Following misguided neoliberal market fundamentalist advice, Greece
abandoned its national currency, the drachma, in favor of the euro in
2002.
This critically consequential move enabled the Greek government to
benefit from
the strength of the euro, albeit not derived exclusively from the
strength of
the Greek economy, but from the strength of the economies of the
stronger
Eurozone member states, to borrow at lower interest rates
collateralized by
Greek assets denominated in euros. With newly available credit, Greece
then went on a debt-funded spending spree, including high-profile
projects such
as the 2004 Athens Olympics that left the Greek nation with high
sovereign debts
not denominated in its national currency. Further, this borrowing by
government
in boom times amounted to a brazen distortion of Keynesian economics of
deficit
financing to deal with cyclical recessions backed by surpluses
accumulated in
boom cycles. Instead, Greece
accumulated massive debt during its debt-driven economic bubble. The Euro Trap
By adopting the euro, a currency managed by the monetary
policy of the super-national European Central Bank (ECB), Greece
voluntarily surrendered its sovereign powers over national monetary
policy, and
rested in the false comfort that a super-national monetary policy
designed for
the stronger economies of the Eurozone would also work for a
debt-infested Greece.
As a Eurozone member state, Greece
can earn and borrow euros without exchange rate implications, but it
cannot
print euros even at the risk of inflation. The inability to print euros
exposes Greece
to the
risk of sovereign debt default in the event of a protracted fiscal
deficit and
leaves Greece
without the option of an independent national monetary solution, such
as
devaluation of its national currency.
Notwithstanding a lot of expansive talk of the euro emerging
as an alternative reserve currency to the dollar, the euro is in
reality just
another derivative currency of the dollar. Despite the larger GDP of
European
Union (EU) as compared to that of the US,
the dollar continues to dominate financial markets around the world as
a bench
mark currency due to dollar hegemony which requires all basic
commodities to be
denominated in dollars. Oil can be bought by paying euros, but at
prices
subject to the exchange value of the euro to the dollar. The EU simply
does not
command the global geopolitical power that the US
has possessed since the end of WWII. The EMU Vision
In 1998, EU member states that met the convergence criteria
of the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) formed a Eurozone of 11 member
states,
with the official launch of a common currency known as the euro on
January 1,
1999. Greece
qualified in 2000 and was admitted on January 1, 2001.
The Eurozone is an Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) of 16
member states, out of the 27-member European Union (EU), that have
adopted the euro
as their sole common legal tender. The Eurozone currently consists of Austria,
Belgium,
Cyprus,
Finland,
France,
Germany,
Greece,
Ireland,
Italy,
Luxembourg,
Malta,
the Netherlands,
Portugal,
Slovakia,
Slovenia
and Spain.
Eight (not including Sweden,
which has a de facto opt out by domestic popular vote) other
states are
obliged to join the zone once they fulfill the strict entry criteria. Stability and Growth
Pact
The euro convergence criteria as spelled out in the
Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) are:
1. Inflation rates:
No more than 1.5
percentage points
higher than the average of the three best performing (lowest inflation)
member
states of the EU.
2. Government
finance:
Annual
government fiscal deficit:
The ratio of the
annual government
fiscal deficit to GDP must not exceed 3% at the end of the preceding
fiscal
year. If not, it is at least required to reach a level close to 3%.
Only
exceptional and temporary excesses would be granted for exceptional
cases.
Government
debt:
The ratio of gross
government
debt to GDP must not exceed 60% at the end of the preceding fiscal
year. Even
if the target cannot be achieved due to the specific conditions, the
ratio must
have sufficiently diminished and must be approaching the reference
value at a
satisfactory pace.
3. Exchange rate:
Applicant countries
should have
joined the exchange-rate mechanism (ERM II) under the European Monetary
System
(EMS) for two consecutive years and should not have devaluated its
currency
during the period.
4. Long-term
interest rates:
The nominal long-term
interest rate
must not be more than 2 percentage points higher than in the three
lowest
inflation member states.
Price Stability vs
Employment
The euro convergence criteria of the EMU aim to “maintain
price stability” within the Eurozone as new member states are admitted.
In
economics, “maintaining price stability” is essentially a euphemism for
maintaining structural unemployment which is generally accepted as 6%.
Such
numerical criteria have been criticized by Keynesian economists as
being
insufficiently flexible to meet fluctuations in business cycles.
Further,
criteria need to be applied over the length of the entire economic
cycle rather
than in any one year. These institutionalist critics fear that by
limiting
governments' abilities to employ Keynesian measures of government
deficit
spending during economic slumps, long-term growth will be stalled by
unnecessary recessions.
From the opposite side, monetarists criticized these
numerical criteria as being too flexible as to become ineffective
because
“creative accounting” gimmickry can be used and have been used by many
member
states to meet the required deficit to GDP ratio of 3%, and by the
immediate
abandonment of fiscal prudence by some member states as soon as they
are
admitted to the euro club. As it happened, “creative accounting”
through the use
of collateralized debt obligations (CDOs) via special purpose vehicles
(SPV)
rendered SGP criteria meaningless and ineffective in preventing
financial
crises all over the world. German and French
Efforts to Water Down SGP
Ironically, the watering down of the Stability and Growth
Pact (SGP) had been at the request of Germany and France, two of the
strongest
of the 16 member states which had been imitating the rush to phantom
wealth
creation through synthetic structured finance and debt securitization
invented
by fearless young traders in New York and London working with money
provided by
central banks led the Federal Reserve. In March 2005, the EU’s Economic and Financial Affairs Council
(ECOFIN), under the pressure of France
and Germany,
relaxed the rules to respond to criticisms of insufficient flexibility
and to
make the pact more enforceable. Permissiveness infested the theoretical
regulatory framework.
ECOFIN is one of the oldest configurations of the Council of
the European Union and is composed of the Economics and Finance
Ministers of
the 27 European Union member states, as well as Budget Ministers when
budgetary
issues are discussed.
The EU Council covers a number of EU policy areas, such as
economic policy coordination, economic surveillance, monitoring of
member state
budgetary policies and public finances, the shape of the euro (legal,
practical
and international aspects), financial markets and capital movements and
economic relations with third countries. It also prepares and adopts
every year,
together with the European Parliament, the budget of the European Union
which
is about €100 billion.
The Council meets once a month and makes decisions mainly by
qualified majority, in consultation or co-decision with the European
Parliament,
with the exception of fiscal matters which are decided by unanimity.
When the
ECOFIN examines dossiers related to the euro and EMU, the
representatives of
the member states whose currency is not the euro do not take part in
the vote
of the Council.
At the urging of Germany
and France,
the
ECONFIN agreed on a reform of the SGP. The ceilings of 3% for budget
deficit
and 60% for public debt were maintained, but the decision to declare a
country
in excessive deficit can now rely on certain parameters: the behavior
of the
cyclically adjusted budget, the level of debt, the duration of the slow
growth
period and the possibility that the deficit is related to
productivity-enhancing procedures. The pact is part of a set of Council
Regulations, decided upon the European Council Summit 22-23 March 2005.
Monetary policy of the zone is the responsibility of the European
Central Bank, though there is no common representation, governance or
fiscal
policy for the currency union. Some cooperation does however take place
through
the euro group, which makes political decisions regarding the legal
tender and
the euro. Eurozone 2008 nominal GDP was €9.21 trillion with a
population of
321.5 million. Dollar Hegemony and
the Washington Consensus
Economic growth under the dollar hegemony regime requires
market-participating nations to follow the rules of the Washington
Consensus, a
term coined in 1990 by John Williamson of the Institute for
International
Economics to summarize the synchronized ideology of Washington-based
establishment economists, reverberated around the world for a quarter
of a
century as the true gospel of economic reform indispensable for
achieving
growth in a globalized market economy. It is an ideology that has
landed much
of the world in recurring financial crises.
Initially applied to Latin America and
eventually to all
developing economies, the Washington Consensus has come to be
synonymous with
the doctrine of globalized neo-liberalism or market fundamentalism to
describe
universal policy prescriptions based on free-market principles and
monetary
discipline within narrow ideological limits. It promotes for all
economies
macroeconomic control, trade openness, pro-market microeconomic
measures,
privatization and deregulation in support of a dogmatic ideological
faith in
the market’s ability to solve all socio-economic problems more
efficiently, and
to assert a blanket denial of an obvious contradiction between market
efficiency and poverty eradication or income and wealth disparity.
Return on Capital vs
Wages
Financial capital growth is to be served at the expense of human
capital
growth. Sound money, undiluted by inflation, is to be achieved by
keeping wages
low through structural unemployment. Pockets of poverty in the
periphery are
deemed as the necessary price for the prosperous center. Such dogmas
grant
unemployment and poverty, conditions of economic disaster, undeserved
conceptual respectability. State intervention has come to focus mainly
on
reducing the market power of labor in favor of capital in a blatantly
predatory
market mechanism.
The set of policy reforms prescribed by the Washington Consensus is
composed of
10 propositions: 1) Fiscal discipline; 2) redirection of
public-expenditure
priorities toward fields offering high economic returns; 3) tax reform
to lower
marginal rates and broaden the tax base; 4) interest-rate
liberalization; 5)
competitive exchange rates; 6) trade liberalization; 7) liberalization
of
foreign direct investment (FDI) inflows; 8) privatization; 9)
deregulation and
10) secure private-property rights.
Abdication of Government
Responsibilities
These propositions add up to a wholesale reduction of the central role
of
government in the economy and its primary obligation to protect the
weak from
the strong, both foreign and domestic. Unemployment and poverty then
are viewed
as temporary, transitional fallouts from wholesome natural market
selection, as
unavoidable effects of economic evolution that in the long run will
make the
economy stronger.
Neo-liberal economists argue that unemployment and poverty,
deadly economic plagues in the short term, can lead to macroeconomic
benefits
in the long term, just as some historians perversely argue that even
the Black
Death (1348) had long-range beneficial economic effects on European
society.
The resultant labor shortage in the short term pushed up wages in the
mid-14th
century, and the sudden rise in mortality led to an oversupply of
goods,
causing prices to drop. These two trends caused the standard of living
to rise
for those still living. Yet the short-term shortage of labor caused by
the
Black Death forced landlords to stop freeing their serfs, and to
extract more
forced labor from them. In reaction, peasants in many areas used their
increased market power to demand fairer treatment or lighter burdens.
Frustrated, guilds revolted in the cities and peasants rebelled in the
countryside. The Jacquerie in 1358, the Peasants' Revolt in England
in 1381, the Catalonian Rebellion in 1395, and many revolts in Germany,
all served to show how seriously the mortality had disrupted
traditional
economic and social relations.
Neo-liberalism in the past quarter-century created conditions that
manifested
themselves in violent political protests all over the globe, the
extremist form
being terrorism. But at least the bubonic plaque was released by nature
and not
by human ideological fixation. And neo-liberalism keeps workers
unemployed but
alive with subsistence unemployment aid, maintaining an ever-ready pool
of
surplus labor to prevent wages from rising from any labor shortage,
eliminating
even the cruelly derived long-term benefits of the Black Death.
Bashing of the State
The Washington Consensus has since been characterized as a “bashing of
the
state” (Annual Report of the United Nations, 1998) and a “new
imperialism” (M
Shahid Alam, “Does Sovereignty Matter for Economic Growth?”, 1999). But
the
real harm of the Washington Consensus has yet to be properly
recognized: that
it is a prescription for generating failed states around the world
among
developing economies that participate in globalized financial markets.
Even in
the developed economies, neo-liberalism generates a dangerous but
generally
unacknowledged failed-state syndrome. (Please see my February 3, 2005 10-part
series: World
Order, Failed
States and Terrorism – Part I: The
Failed
State Cancer) Greece Seduced Greece
both benefited from and was victimized by macro policies based on the
Washington
Consensus. To continue the high growth rate of the Greek Economic
Miracle years
between 1950 to mid 1973, Greece
after joining the EMU in 2002 adopted, with international investment
banks, US
structured finance innovations to mask its true financial liabilities
to
present a rosier picture of its financial reality.
As the world economy imploded from the last of a two-decade
long serial debt bubble that began in the US two decades earlier in
1987 and
finally burst in the US in July 2007, the Greek economy faced sharp
contraction
along with most other economies around the world. To keep social peace,
the
Greek government had to incur fiscal deficits to maintain the heavily
socialist
economic structure that it managed to keep afloat when it adopted
deregulated
market fundamentalism introduced two decades earlier under better
times.
As the global financial crisis deepened, international
lenders and the IMF began expressing doubt on the reliability of
official Greek
economic data which they conveniently overlooked while the debt bubble
was
building. This sudden doubt from creditors who had earlier extended
credit with
no question asked, led to drastically higher risk premium on Greek
sovereign
debt denominated in euros at a time when government revenue shrank from
general
economic slowdown. A long tradition of widespread tax avoidance and
evasion by
the Greek financial elite added to the problem of declining fiscal
revenue. As
the IMF and fellow EU member states pressed the Greek government to
accept hash
“conditionalities” for emergency loans needed to avoid a default on
Greek
sovereign debt, violent demonstrations broke out in Athens against the
government’s austerity measures to secure new loans to service its €300
billion
($397 billion) debt, such as cuts to public sector pay and benefits and
pension
commitments. In April, 2010, the Greek government announced that it
needed
immediate access to the €30 billion ($39.7 billion) in emergency loans
offered
by other EU countries. It
was hit by the downturn, which meant it had to spend more on
benefits and received less in taxes. There were also doubts about the
accuracy
of its economic statistics.
Greece's economic problems meant lenders
started charging higher
interest rates to lend it money and widespread tax evasion also hit the
government's coffers.
There have been demonstrations against the
government's austerity
measures to deal with its 300bn euro (£267bn) debt, such as cuts
to public
sector pay.
Now the government has announced that it needs
to access the 30bn
euros (£26bn) in emergency loans it has been offered by other EU
countries.
Structured
Finance - Escape
Hatch from EMU Rules
Greece fell into the euro debt trap by yielding to the
temptation of structured finance, the instruments of which were first
developed
in the US and adopted by US transnational financial institutions such
as
Goldman Sachs, Citibank, JPMorgan Chase and Bank of America to generate
phenomenal profit for them in deregulated global markets fueled by
floods of
dollar-denominated liquidity release by the Federal Reserve, the US
central
bank, through the virtual transaction of synthetic derivatives known as
synthetic collateralized debt obligations (CDO). This new game of
phantom
wealth creation was soon joined by copycats in Europe
such as Barclay, Société Générale, Deutsche
Bank and ING. Such synthetic
instruments were designed to, among other things, help banks hide their
liabilities by pushing them off their balance sheets and thus lowering
their
capital requirement to increase profit from expanded loan-making to
yield
higher return on capital.
(Please see my May 9, 2007
AToL article: Liquidity
Boom
and Looming Crisis, written and published two months before the
credit
crisis first imploded in July 2007.)
Later, expanding from the private sector, such schemes were
sold to EMU member governments to help them mask their true public debt
levels
to skirt strict EMU rules, in order to engage in permanent monetary
easing.
Across the eurozone, in obscure and opaque over-the-counter (OTC)
derivative
deals that traded directly between counterparties off exchanges between
“special purpose vehicles” (SPV), and designed to help governments
legally
skirt EMU criteria, transnational banks provided Eurozone governments
with cash
upfront in return for future payments by government. Such payments
would reduce
government fiscal revenue since the revenue from collateral assets has
been
pledged to investors of CDOs. The liabilities were taken off their
national
balance sheets to present a healthy picture of national finance, until
the
government is forced to make up the revenue shortfall in a recession. Special Purpose
Vehicles (SPV)
In an article: BIS vs.
National Banks,
published in Asia Times on Line on May 14, 2002, five year before the
financial
crisis that began in July 2007, I warned against the danger of SPV:
Set for 2004 by the
Bank of
International Settlement (BIS), implementation of the new Basel Capital
Accord
II is meant to respond to such regulatory erosion by LCBOs (large,
complex
banking organizations). “Synthetic securitization” refers to structured
transactions in which banks use credit derivatives to transfer the
credit risk
of a specified pool of assets to third parties, such as insurance
companies,
other banks, and unregulated entities, known as Special Purpose
Vehicles (SPV),
used widely by the likes of Enron and GE. The transfer may be either
funded, for
example, by issuing credit-linked securities in tranches with various
seniorities (collateralized loan obligations or CLOs) or unfunded, for
example,
using credit default swaps (CDS). Synthetic securitization can
replicate the
economic risk transfer characteristics of securitization without
removing
assets from the originating bank’s balance sheet or recorded banking
book
exposures. Synthetic securitization may also be used more flexibly than
traditional securitization. For example, to transfer the junior (first
and
second loss) element of credit risk and retain a senior tranche; to
embed extra
features such as leverage or foreign currency payouts; and to package
for sale
the credit risk of a portfolio (or reference portfolio) not originated
by the
bank. Banks may also exchange the credit risk on parts of their
portfolios
bilaterally without any issuance of rated notes to the market.
Such structured finance deals implemented through SPVs,
because they were technically recorded as sales through SPVs rather
than
collateralized loans to the government, misled investors and regulators
about
the actual depth of a country’s liabilities, thus allowing it to sell
more
sovereign bonds. Greece, for example, traded away the rights to collect
airport
fees, expressway tolls and lottery proceeds for decades to come, with
little
concern for potential default in the event of a sharp reduction in
these
revenues should the economy falls into recession from a burst of the
global
debt bubble. Greek Myths of Public
Finance
Some of the Greek SPV derivative deals were named after
figures in Greek mythology. One of them was called Aeolos (Αἴολος
in Greek), after the god of the winds in Greek
myth,
ironically appropriate for Greek national fortune having gone with the
wind.
The financial wizardry went even further. In what amounted
to a frenzy promotion on a national scale in an E-Bay type auction of
exotic
financial instruments, the Greek government essentially mortgaged the
country’s
infrastructure revenue to raise much-needed up-front money not to
finance
productive development, but to finance runaway consumption unsupported
by
economic fundamentals, socialist or capitalist.
Aeolos, a legal SPV created in 2001, helped the Greek
government move some of its debt off its balance sheet that year. As
part of
the deal, Greece
got cash upfront in return for pledging future landing fees at the
country’s
airports. A similar SPV created in 2000 called Ariadne devoured the
revenue
that the government collected from its national lottery. Greece,
however, classified those transactions as sales, not loans that needed
to be
paid back out of government revenue, despite doubts by many critics. Ariadne (Αριάδνη),
in Greek mythology, was
daughter of King Minos of Crete. Minos attacked
Athens
after his son was killed there. The Athenians sued for peace, terms of
which
included an annual sacrifice of seven young men and seven maidens to
the Minotaur,
a creature with a man’s body and a bull’s head who lived in a
labyrinth. Ariadne
fell in love at first sight of the young Thesus who volunteered to come
and
kill the Minotaur, and helped him by giving him a sword and a ball of
red
fleece thread that she was spinning, so that he could find his way out
of the
Minotaur’s labyrinth after victory. Alas, in 2010, the Ariadne
structured
finance deal was unable to lead Greece
out of it debt labyrinth. EU Governments
Divided on SPVs, but Greenspan Opposed Full Disclosure
These kinds of SPV deals have had their critics within EU
government circles for years. As far back as 2000, European finance
ministers
fiercely debated whether derivative deals used for creative accounting
should
require full disclosure. The answer, supported by positions taken in
the US
by then Fed Chairman Alan Greenspan, was that full disclosure was not
needed
and would unnecessarily hamper innovation. However, in 2002, accounting
disclosure was required for many entities like Aeolos and Ariadne that
did not
appear on nations’ balance sheets, prompting governments to restate
such deals
as loans rather than sales. But since the liabilities resided in
special
purpose vehicle with secured cash flow, the issuing government was
considered
insulated from risk. The Enabling Role of
Goldman Sachs
In 2005, Goldman Sachs sold interest rate swaps it created
to the National Bank of Greece,
the country’s largest bank. In 2008, Goldman Sachs helped National put
the swap
denominated in euros into a legal special purpose vehicle (SPV) called
Titlos.
But National retained the bonds that Titlos issued for use as
collateral to
borrow even more euros from the European Central Bank (ECB) and in turn
from
international banks. The swap will be costly and unprofitable for the
Greek
government through its long contract term. Appropriately, in Greek
manuscripts,
the titlo was often used to mark the
place where a scribe accidentally skipped the letter, if there was no
space to
draw the missed letter above. SPV Titlos performed the special purpose
of
skipping the liability Greece
had assumed in order to get more loans from the ECB and international
banks
than was permitted. Such SPV deals were not made public even though
Titlos
obligations are among the weak links in Greek public finance in 2010.
Information on them finally trickled out only through government
investigations
and media investigative reporting. Der Spiegel reported
in early January 2010 that Goldman Sachs two years earlier had helped
the
government of Greece
cover up part of its huge deficit via a currency swap deal name Titlos,
which
used artificially high exchange rates. A report
commissioned by the Greek Finance Ministry released on February 1, 2010, revealed
that Greece had used swaps to defer interest repayments by several years.
On February 15, 2010,
Bloomberg reported a Greek government inquiry uncovered a
series of swaps agreements with securities firms that allowed it to
mask its
growing debts. The document did not identify the securities firms Greece
used. But the former head of Greece’s
Public Debt Management Agency told Bloomberg that the government turned
to
Goldman Sachs in 2002 to obtain $1 billion through a swap agreement.
“While swaps should be strictly limited to those that lead
to a permanent reduction in interest spending, some of these agreements
have
been made to move interest payment from the present year to the future,
with
long-term damage to the Greek state,” the Finance Ministry report said.
The
106-page dossier is now being re-examined by Greek lawmakers most of
whom had
not been fully informed of the opaque transactions.
A currency swap
is a foreign-exchange agreement between two parties to exchange aspects
(namely
the principal and/or interest payments) of a loan in one currency for
equivalent
aspects of an equal in net present value loan in another currency.
Currency
swaps are motivated by comparative advantage. A currency swap between
private
parties should be distinguished from a currency swap between central
banks to
increase liquidity in one of the swap currencies, such as the currency
swap
agreements between the Federal Reserve and the European Central Bank. OTC Currency Swaps
Currency swaps are OTC (over-the-counter: not traded on
exchanges) derivatives, and are closely related to interest rate swaps.
However, unlike interest rate swaps, currency swaps can involve the
exchange of
the principal.
The Goldman Sachs transaction consisted of a cross-currency
swap of about $10 billion of debt issued by Greece
in dollars and yen that was swapped into euros using a historical
exchange
rate, which produced a reduction in debt that added some $1 billion of
funding
to the EU’s Luxembourg-based statistics office for that year.
Importantly,
Bloomberg claimed that rating companies were aware of the deal but did
not
change their credit ratings on Greece, on account that the risk profile
for
Greece had not changed since the additional unit risk was made
invisible
through dispersion into systemic risk of the Eurozone and through it
into
global systemic risk.
Similar to damage done to other credit markets involving
high tech dot com debt and subprime home mortgages, toxic structured
finance
instruments, the category term for complex debt securitization and
derivative
based synthetic financial products, are now showing their ugly faces as
systemic crises in sovereign debt markets all over the world.
The sovereign debt crisis in the PIIGS (Portugal,
Ireland,
Italy,
Greece,
Spain)
economies, visible first in Greece,
poses the most significant systemic challenge to Europe’s
common currency, the euro, since its creation on January 2, 1999, and through it to Europe’s
goal of full unification. Technically, Greece
is not “too big to fail”. It has a population of 11 million out of the
total EU
population of 830 million and a GDP of $357 billion in 2008 out of a
total EU
GDP of €11,805.66 billion ($16,447.26 billion in 2009). Greece Not Too Big to Fail, but the Euro Is
On the surface, Greece
owes its foreign creditors €300 billion, an amount of little impact in
the
scale of global government finance. What is at stake is the undisclosed
counterparty risk in euro-based OTC derivative instruments held by
major
international banks in the event of a sovereign debt default within
Eurozone
and its adverse impact on the exchange value of the euro. Suddenly,
highly
rated mark-to-model instruments are reduced to underwater status when
mark-to-market. A chain reaction of counterparty defaults can amount to
trillions. This lack of transparency caused banks to limit their risk
exposure
by refusing to lend to other banks, thus causing a liquidity crisis not
much
different except possibly at larger scale than the meltdown of the
credit
market brought on by the Lehman collapse in 2008.
Almost two year after the breakout of the credit crisis in
July 2007, resistance to efforts to reform the loose regulatory regime
of the
$605 trillion OTC derivative market continues to hold. Counterparty
defaults of
these impaired derivative contracts, detonated by little Greece,
similar to that created by the Lehman collapse, would reverberate
around global
financial markets to cause a meltdown. Greece
is not too big to fail, but its derivative obligations are too widely
spread to
fail without serious global consequences. Recent History of
Greek Politics
George Papandreou (junior), who became socialist prime minister
on October 6, 2009, is a scion of a prominent Greek political family,
whose
father, Andrea, was a highly respected Harvard-educated economist and
professor
and department chairman at the University of California at Berkley
before
returning to Greece in 1959 to participate in Greek politics and
eventually
became Greece’s first socialist prime minister in 1981. As a student,
Andreas
was arrested for Trotskyite activism by the Fascist Metaxas
dictatorship in
1938 and deported to the US
in 1941 and enrolled in Harvard in 1942. George’s grandfather, also
named
George, served three times as prime minister.
When the Greek Junta led by Colonel Georgios Papadopoulos
seized power in April 1967, Andreas Papandreou was incarcerated while
his
father George Papandreou (senior) was put under house arrest and died
in 1968.
The grandson, George Papandreou, became prime minister on October 6,
2009 when
he led the Pan-Hellenic Socialist Movement (PASOK) to electoral victory
over
the conservative center-right New Democracy Party on a campaign that
promised
to lead Greece out of the recession caused by the global financial
crisis that
began in the US in 2007. A Toxic Inauguration
Gift for the new Greek Socialist Government
Upon inauguration, George Papandreou’s new socialist
government discovered that the condition of public finance was far
worse than
had been previously disclosed by the conservative New Democracy Party,
with a budget
deficit of 12.7% of GDP, more than quadrupling the EMU limit of 3%, and
a public
debt of $410 billion, at 115% of GDP, almost doubling EMU limit of 60%.Not only there was no money available to
execute deficit financing to jump start the Greek economy from
recession, the
government was faced within a serious sovereign debt crisis that it
could not
solve without outside help.
On April 23, 2010,
the Greek government under Papandreou requested that the EU/IMF bailout
package
that had been discussed for months be immediately activated to prevent
sovereign default. The IMF responded that it was “prepared to move
expeditiously
on this request”, not with IMF guarantees or funds, but with technical
restructuring advice IMF style which means hash “conditionalities” to
force
Greek fiscal surpluses over future years to pay back debts owed to
foreign
banks. The size of the emergency bailout from the EU to allow Greece
to avoid a default was expected to be €45 billion ($61 billion) and it
was
expected to take three weeks to negotiate, with a payout within weeks
of the €8.5
billion of Greek bonds becoming due for repayment.
Four days later, on April 27 2010, Greek sovereign debt rating
was lowered to BB+ (a ‘junk’ status) by Standard & Poor’s amidst
fears of default
by the Greek government in the event the bailout package failed. Greece
had to offer investors interest at 15.3% on two-year government bonds
while
two-year US Treasuries were yielding 0.71%. Standard & Poor’s
estimated
that in the event of default on Greek government bonds, investors would
lose
30–50% of their principal. Stock markets worldwide and the exchange
rate of the
Euro declined sharply in response to the announcement of impaired
confidence. Eurozone Finance Ministers
Fiddled While Athens Burned
While the sovereign debt problem had been known for years in
EMU government circles, Eurozone officials were debating on the
seriousness of
the situation while the debt bubble was still expanding. As the global
financial crisis erupted in mid 2007, EMU officials were slow to
recognize the
fatal contagion effect. Suddenly, Eurozone’s 16 finance ministers,
found
themselves in an emergency meeting on Sunday, May 2, 2010, that lasted
until
the early hours of Monday, and emerged with a quickly assembeled €110
billion
($146 billion) package of emergency loans aimed at averting a sovereign
default
by Greece and preventing a confidence crisis contagion spreading to
other
Eurozone countries such as Spain and Portugal.
The loans to Greece
from the 15 other eurozone countries and the International Monetary
Fund were
described by IMF officials as “big and unprecedented”. The details of
the
package were thrashed out at a meeting of eurozone finance ministers in
a late
night meeting. Eurozone countries are to contribute €80 billion of the
total.
The emergency loan was conditioned on Greece’s agreement to severe
austerity fiscal measures, including a sharp reduction of Greece’s
budget
deficit from 13.6% of GDP to below 3% within three years, by 2014, and
to stabilize
the public debt at about 140% of GDP, even though it is expected to
peak at
almost 150% of national income. The package included tough measures to
drastically
reduce the size of Greece’s public sector built up by earlier socialist
policy
that had been rendered inoperative by neoliberal economic policies of
recent
years under the previous conservative New Democracy government, cuts in
public
sector salaries and pensions, a rise in value-added tax and an increase
in taxes
on fuel, alcohol and tobacco.
Even though such hash austerity measures would hit the already
severely impaired Greek economy hard, the Greek Finance Ministry had no
choice
but to accept them, as it revised down its economic forecasts and
projected
that the economy would contract 4% in 2010 and 2.6% 2011. Official Celebration on
an Explosive Rescue Package
Yet, in Brussels,
José Manuel Barroso, the European Commission president,
described the agreed
set of measures as a “solid and credible package”. US President Barack
Obama
told Greek Prime Minister George Papandreou that he welcomed
Greece’s
“ambitious’’ reform program as well as the “significant support’’
provided to
the country by the IMF and other Eurozone members.
The European Central Bank’s governing council welcomed the
rescue deal with the following statement: “The program is comprehensive
and
supported by strong conditionality.” But the ECB statement added: “The
governing council also considers essential that the Greek public
authorities
stand ready to take any further measures that may become appropriate to
achieve
the objectives of the program.” In other word, Greece
was expected to go through tough austerity measures for more than three
year,
perhaps even a decade. The Greek People
Bolted
While the financial establishment was profusely supportive
of the hash “conditionalities”, the Greek public was less enthusiastic.
Three days after the rescue deal
was announced, on Wednesday, May 5, 2010,
thousands in Athens, Greece’s
capital, took to the streets to protest deep spending cuts aimed at
saving the
country from default on its sovereign debt and from falling into
insolvency.
Clashing with the police, the demonstration turned deadly. Three bank
employees
died in the chaotic demonstration, trapped in a blaze started by a
petrol bomb
thrown as the city erupted into violence during a march by tens of
thousands of
striking workers angry at the government’s deep spending cuts. The
clashes
erupted after the government announced further cuts in bonuses and
allowances
for about 600,000 public sector workers and an increase in value-added
tax. The
strike grounded flights in and out of Athens
international airport and shut public transport.
Still, Prime Minister George Papandreou vowed to push
through draconian economic measures demanded as part of the €110
billion rescue
package for his debt-burdened country despite the mass demonstrations.
Papandreou characterized the deaths as caused by “a murderous act”. He
said he
would not be deterred from pushing through unpopular public spending
cuts and
tax increases demanded by the IMF as part of the €110 billion rescue
package agreed
with the other Eurozone members and the IMF.
The deaths were the tragic outcome in five months of daily
street protests against the government’s austerity program. But the
full socioeconomic
tragedy will take decades to play out. A spokesman for ADEDY, one of
the unions
organizing the march to parliament, said he regretted the deaths but
that the
protests would continue. Television news showed Greek police firing
teargas and
stun grenades at demonstrators who tried to force their way into
parliament
ahead of a debate on the three-year program. Angry protestors outside
the
parliament building raised clenched fists and shouted “Thieves,
thieves” - an
accusatory expression for corrupt politicians and bankers. Confidence
in a
government that is prepared to sacrifice its working population to
restore
market confidence is shown by the people to be in sharp decline. May 17, 2010