These search terms are highlighted: henryckliustagnant
Development
Through
Wage-Led Growth
By
Henry C.K. Liu
Part I: Stagnant
Worker Wage Income Leads to Overcapacity
This article appeared in AToL on
November 24, 2010
In the economics of development, there is an iron-clad rule
that “income is all”. The rule states that the effectiveness of
developmental
policies, programs and measures should be evaluated by their effect on
raising
the wage income of workers; and that a low-wage economy is an
underdeveloped
economy because it keeps aggregate consumer demand below its optimum
level,
thus causing overcapacity in the economy that needs to be absorbed by
export.
Workers income is the key factor in generating national
wealth in a country. Export through low-wage production is merely
shipping under-priced
national wealth outside the national border without adequate
compensation, by
under-pricing labor within the nation. During the age of industrial
imperialism, export of manufactured goods was promoted by high-wage
economies
to the low-wage colonies in return for gold-back money, so that more
investment
could be made to provide more jobs for high-wage workers at home. In
post-industrial finance economies, cross-border wage arbitrage in
unregulated
global trade exploits workers in low-wage economies to produce for
consumers in
higher wage economies to earn fiat crrency in the form of the dollar
that cannot be spent in the exporting economy.
Globalization of
Trade Preempts Domestic Development in All Countries
This “income is all” rule has been mostly obscured in
recent decades during which globalized foreign trade promoted by
neoliberals
has pre-empted domestic development as the engine of economic growth in
all
market economies around the world. In today’s game of globalized
international
trade, the new operative rule is that “profit is all” and that high
profit in
competitive export trade requires low domestic wages, even if low local
wages
retard domestic economic development by reducing aggregate purchasing
power in
the domestic market to cause overcapacity that rely on export. As
workers wages
are not sufficient to buy the goods they produce, domestic markets fall
into underdevelopment
and export to high-wage economies is needed to produce profit for
companies.
Excessive Corporate
Profit From Low Wages Leads to Overcapacity
This new rule of globalized trade is designed to produce
short-term maximization of corporate profit for an export sector. But
in the
post industrial finance economy, the export sectors in low-wage
economies are
largely owned or financed by cross-border international capital. This
type of
international trade incurs inevitable long-term stagnation in the
domestic
economies of all trading nations because the low wages paid by
international
capital lead to insufficient aggregate domestic consumer demand.
Stagnant
wages
everywhere in turn reduce aggregate global purchasing power needed for
the
expansion of international trade. It is a clear case of imbalanced
economic
sub-optimization.
Foreign Capital
Invested in International Trade Has No Incentive to Raise Local Wages
The export sector of foreign trade in any economy naturally
does not consider the purchasing power of local workers as being of any
consequence because the goods produced and services provided by local
workers
in the export sector are sold in higher-wage foreign markets for profit
denominated in the reserve currency generally accepted in international
trade,
which since the end of World War II has been the US dollar.
As a result, the import sector in foreign trade in all
economies also underperforms because of insufficient domestic
purchasing power
for both domestic products and needed imports. This is true in varying
degrees
for all economies that participate in international trade. The only
exception
is the US
economy whose gold-backed currency had been generally accepted as the
reserve
currency for international trade since the end of World War II. But the
dollar has
been a fiat currency since 1971 when it was detached from gold.
In the advanced financial economies, consumer debt is used
to overcome stagnant
consumer purchasing power caused by low wages. Low
wages
have been the fundamental cause of recurring debt bubbles in advanced
economies. Even for the US,
cross-border wage arbitrage has also kept US wages stagnant,
which US
policy
makers compensated with a policy of high consumer debt that was
unsustainable
by stagnant
wages. The biggest item in consumer debt is home mortgage.
This
excessive debt in relation to wage income has been the real cause
behind the
current global financial crisis.
Demise of the
Bretton
Woods International Finance Architecture
Towards the end of World War II, an international conference
of the victorious allies was held in the US
at Bretton Woods, New
Hampshire
in 1944 to fashion a post-war international finance architecture in
which the
monetary regime would be based on the dollar as a reserve currency for
international trade, pegged to gold at $35 per ounce. The exchange
rates of currencies
issued by trade-participating governments were fixed and relatively
stable. Currency
exchange settlements were conducted only between central banks. There
was no
open currency trading market as most nations practiced capital control
within
its borders. Economies that incurred persistent trade deficits would
not be
able to devalue their currencies to achieve trade surpluses. Economic
theory at
the time did not view cross-border capital flow as necessary for or
beneficial to
domestic development.
Yet even after the US suspended the dollar’s peg to gold in
1971 in response to the depletion of the amount of gold held by the
Federal
Reserve, the US central bank, due to the country’s persistent trade and
fiscal
deficits, the dollar continues to be accepted by trading nations as the
dominant reserve currency for international trade by default, for lack
of an
alternative reserve currency and because US geopolitical prowess has
managed to
cause trades in basic commodities, most notably oil, to be denominated
in
dollars after 1973.
Today, about 60%
of world currency reserves are denominated in dollars, as compared to
its top
competitor, the Euro, in which only about 24% of world reserves is
denominated.
This is only a technical distinction as all other freely convertible
fiat
currencies are essentially derivatives of the dollar as long as prices
of all
basic commodities are denominated in dollars.
The Dollar now a
Fiat
Currency issued by the World’s Most Indebted Nation
The exchange
value of any fiat currency is a function of the level of outstanding
public
debt owed by, and the quantity of money issued by its government. The
dollar,
the world’s dominent reserve currency for trade, is the fiat currency
of the world’s
most indebted nation. This is because US sovereign debt is denominated
in
dollars, not foreign currencies. The US has no foreign debt, only
sovereign
debt denominated in its own currency held by foreigners.
US public debt
outstanding, or debt owed by the public collectively, is in excess of
$13
trillion in 2010 against a GDP of $14.6 trillion. US public debt
continues to
grow at a rate of about $3.83 billion each day, or $1.4 trillion a
year. Annual
growth of US public debt is at 10%, in excess of its GDP growth at less
than 2%. US
public debt of 100% of GDP in 2010 is in excess of the generally
accepted level
of 60% debt to GDP ratio. Yet the dollar’s reserve currency status for
international trade remains firmly secured, albeit the dollars exchange
rate against
other currencies has been declining steadily since 2002.
Total US Debt
Unsustainably High
Total US public debt
(debt owed collectively by all citizens) and private debt (debt owed
privately
by individuals and by private entities) was $50.2 trillion at the end
of Q1,
2010 or 3.5 times concurrent GDP. What makes US public and private
debts
different from those held by other countries is that all US debts are
denominated in its own currency which the US can issue at will with
little
penalty beside possible devaluation of the dollar’s eschange value.
Total net worth
of the US as a nation stood at $44.2 trillion at the end of Q1, 2010,
about
3.02 times of concurrent GDP. US domestic financial assets totaled $131
trillion and domestic financial liabilities totaled $106 trillion,
leaving a
net worth of $25 trillion, or 1.42 times GDP. Non-financial assets net
worth
totaled $19.2 trillion, or 1.32 times GDP.
Acording
to Federal Reserve data, the total net worth of the United States
remained
between 4.5 and 6 times of annual GDP from 1960 until the 2000s, when
it rose
as high as 6.64 times GDP in 2006, principally due to an increase in
the net
worth of US households from the wealth effect of the housing bubble.
However,
by the end of 2008, the net worth of the United States had declined
sharply
from 6.64 to 5.2 times annual GDP due to the sharp decline in the
market value
of corporate equities and real estate in the wake of the collapse of
the
securitized sub-prime mortgage market and the resultant global
financial crisis. US
household
net worth alone amounted to only 3.55 times annual GDP. This net
worth/GDP ratio does not
accurately reflect US net worth because ehile nominal US GDP has grown
slightly, it has declined after adjusting for inflation since 2007 .
Between 2008 and 2009, the net worth of US households had
recovered slightly from a low of 3.55 times annual GDP to 3.75 times
annual GDP
as a result of government intervention to transfer private debt into
public
debt by the Treasury bailing out too-big-to-fail financial institutions
and by
the Federal Reserve expanding its balance sheet though quantitative
easing. The
median sale price of existing homes is still lower in September 2010
than it
was five years earlier. Before the current recession thatbegan in
mid-2007, home prices
always
increased at a rate of at least 2.5% a year over five-year periods,
meaning the
market price of home doubled every four years during that period of
debt bubble.
The net worth of US non-financial businesses fell from 1.37
times annual GDP in 2008 to 1.22 times as the economy continued to
contract in
2010. As a double dip recession or a drawn out stagnation appears
likely in
2011 because of the ineffectiveness of US
stimulus measures, US total net worth can be expected to decline
further from
the historical low of 3.02 times GDP at the end of Q1, 2010.
The net worth of US households and non-profits has accounted
for 3.5 times of annual GDP since 1980 and has constituted
three-quarters of
total US net worth. Since 1960, until 2008, US households had
consistently held
this net worth position, followed by non-financial businesses (137% of
GDP in
2008) and by state and local governments (50% of GDP in 2008).
The US financial sector, where most of the wealth had been
created in recent decades, has hovered around zero net worth since
1960,
reflecting its high leverage, while the federal government has
fluctuated from
a negative net worth of (-7%) of GDP in 1946, a high of 6% of GDP in
1974, to
-32% of GDP in 2008. While the federal government cannot go bankrupt,
the US
financial sector was technically insolvent for the first third of 2008.
These
weak financial fundamentals will make economic recovery difficult
without
adding to the already excessively high financial leverage in the US
economy.
Stock Prices Affect
Household Wealth More Now than 3 Decades Ago
There was a similar prolonged period of weak stock prices in
the US
in the
1970s, but stocks were far less important component in most US
household wealth at the time. Stocks are more important in US
household wealth makeup now because more people are now seeing their
retirement
as dependent on their own investments in the stock market. That change
inn
personal financial planning had come gradually in recent decades as
fewer
companies offered defined-benefit pension plans and more people had
401(k)
defined contribution plans, which were often invested in stock mutual
funds. By
early 2000 — as the stock market was peaking on its path to a drastic
correction — 43% of household financial assets were in stocks, triple
the
proportion in the mid-1980s. This is why a collapse in the US
equity market was a big hit to US household along with the collapse of
the
housing market.
The wealth of US
families plunged nearly 18% in 2008, erasing years of sharp gains on
housing
and stocks and marking the biggest loss since the Federal Reserve began
keeping
track after World War II. US household net worth tumbled by $11
trillion -- a decline in a single year that equals the combined annual
output
of Germany, Japan and the U.K. The data signal the end of an epoch
defined by widespread
ownership of first and second homes, rising retirement funds and
ever-fatter
portfolios.
Past downturns
have been mere blips compared with the losses Americans faced in 2008,
which
set them back to below 2004 levels. The decline in net worth, which was
the
first in six years, follows an extraordinary boom. Not accounting for
inflation, household wealth more than doubled from 1990 to 2000, and
then,
after a pause, rose nearly 50% before the bust of 2008.
While the market value
of their assets was falling, US total private debt remained roughly
flat. Total household
debt increased by half a percentage point in 2008 as
families
faced tighter lending standards and many started trying harder to live
within
their means. After years of splurging with an eye on their rising
assets, that
phenomenon, known as the wealth effect, now cuts the other way,
spurring frugality.
Collectively, US homeowners
had 43% equity in their homes -- the lowest level since records have
been kept.
Amid foreclosures and tighter lending, the total amount of mortgage
credit was
down last year for the first time since the Fed started keeping track
in 1945.
The recession
that began in December 2007 has reversed a particularly long boom.
The Federal Reserve estimates that US citizens and residents
had $43.8 trillion in financial assets at the end of June, 2010, 15%
below the
figure for June 2007, shortly before the recession began. Standard
& Poor’s
index of 500 stocks in June 2010 remained below where it was five years
earlier
in 2005, 2 years before the market peaked in Q2, 2007.
Auction-Rate
Securities Market Still Frozen
The Wall Street Journal reports on October 30, 2010 that more
than two years after the $330 billion auction-rate securities market
froze—deepening the most severe economic crisis since the Great
Depression—hundreds or possibly thousands of individual investors are
still stuck
holding the securities.
About $130 billion of retail and institutional investor
money remains stranded in the troubled auction rate securities,
according to
SecondMarket, a broker-dealer and secondary market for illiquid assets,
and
they continue to be a drag on companies’ bottom lines.
Auction-rate securities, which were issued by cities,
schools, hospitals and others, are long-term debt instruments that are
resold
with updated interest rates in periodic auctions held by banks. Many
investors
bought them on the advice of their brokers, who often touted them as a
higher-yielding, but still safe, alternatives to cash. Then, in early
2008,
Wall Street dealers abruptly stopped buying the securities at auction
as the
credit market failed.
Since then, dozens of big banks and brokerages have
repurchased billions of dollars of auction-rate securities from
investors in
settlements with regulators. But some investors, such as those who
bought auction-rate
securities at one firm and then moved their accounts to another, have
been left
out of the settlement. And some brokerages that sold auction-rate
securities created
by other firms have not yet settled.
Economies with Trade
Surpluses Are Victims of Dollar Hegemony
As for the exporting economies that regularly sustain trade
surpluses denominated in dollars, such as China and Japan, the trade
surplus
dollars cannot be spent in their domestic economy without causing
inflation
because the wealth behind this surplus has already been shipped outside
the
country as exports. Thus the trade surplus dollars must then be used to
buy US
sovereign debt which in turn allows the US
to buy more imports with dollars it receives from selling sovereign
debt
denominated in dollars and with more new dollars that it can print at
will
without incurring immediate monetary penalty. The US
can run up external debt denominated in dollar without fear of
inflation for
long periods because inflation will be kept tame by low-price imports
from
low-wage exporting economies, such as China’s.
International trade then has been reduced in recent decades
to a game in which the US
makes dollars by fiat and the exporting countries, such as China,
make goods with low wages and environmental abuse that fiat dollars can
buy.
This dysfunctional monetary arrangement in international trade is known
as
dollar hegemony. (Please see my 2002 article on Dollar Hegemony for
more
details.)
Rise of the Foreign
Exchange Market
The rules of the Bretton Woods regime, set forth in the
articles of agreement of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the
International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD), provided
for a
system of fixed exchange rates for all currencies that participated in
international trade. The rules further sought to encourage an open
system by
committing members to free trade via the convertibility of their
respective
currencies into other currencies at pegged rates.
Trading nations were required to establish a parity of their
national currencies in terms of gold (a “peg”) and to maintain exchange
rates
within plus or minus 1% of parity (a “band”) by intervening in their
foreign
exchange markets (that is, buying or selling foreign money) conducted
among
central banks.
In theory, the reserve currency in the Bretton Woods regime would
be the bancor, a World Currency Unit suggested by John Maynard Keynes
that was
never implemented due to US
objection. Instead, the United States
succeeded in making the dollar the “reserve currency” for international
trade.
This meant that other countries would peg their currencies to the US
dollar,
and—once convertibility was restored—would buy and sell US dollars to
keep
market exchange rates within plus or minus 1% of parity. Thus the
gold-back US
dollar took over the role that gold itself had played under the gold
standard
in the post-war international financial architecture.
President Richard Nixon de-linked the dollar from gold in
1971 and closed the gold window. But dollars was still traded among
central
banks at $35 per troy ounce of gold but the dollar could no longer
redeem gold
at the Federal Reserve. In February
1973, after a last-gasp devaluation of the now fiat dollar from $35 to
$44 per
troy ounce of gold, the Bretton Woods fixed exchange rate regime based
on a
gold-backed dollar maintained by central banks of all trading nations
was
replaced by open currenies markets of floating exchange rates that
primarily
traded in London. Thus began a floating rate currency trading regime
for those
currencies whose central banks had abandoned cross-border capital
control and
fixed exchange rates.
This currency market in 2010 trades $4 trillion a day, a 23%
gain from $3.3 trillion in 2007. Trade directly involving the dollar
accounted
to 84.9% of the transactions in 2010, down only slightly from 85.6%
prior to
the financial crisis in 2007. The rest of the trades (15.1%) still
involves the
dollar indirectly. The currency market is by far the biggest financial
market
in the world. It now overwhelms by a factor of 15:1 the US
equity market which traded $134 billion a day in April 2010, down from
$248
billion average daily volume in 2007. Aside from trading in US dollars
of $4
trillion a day, trading in US sovereign debt (Treasuries) amounted to
$445
billion a day in April, 2010, down from $570 billion daily average in
2007, .
High Leverage
Routine
in Currency Trading
Astronomically high leverage is standard practice in
currency trading even for individual market participants. An individual
trader
can routinely borrow up to $100 for every dollar of equity from his
broker/dealer, subject to real-time margin calls. The Commodities
Exchange
Commission tried to cut the leverage from 100:1 to 10:1 but after a
vocal wave
of protest from market participants, settled to a leverage limit of
50:1.
The Dollar’s Value
in
Gold
It is not informative to track the price of gold in dollars.
The meaningful way is to track the value of the dollar in gold because
gold is
the element with constant value. While the US
has been facing general deflationary price pressure from the global
financial
crisis since mid 2007, the price of gold has been rising to reflect the
true
depreciation of the dollar in a generally deflationary environment.
Gold is More than a
Commodity
Prices of most key commodities denominated in dollars have been falling
since mid 2007
except gold. The global financial panic and the economic slowdown have
put at
least a temporary end to the commodity bull market of the previous
seven years,
sending prices tumbling for many of the raw ingredients of the world
economy.
The bear market for commodities may now stretch out to a decade or
more.
Since the spring and early summer of 2008, after prices for
many commodities peaked amid pre-crisis speculation driven by fears of
permanent
shortage,
wheat and corn — two cereals at the base of the human food chain —
dropped more
than 40%. Oil dropped 44%. Metals like aluminum, copper and nickel
declined by
a third or more. But gold in Q3 2010 traded about 1:57 against the
price of silver, vastly out of
sync compared
to the historical gold-silver ratio of 1:16.
Traders generally have high expectations for silver widely exceeding
gold’s
gain. They expect to see silver not only to rally with gold, but
to
amplify gold’s gains. A non-confirmation of gold’s strength by
silver is
widely perceived as a warning sign that gold’s rally is somehow flawed
or
false, likely to fail suddenly, since silver has not come along for the
ride.
Gold has gone up since 1999 in value and
is now more than 5 times its low of 11 years ago. This is not caused by
a sudden
shortage of gold versus silver. It is an indication of market
distrust of the
dollar. Gold is a store of value rather than just another commodity.
One ounce
of gold in 2010 stores $1,350 rather than $35 in 1970.
Commodities Prices
Fell
but Still High
The swift downturn of commodity prices in 2008 was by
default the brightest economic news of a terrible year for harassed
consumers, keeping
more money into their pockets after paying for necessities at a time
they needed
the money badly. Gasoline prices in the United
States fell precipitously after
peaking in
July 2008 at $4.17 a gallon, to a national average price of $1.71 a
gallon in
December.
.
Prices for most other commodities remained elevated by historical
standards. But the market trend was downward as traders weighed the
prospect
that a prolonged global economic crisis would lead to sharp drops in
demand.
The big question was whether prices would drop all the way to long-term
norms
or whether Asia’s continuing economic boom amid
a
worldwide recession could be sustained to set a floor for commodities.
The rapid decline of commodity prices eased fears of
inflation, a reason central banks were able to lower interest rates
around the
world since 2008 in an effort to salvage economic growth in a
deflationary
environment. It also represented a fundamental shift of market
sentiment from that
driven by excessively optimistic views that had been behind debt-driven
commodity
bull markets since 1980.
Uncertain Demand
Going Forward
Up until 2008, US consumers had been seen as forceful participants
in a bidding war with emerging middle class consumers in the BRIC
(Brazil,
Russian India, China)
economies for the same pool of commodities worldwide. But that was
before an
extreme slowdown in demand for commodities as diverse as gasoline and
aluminum
and the retreat of investment money from commodity futures into the
safer
havens of sovereign debt.
The commodity market bust began way before the broader
market declines in 2008, though the ensuing panic in 2008 did
exacerbate the downward
price pressure on commodities. Oil dropped by 10% in the second week of
October
2007 alone, but then recovered some of that loss a week later from
technical
reaction to settle at $81.19 a barrel, still far below its high of
$145.29 in
July 2007, the month credit markets froze.
While welcoming the multi-year price declines, most market
participants expected commodity prices to still remain above long-term
historical
norms. Price increases of recent decades had served their economic
function of
generating additional supplies of many commodities, as farmers planted
every idle
acre they could, mining companies reopened dormant mines and oil
companies went
to the far corners of the earth to drill deep undersea wells far
offshore. In
many cases, high prices also caused demand to decline even as supply
started
rising after investment were lured towards alternative energy
solutions.
Food Market Failure
Food, in particular, has been singled out as a continuing long-term
problem because there is no economic alternative to food for human
survival. Despite
the prolonged recession, food prices are still too high to allow large
number
of people in developing economies to afford adequate diets. Nor have
the recent
declines in wholesale food prices been passed along to consumers in
advanced
economies.
The United Nations has projected that global food prices will remain
elevated
for years to come. Yet low-price food needed to feed the world’s poor
will also
discourage food producers in the global market economy to produce more
food.
And hunger, which drives demand for food, does not decline in economic
recessions. Food economics is a clear case of a commodity sector that
operates in a failed
market in
which profit from food production is paid for with mass hunger.
Food as Substitute
Fuel
The US,
with the world’s largest fuel consumption per capita, has been cutting
back on
gasoline since the onset of the big recession in mid 2007, with decline
approaching double digits. US
motorists pumped 9.5% less gasoline during the first week of October
2007,
compared with the same week a year earlier. An International Energy
Agency (IEA)
report cut its forecast for global oil consumption yet again,
projecting that
2008 would end with the slowest demand growth in 15 years.
Big increases in world wheat production because of increased
acreage in the United States, Canada, Russia
and much of Europe have brought wheat prices to
$4.3 a
bushel in June, 2010 from nearly $13 in March. But it rose back to $7.4
in
September as farmers cut back on wheat production to produce corn.
There were
also concerns about wheat crops in the Ukraine and Russia, which either
have
imposed quotas or banned wheat exports after a drought devastated crops
there
earlier in 2010.
The United Nations Food and Agriculture Organization (UNFAO)
called for a review of biofuel subsidies and policies, noting that they
had
contributed significantly to rising food prices worldwide and hunger in
poor
countries.
With policies and subsidies to encourage biofuel production
in place in much of the developed world, farmers often find it more
profitable
to plants crops for fuel than for food, a shift that has helped lead to
global
food shortages and rising food prices.
The UNFAO report said national agricultural policies should
be “urgently reviewed in order to preserve the goal of world food
security,
protect poor farmers, promote broad-based rural development and ensure
environmental sustainability.” In releasing the report, the United
Nations
joined a number of environmental groups and prominent international
specialists
who have called for an end to subsidies for biofuels, which are
cleaner,
plant-based renewable fuels that can sometimes be substitutes for oil
and gas.
An Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD)
report concluded that government support of biofuel production in
member
countries was hugely expensive and that while it “had a limited impact
on
reducing greenhouse gases and improving energy security,” it did have
“a
significant impact on world crop prices” by helping to push them
higher.
“National governments should cease to create new mandates for biofuels
and
investigate ways to phase them out,” the OECD report concluded.
A contrary view is voiced by EuropaBio, a biotechnology
industry group, that the world possessed the land and agricultural
ability to
produce enough food and fuel through subsidy programs with high
sustainability
criteria, including consideration of the fact that biofuels could help
reduce
poverty by providing new revenue options for farmers all over the
world, including
poor farmers. This may be an arguable point theoretically but the
argument is
muted by facts: food prices have been rising even in a severe and
prolonged
recession.
In the past eight years, as oil prices and global concerns
about carbon emissions increase, rich countries, including the United
States, and European Union states have
put
into place subsidies and incentives to energize the fledgling biofuel
industry.
As a result, the production of biofuels made from crops that could have
been used
for food increased more than threefold from 2000 to 2007, according to
the UNFAO.
Support to encourage biofuel production in OECD countries amounted to
more than
$10 billion in 2006.
But recent studies concluded that the rush to biofuels had
some disastrous, even if unintended, consequences for food security and
the
environment. Less affordable food is available in poor countries
because global
grain prices have skyrocketed and precious forests have been cut down
as farmers
created growing fields to join the biofuel boom.
Worse still, so much energy is required to convert plants
into fuel that the process does not result in a net reduction of carbon
emissions. The OECD report said only two food-based fuels (used cooking
oil and
sugar cane) were clearly environmentally better than fossil fuels when
considering the entire “life cycle” of their production. Sugar cane is
far
easier to convert to biofuel than most other crops.
Already in 2010, the European Union has stepped back from
its target of having 10% of Europe’s fuel for
transportation
come from biofuel or other renewable fuels by 2020. The European
Parliament
suggested that only 5% come from renewable sources by 2015, and that
20% come
from new alternatives “that do not compete with food production.”
The food as fuel strategy seemed to have reached a high
point in 2008 when Congress mandated a fivefold
increase in the use of biofuels. Since then , a reaction is building
against
policies in the United States
and Europe to promote ethanol and similar
fuels, with
G20 political leaders from poor countries contending that these
substitute fuels
are driving up food prices and starving poor people. Biofuels are fast
becoming
a new flash point in global diplomacy, putting pressure on G7
politicians to
reconsider their policies, even as they argue that biofuels are only
one factor
in the seemingly unavoidable rise in food prices.
In some countries, higher food prices are leading to riots,
political instability and growing worries about feeding the poorest
people in
the world. Food riots contributed to the dismissal of Haiti’s
prime minister in April 2008, and leaders in some other countries are
nervously
trying to calm anxious consumers. At a
2008 conference in Washington,
representatives of poor countries that had been hit hard by rising food
prices
called for urgent action to deal with the price spikes, and several of
them
demanded a review of biofuel policies adopted recently in the West.
Many specialists in food policy consider government mandates
for biofuels to be ill advised, agreeing that the diversion of crops
like corn
into fuel production has contributed to the higher food prices. But
other
factors have also played big roles, including droughts that have
limited output
and rapid global economic growth that has created higher demand for
food.
That growth, much faster over the last four years than the
historical norm, is lifting millions of people out of destitution and
giving
them access to better diets and prolonging longevity. But farmers are
having
trouble keeping up with the surge in demand.
While there is agreement that the growth of biofuels has
contributed to higher food prices, the amount is disputed. Work by the
International Food Policy Research Institute in Washington
suggests that biofuel production accounts for a quarter to a third of
the
recent increase in global commodity prices. The UNFAO predicted late in
2008
that biofuel production, assuming that current mandates continue, would
increase food costs by 10 to 15 percent. This may not be a significant
increase
for developed economies, but to the poor in developing economies that
already
are suffering from inadequate diets, such increase can push large
number of
people into starvation.
Ethanol supporters maintain that any increase caused by
biofuels is relatively small and that energy costs and soaring demand
for meat
in developing countries have had a greater impact. In Washington,
despite criticism from abroad, support for ethanol remains solid. The
policy is
solidly anchored in effect on US
trade deficit through the trade off between importing less oil and
exporting
less food.
According to the World Bank, global food prices have
increased by 83% in the three years before 2008. Rice, a staple food
for nearly
half the world’s population, has been a particular focus of concern in
recent months,
with spiraling prices prompting several rice-producing countries to
impose
drastic limits on exports as they try to protect domestic consumers.
While
grocery prices in the United States
increased about 5% over all in 2009, some essential items like eggs and
milk
have jumped far more. New data on domestic food prices are expected to
have
notable increases.
Commodity Prices in
Steep Fall After the 2001-08 Boom
Commodity prices are still at the beginning of a steep fall
as recurring Fed quantitative easing in response to the intractable
credit
squeeze would move the world economy from a melt down crisis into a
long deep
recession. More deflation is expected in the housing sector, in capital
assets,
and in commodities even as newly injected liquidity is absorbed by
institutional de-leveraging rather than stimulating the seriously
impaired
economy.
While price dynamics varied for different commodities,
prices generally hit a low point for the decade after the terrorist
attacks of
September 11, 2001, then rose as the global economy strengthened in the
following years as the Federal Reserve led all central banks in the
world with
monetary easing policies. From late 2001 until mid-2008, the price of
oil rose
800%, copper rose 700% and wheat rose 400%. This rise amid steady
supply
suggests only a price effect of a depreciating dollar. Yet wages
were not kept a pace with asset
inflation.
But the price decline in 2008 took virtually every key
commodity more than halfway back to its late 2001 price adjusted for
inflation. By 2010 the gains of the bull market of the 2000s had been
erased entirely,
even as the dollar’s value fell against gold. Wages declined sharply
when
measured in gold.
On July 11, 2008,
oil prices rose to a new record of $147.27, settling around $125 a
barrel on
July 24, 2008. Oil traded below $70 a
barrel on October 16, 2008. On December 21, 2008, oil was trading at
$33.87 a
barrel, less than one fourth of the peak price reached five months
earlier. Prices
of oil did not rebound in 2009. Instead, after initially climbing above
$48,
prices descended by mid-February to below $34, hurt by forecasts for
further
declines in world demand. Through March and April 2009, oil traded at
about $40
per barrel. By August 2009, prices returned to $70 a barrel. The world
economy
had not grown during this period, only the dollar had fallen in value.
The costs of finding oil below deep waters or mining oil sands
in Canada remain high, in the $60 to $70 a barrel range — and since
those are
now increasingly vital sources of supply, they could help put a floor
under the
oil price after the oil glut is absorbed in the speculative market.
Additionally, the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries
(OPEC) can
always cut production over time to shore up prices, even to the point
of
reducing gross revenue from lower sale volume. The continuing credit
crisis and
economic slowdown will inevitably stall new industrial projects,
reducing
demand for oil and metals worldwide, even for China.
Falling prices will also discourage new mining and drilling to increase
long-term supply which would push commodity prices up in an eventual
recovery.
This supply dynamics will keep any eventual recovery anemic.
The biggest single factor that will decide whether a
prolonged bull market in commodities is over, or just in a lull, is the
performance
of the Chinese economy. Industrial development of China
in recent years was responsible for much of the world’s increased
consumption
of copper, aluminum and zinc, and almost a third of the increase in oil
consumption.
Chinese growth has slowed since the beginning of the global
financial crisis in mid-2007 but it is still running near 10%. China
has launched a massive stimulus package and is expected to undertake
many huge
projects in coming years as it repairs damage from natural disasters
such as earthquakes
and storms and to take actions to solve long-range development
challenges in social
security, health services, education, environmental restoration and
protection,
transportation, food and water. Unless China
succeeds in shifting its excessive dependence of export, which is
currently at
70% of GDP, to develop its domestic market by raising wages
aggressively, China’s
massive stimulus package will end up as an unsustainable asset bubble.
Of all the major commodities, only oil at its peak in July 2008
traded at a higher price than in bull markets of the last decade,
adjusted for
inflation. The previous commodity market bull runs of 1970s and 1980s,
stimulated by decades of high economic growth from asset bubbles
unleashed by irresponsible
central bank monetary easing and accompanying inflation, were followed
by
nearly two decades of weak prices that accompanied the transition in
the US
from an industrial to a finance economy by shifting industrial
production off
shore.
Economic growth in China
and India
at
the turn of the 21st century, followed by the oil-driven
economies of Brazil
and Russia
and greater consumer spending in the Middle East
in the
last five years pushed commodity prices up in a final long debt-fueled
bull run
that finally ended in 2007. But these new economic powerhouses are
beginning to
seek ways to moderate their growth from quantity to quality by making
more
efficient use of commodities. This will mean that even if the grow rate
remains
high, the demand for commodities would moderate.