
Geithner has been lobbying for weeks for European officials
to leverage their €440
billion ($603 billion) European Financial
Stability
Fund through the ECB to increase its capacity. His statement suggests
that he
wants Europe to employ the ECB's balance sheet
in the
same manner as the Federal Reserve did with Treasury capital during the
2008-09
financial crisis.
The Treasury in 2008 pledged $20 billion in capital to allow
the Federal Reserve to lend $200 billion to restart credit markets
frozen by
the financial crisis.
Geithner said that because inflation risks were largely less
acute, some central banks had room to further ease policy, keep rates
lower
longer and slow the pace of expected tightening.
He and Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke met on Friday,
September 16, in Washington
with
top officials from the European Central Bank and some national central
banks
from Europe, in part to discuss international
financial
regulatory reform.
Geithner said US
growth needed additional support from the Obama administration's $447
billion
tax-cut and spending package to boost jobs growth. Without this, fiscal
policy
would shrink too quickly and likely cause U.S.
growth to be below potential in 2012.
“Fiscal policy everywhere has to be guided by the
imperatives of growth," he said. Geithner also said that the IMF is still falling short in
assessing exchange rate policies and should itself be subject to more
scrutiny.
“The Fund's surveillance would benefit from the publication
of an External Stability Report that provides a frank assessment of
exchange
rate misalignment and excessive reserves accumulation and progress
being made
in reducing global imbalances," Geithner said. "We call on the IMF to
set forth a strong and comprehensive set of proposals to address these
deficiencies.”
On September 29, 2011,
the German Parliament approved the expansion of the bailout
fund for heavily indebted European countries, the most important step
in a
tortuous process that has rattled markets and raised doubts about the
ability
of governments to react to the expanding debt crisis.
September 29, 2011
Next: The Role of the IMF/ECB/EC Troika
|
|