Global Post-Crisis
Economic Outlook
By
Henry C.K. Liu
Part I: Crisis of
Wealth Destruction Part II: Two
Different Banking Crises - 1929 and 2007
This article appeared in AToL
on April 14, 2010
The 1929 banking crisis that launched the Great Depression
was caused by stressed banks whose highly leveraged retail borrowers
were
unable to meet margin calls on their stock market losses, resulting in
bank
runs from panicky depositors who were not protected by government
insurance on their
deposits.
In the 1920s, there were very few traders beside
professional technical types. The typical retail investors were
long-term
investors, trading only infrequently, albeit buying on high margin.
They bought
mostly to hold based on expectations that prices would rise endlessly.
By contrast, the two decades of the 1990s and 2000s were
decades of the day trader and big time institutional traders. New
powerful traders
in major investment banking houses overwhelmed old-fashion investment
bankers
and gained control of these institutions with their high profit
performance. They
turned the financial industry from a funding service to the economy
into a
frenzy independent trading machine. Many of the investing public
aspired to be
the Master of the Universe, as caricatured in Tom Wolf’s Bonfire
of the Vanity, which was turned into a movie starring Tom
Hanks. Derivative trading by hedge
funds was routinely financed through broker dealers funded by banks at
astronomically high leverage. Greenspan – the
Wizard of BubbleLand
But the debt joyride was by no means all smooth sailing in a
calm sea. Repeated mini crises were purposely ignored by regulators who
should
have known better. Greenspan, notwithstanding his denial of
responsibility in
helping throughout the 1990s to unleash serial equity bubbles, had this
to say
in 2004, three year before the 2007 tsunami of a century, in hindsight
after
the bubble burst in 2000: “Instead of trying to contain a putative
bubble by
drastic actions with largely unpredictable consequences, we chose, as
we noted
in our mid-1999 congressional testimony, to focus on policies to
mitigate the
fallout when it occurs and, hopefully, ease the transition to the next
expansion.” The Greenspan Fed adopted the role of a clean-up crew of
otherwise
avoidable financial debris rather than that of a preventive guardian of
public
financial health. Greenspan’s one-note monetary melody throughout his
18-yesr-long tenure as the nation’s central banker had been when in
doubt,
ease. LTCM – the Crisis
that the Fed Papered Over
In the 1920s, there were no derivative markets. In the case
of Long Term Capital Management, the hedge fund that failed in 1998,
the firm
had equity of $4.72 billion and had borrowed over $124.5 billion to
acquire
assets of around $129 billion, for a debt-equity ratio of about 25 to
1. But even
that it was conservative when compared to the 40 to 1 ratio used by
investment
banks in the 2000s.
LTCM had off-balance-sheet derivative positions with a
notional value of approximately $1.25 trillion, most of which were in
interest
rate derivatives such as interest rate swaps, equaling to 5% of the
entire
global market. LTCM also invested in other derivatives such as
equity
options. LTCM was bailed out by its counterparty creditors under the
guidance of
the NY Fed. (Please see myDecember 3, 2009 series: Reform of
the OTC Derivative Market - Part
One: The Folly of Deregulation) The Enron Fraud
In the 1920s, there was no structured finance or
securitization of debt. The case of Enron, a large brave new energy
trader, and
its spectacular bankruptcy marked the high watermark of legalized
financial
fraud. The evidence is undeniable that the Enron scandal exposed
critical flaws
in the entire financial system and the ineffective policing of US
capital
markets and corporate governance. In a December 18, 2001 Senate
Commerce
Committee hearing on the Enron collapse, Arthur Levitt, former
Democratic head
of the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), characterized
corporate
financial statements as “a Potemkin village of deceit”. Senator Ernest
Hollings, a Democrat from South Carolina,
characterized Enron Chairman Kenneth Lay’s political prowess as “cash
and carry
government”. Embarrassingly, the New York Times reported the following
day that
Hollings had received campaign contributions from Enron and its auditor
Arthur
Andersen dating from 1989.
Until Enron filed for bankruptcy in 2001, the system’s top law firms
and
accounting firms were providing professional opinion that what went on
in Enron
was "technically" legal. The international dealings of Enron received
unfailing support from the US
government. Many of the schemes undertaken by Enron and other companies
were
devised by investment bankers who collected fat fees advising their
clients and
who profited handsomely from providing financing for schemes they knew
were
towers of mirage. It was known in the industry as "finance
engineering" and the vehicle was structured finance or derivatives.
(Please see my August 1, 2002
article: Capitalism’s bad
apples: It's the
barrel that's rotten) Greenspan – Enron Prize Recipient
Chairman of the Federal Reserve since 1988, Alan Greenspan gave
a lecture at Stude Concert Hall sponsored by the James A. Baker III
Institute for
Public Policy on November
13, 2001.
Following his lecture, he received the Baker Institute’s Enron Prize
for
Distinguished Public Service. The prize, made possible through a
generous and
highly appreciated gift from the Enron Corporation, recognizes
outstanding
individuals for their contributions to public service.
Greenspan’s speech offered an assessment of what lies ahead
for the energy industry to an admiring audience. In the wake of the
September
11 attacks and the then weakened state of the economy, Greenspan
stressed the
need for policies that ensure long-term economic growth. “One of the
most
important objectives of those policies should be an assured
availability of
energy,” he said.
Greenspan said that this imperative has taken on added significance
in light of heightened tensions in the Middle East,
where two-thirds of the world’s proven oil reserves reside. He noted
that the
Baker Institute is conducting major research on energy supply and
security
issues.
Looking back at the dominant role played by the United
States in world oil markets for most
of the
industry’s first century, Greenspan cited John D. Rockefeller and
Standard Oil
as the origin of US pricing power, notwithstanding the nation saw fit
to break
up the Rockefeller/Standard Oil trust. Following the breakup of
Standard Oil in
1911, he said this power remained with American oil companies and later
with
the Texas Railroad Commission. This control ended in 1971 when
remaining excess
capacity in the US
and oil pricing power shifted to the Persian Gulf.
Greenspan was saying better Standard Oil than OPEC. He seemed oblivious
to the
development since the 1973 oil embargo that US
oil companies have been working hand in glove with OPEC producers to
keep oil
prices high. The Power of Markets against
Market Power
“The story since 1973 has been more one of the power of markets
than one of market power,” Greenspan said. He noted that the projection
that
rationing would be the only solution to the gap between supply and
demand in
the 1970s did not happen. While government-mandated standards for fuel
efficiency eased gasoline demand, he said that observers believe market
forces
alone would have driven increased fuel efficiency.Greenspan appeared to be the only one who
sincerely believed that a free market existed or could exit for the
trading of
oil. All oil traders know that the price of oil is one of the most
manipulated components
in world trade.
“It is encouraging that, in market economies,
well-publicized forecasts of crises more often than not fail to
develop, or at
least not with the frequency and intensity proclaimed by headline
writers,”
Greenspan credited free markets with mitigating the oil crisis.
As it turned out, the California
energy crisis of rolling blackouts was not caused by Middle
East
geopolitics. It was the handy work of Enron fraudulent trading
strategies. Greenspan against Reform
All though the 1990s and early 2000s, there were much talk
of reform that led nowhere near what was actually needed. Less than a
decade later,
a financial crisis that Greenspan characterized as the market failure
of a
century imploded with a big bang.
On Greenspan’s 18-year watch at the Fed, government-sponsored
enterprises (GSE) assets ballooned 830%, from $346 billion to $2.872
trillion.
GSEs, namely Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, are financing entities created
by the
US Congress to fund subsidized loans to certain groups of borrowers
such as
middle- and low-income homeowners, farmers and students. Agency MBSs
(mortgage-backed securities) surged 670% to $3.55 trillion. Outstanding
ABSs
(asset-backed securities) exploded from $75 billion to more than $2.7
trillion.
Greenspan presided over the greatest expansion of
speculative finance in history, including a trillion-dollar hedge-fund
industry,
bloated Wall Street firm balance sheets approaching $2 trillion, a $3.3
trillion daily repo (repurchase agreement) market, and a global
derivatives
market with notional values surpassing an unfathomable $220 trillion.
Granted,
notional values are not true risk exposures. But a swing of 1% in
interest rate
on a notional value of $220 trillion is $2.2 trillion, approximately
20% of US
gross domestic product (GDP). Grated that much of the derivative trades
were
hedged, meaning the risks are mutually canceling. But the hedges
would
only hold without counterparty default. All that was needed to unleash
a
systemic
failure was for the weakest link to fail. Greenspan created a monetary
situation
that
permitted the market to speculate on risks that it could not afford.
Having released synthetic credit of dangerously high notional value,
Greenspan raised the Fed funds rate target from its lowest point
of 1% set on June 23, 2003, to 4.50% on January 31, 2006, to dampen
inflation expectations, before retiring as chairman the following
month. Ben Bernanke, his successor as of February 1, 2006, continued
increasing the Fed funds rate target in three more steps to 5.25%
on June 29, 2006, the cumulative effect adding aggregate interest
payments to the financial system greater than US GDP in 2006.
That was like striking a
match to
light a candle in a dark kitchen filled with leaked gas. Under such
fragile
and explosive conditions, there was little wonder that the market
collapsed a year
later. (Please
see my March 16, 2007 article: Why
the US sub-prime mortgage
bust will spread to the global finance system, written at a time
when
mainstream opinion was that the housing market, being geographically
disaggregated, would not spread.)
Much of the precautionary measures instituted during the New
Deal to prevent a replay of the 1929 crash, such as the separation of
investment
banking from commercial banking, requiring banks to be neutral
intermediary of
capital funds rather than profit-seeking market makers, in the form of
the Banking
Act of 1933 (Glass-Steagall), were repealed, as a result of bank
lobbying.
Glass-Steagall was replaced by the Financial
Services Modernization Act of 1999, (Pub.L.
106-102, 113 Stat. 1338, enacted
November 12, 1999), aka the Gramm, Leach-Bliley Act (GLBA). Wholesale Credit
Market Failure
Yet with the benefit of deposit insurance instituted during
the New Deal remaining operative, the current financial crisis that
began in
mid-2007 was caused not by bank runs from depositors, but by a melt
down of the
wholesale credit market when risk-averse sophisticated institutional
investors
of short-term debt instruments shied away en mass.
The wholesale credit market failure left banks in a
precarious state of being unable to roll over their short-term debt to
support
their long-term loans. Even though the market meltdown had a liquidity
dimension, the real cause of system-wide counterparty default was
imminent insolvency
resulting from banks holding collateral whose values fell below
liability
levels in a matter of days. For many large, public-listed banks,
proprietary
trading losses also reduced their capital to insolvency levels, causing
sharp
falls in their share prices. Bank Bailouts
Citi Group shares fell from $70.80 in July 31, 2007 to $1.02 on March 4, 2009. CitiGroup market
capitalization
dropped to $6 billion from $300 billion two years prior.
CitiGroup shares were trading at $4.54 on April 2010 after
having received $320 billion of bailout help from the Treasury in
November
2008. Citigroup and Federal regulators negotiated a plan to stabilize
the bank-holding
company with the Treasury guaranteeing about $306 billion in loans and
securities and investing about $20 billion directly in the company. The
assets
remain on Citigroup’s balance sheet; the technical term for this
arrangement is
“ring fencing” or hypothecation,
the dedication of the revenue of a specific tax for a specific
expenditure
purpose. In a New York Times op-ed, author Michael Lewis and
hedge fund
manager David Einhorn described the $306 billion guarantee as “an
undisguised
gift” without any real crisis motivating it.
From October 2008 to January 2009, the US Treasury provided
Citigroup with three rounds of financial aid worth $45 billion.
Citibank has to
pay back $20 billion of the aid as the US
government acquired 34 percent of Citigroup’s capital. The government
also
imposed executive pay restrictions which the bank was eager to dodge
fearing
the exodus of “talented” employees. Even though the bank was optimistic
about
the plan, offering $15 billion in common stock, there were some within
the bank
who questioned whether the aid should be paid back so soon. Some
government
officials also voiced concerns that the US
economy might head back into recession causing consumer credit losses
and
commercial real estate losses.
"The basic objective is to make sure as we exit ... we’re leaving the
capital position of the institutions stronger, not weaker," said US
Treasury Secretary Timothy Geithner, as if merely stating the goal is
as good as
achieving it. Tax Deduction Stealth
Bailout
Under the Bush Administration, the IRS, an arm of the
Treasury Department, changed a number of rules during the financial
crisis to
reduce the tax burden on financial firms and to encourage mergers,
letting Wells
Fargo cut billions of dollars from its tax bill by buying the ailing
Wachovia.
The government was consciously forfeiting future tax revenues from
these
companies as another form of assistance.
On December 16, 2009, the Bush administration government
quietly agreed to forgo billions of dollars in potential tax payments
from Citigroup
as part of the deal to help wean the company from the massive taxpayer
bailout
that enable it to survive its blunders that helped cause the financial
crisis.
The Internal Revenue Service issued an unusual exception to
long-standing tax
rules for the benefit of Citigroup and a few other companies that had
been partially
acquired by the government.
As a result of the exception, Citigroup will be allowed to
retain billions of dollars worth of tax breaks that otherwise would
decline in
value when the government sells back its Citigroup stake to private
investors. The
Obama administration, in updating the exceptions, has said taxpayers
are likely
to profit from the sale of the Citigroup shares. Many accounting
experts, however,
are of the opinion that the lost tax revenue could easily outstrip
those
profits.
Treasury officials said the most recent change was part of a
broader decision initially made to shelter companies that accepted
federal aid
under the Troubled Assets Relief Program from the normal consequences
of such
an investment. Officials also said the ruling benefited taxpayers
because it
made shares in Citigroup more valuable and asserted that without the
ruling, Citigroup
could not have repaid the government at this time.
“This rule was designed to stop corporate raiders from using
loss corporations to evade taxes, and was never intended to address the
unprecedented situation where the government owned shares in banks,”
Treasury
spokeswoman Nayyera Haq said. “And it was certainly not written to
prevent the
government from selling its shares for a profit.”
When working as spokeswoman for Representative John Salazar,
Democrat of Colorado Nayyera Haq joined with 22 other Muslims aides on
Capitol
Hill to form the Congressional Muslim Staffers Association, after
hearing a
radio interview in which Tom Tancredo, a Colorado Republican, in
response to a
question on what should be done if Muslim terrorists attacked the
United
States, suggested bombing Islam's holy sites, including Mecca. “That's
when I
realized there was something really wrong,” said Ms Haq. “Not just with
members
of Congress, but as Americans and our approach to dealing with
‘others’.” Byzantine Partisan
Politics
The Democrat-controlled Congress, concerned that lame-duck
Bush Treasury was bypassing Congress to rewrite tax laws, passed
legislation
early in 2009 that reversed the ruling that benefited Wells Fargo in
2008 and
restricted the ability of the IRS to make further changes. A Democratic
aide to
the Senate Finance Committee, which oversees federal tax policy, said
the Obama
administration, just as the Bush administration did, has the legal
authority to
issue the new exception, but now Republican aides to the committee say
they are
reviewing the issue.
A senior Republican staffer now questions the Obama
administation’s echo of the Bush rationale. “You’re manipulating tax
rules so
that the market value of the stock is higher than it would be under
current
law,” said the aide, speaking on the condition of anonymity. “It
inflates the
returns that they're showing from TARP and that looks good for them.”
Never
mind thatTARP had first been initiated
by Republican Treasury Secretary Henry Paulson.
The Obama administration and some of the nation’s largest
banks have hastened to file for separation in recent months. Bank of
America,
followed by Citigroup and Wells Fargo, agreed to repay federal aid.
While the
healthiest banks had already escaped earlier this year, the new round
of
departures involves banks still facing serious financial problems. It
seems
obvious that executive pay restriction has much to do with the mad rush
to
independence.
The banks say the strings attached to the bailout, including
limits on executive compensation, have restricted their ability to
compete and
return to health. Executives also have chafed under the stigma of
living on the
federal dole. President Obama chided 13 of the nation’s top bankers at
the
White House for not trying hard enough to make small-business loans.
The Obama administration also is eager to close out a bailout
program that has become a major political liabilities in
this season
of populist discontent. Administration officials defend the program as
necessary and
effective
under emergency conditions, but the president has acknowledged that the
bailout
is “wildly unpopular” and officials have pointed out at every chance
they do
not relish
helping banks that seem to be milking the crisis for narrow advantage. The Root Cause of
Excess Debt for Both Crises
Both crises, though 80 years apart, have the same root cause
of excess debt, but the contours of the crises are quite different. In
both
crisis, the function of the stock market as a venue for raising capital
was
distorted to one where most of the investing population expects to make
unearned fortunes by speculating on stock prices. Capital formed from
savings became
dissatisfied with fair return from sound, long-term investment based on
economic fundamentals. Instead, highly leverage capital began to seek
outsized
returns from risky assets technically-driven to high prices in
debt-financed
bubbles in hope of selling them to latecomer investors for spectacular
profit
before inflated prices expectedly returned to normal levels.Prices continued to rise in an expanding
bubble as a result of escalating mass speculation, creating an
unrealistic expectation
that prices could only rise higher from artificially generated high
demand over
limited supply.
But prices could not continue to rise without fundamental
growth and fundamental growth cannot take place without sound long-term
investment to increase productivity that keeps income rising. As soon
as asset
prices began to fall from correction on an overbought market, a large
number of
highly leveraged institutional speculators were forced to liquidate
with high
losses. Bankers and brokers continued to act as market cheerleaders,
calling
every decline as merely market corrections that were in fact windows of
buying
opportunity, while the smart money was unloading their excess risk onto
unsuspecting and less informed speculators worldwide. Structured
finance also
allowed conservative institutional investors to invest in highly rated
derivatives
of subprime loans.
Worse still, in the 2007 crisis, much of the institutional
money came from pension funds of the working population whose savings
were
seeking high returns from risky speculative financial derivatives of
the
population’s own highly leveraged debts, mainly in bloated housing and
consumer
credit sectors that were not supported by stagnant debtor income. Loss of Market
Confidence over High Leverage
Both crises, though 80 years apart, involved banking system
failures brought on by an abrupt loss of confidence in a market
infested with excessive
leverage. But the 1929 crisis manifested itself first in the retail
markets while
the 2007 crisis began in the wholesale markets. Yet the leverage was
much
higher in 2007 and the face amount of exposure much bigger. In 1920,
the average
leverage was 10 times. To put it another way, the margin set at was 10%
which
meant $10 of equity for every $100 of speculative trade. In 2007, the
going leverage
has risen to 40 times, or $10 of equity for every $400 of speculative
trade. Liquidity and Insolvency
Both crises, though 80 year apart, involved problems of
sudden illiquidity, but due to finance globalization and electronic
trading
developed in recent decades, the 2007 banking crisis was faced with an
additional problem of fastpaced
global contagion triggered by
insolvency in financial institutions that were “too big to fail”
without triggering
serious global systemic consequences, a problem that remains unsolved
as post-crisis
regulatory reform is watered down in a Congress highly influenced by
special
interests financed lobbying. Bank Capital Ratio
Conspicuously missing from the House regulatory reform bill (Wall
Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2009 - H.
R. 4173) is required capital ratio, the minimum level of
capital that banks should be required to hold for every dollar they
lend.The bill also does not define what
can be
counted as capital, or how much of that capital should be readily
available to
provide adequate liquidity. Those important questions are being left to
the new
regulators to sort out later, without any assurance of adequate
technical
capability for the challenging task. Rating Agencies
Immunity
Rhode Island Democrat Senator Jack Reed criticized Standard
& Poor’s for its “cynical” attempt to resist regulatory reform by
asking
Republican members of Congress to oppose legislation that would make it
easier for
market victims to sue credit-rating firms for misleading rating. “The
same
companies that helped cause the financial crisis are now trying to
block
reform,” Reed, who drafted the litigation provision, said in a
statement on April 6, 2010.
“This cynical attempt
by Wall Street lobbyists to kill Wall Street reform before it has a
chance to
see the light of day must be resoundingly rejected.” Legislative Tactics
The Senate Banking Committee under Democrat Chairman
Christopher Dodd on March 23 approved landmark financial regulatory
reform
legislation, pushing the fight over the issue to the full Senate in
April. The
Democrat-controlled committee voted 13-10 along party lines to pass a
1,336-page bill, which will need 60 votes to move for a vote on the
Senate
floor, a calculation that was key to Republicans’ acquiescence to a
quick
committee decision. All Republican committee members voted against the
Democratic
measure at a working session that lasted only 30 minutes.
In the full Senate, the Democrats will need to pick up some
Republican support to win passage. Democrats control only 59 votes out
of 100
in the chamber since it lost the critical seat of the late Senator
Teddy
Kennedy to Scott Brown, a Massachusetts Republican. The Dems would need
to
muster 60 votes to overcome procedural roadblocks, such as a
filibuster, that
Republicans are likely to throw up to stall a vote.
Just hours before voting, the Committee dropped plans for a
weeklong debate of 400 amendments that were to be offered by both
Republicans
and Democrats to a bill unveiled in the previous week by the Chairman
Dodd.
The shift came after Republicans decided not to offer their
300 amendments, opting instead to take their fight to the Senate floor,
where
they have a better chance at blocking reforms that are opposed by their
party,
the banks they represent and Wall Street interests that fund their
campaign
costs.
“Republicans will not offer hundreds of amendments that
would only be defeated at the committee level,” said Richard Shelby,
the top
Republican on the Committee. The tactical adjustment followed a narrow
win on
Sunday, March 21 in the House of Representatives for the Democrats and
the White
House on healthcare reform -- another top priority on the Obama agenda.
The Dodd bill would set up a council of regulators to
oversee financial risk, create an orderly process for liquidating
distressed
financial firms, regulate derivatives markets, and take other steps
meant to
avert another financial crisis caused by the too-big-to-failed syndrome.
President Barack Obama welcomed the Dodd Committee vote. “We
are now one step closer to passing real financial reform that will
bring
oversight and accountability to our financial system and help ensure
that the
American taxpayer never again pays the price for the irresponsibility
of our
largest banks and financial institutions,” the President said. Obama
vowed in a
statement to fight to strengthen the measure and urged senators on the
floor to
resist efforts to water it down. The bipartisan appeal fell on deaf
ears.
The Committee’s approval of the Dodd bill, which critics
complained as a water-downed compromise, marks the biggest concrete
step yet
taken by the Senate toward putting in place new rules for banks and
capital
markets, two years after the collapse of Bear Stearns ushered in the
worst
financial crisis since World War Two.
While Republicans have worked closely with bank lobbyists to
block reforms that they think will threaten financial industry profits,
some liberal
Republicans concur that regulatory reform is needed up to a point. They
disagree with Democrats on how fundamental reform should reach. Shelby
said he
remains hopeful that “broad consensus” can be reached on reform as the
Dodd
bill moves toward the floor. The Senate began a two-week recess on
Friday,
March 26. When it returns in April 12, Democratic leaders will decide
how and
when to bring financial reform to the floor. Until then, lawmakers of
either
party could reshape the bill to increase or decrease its chances of
passage.
Republican Senator Judd Gregg said in a statement that he
wants to continue working with Democrats, but he criticized the Dodd
bill on
several fronts. Senator Bob Corker, a Republican who tried but failed
to broker
a bipartisan deal with Dodd, called the committee’s unexpectedly quick
vote
“dysfunctional”. But he added that “there is still an opportunity to
produce a
sound piece of legislation that will merit broad bipartisan support
from the
full Senate and stand the test of time.” In other words, the
Republicans hope
to water down fundamental reform further.
Failure by the Senate to produce a bill by July would hand
Obama and the Democrats a defeat heading into the November mid-term
congressional
elections, and leave a cloud of political uncertainty hanging over the
financial services industry. Consumer Protection
The Consumer Financial Protection Agency (CFPA), much fought
for by reformers, has been put under the Federal Reserve by the Senate
bill.
Advocates for an independent agency argue that the Federal Reserve has
always
had consumer protection power that it repeatedly failed to use to
prevent the
crisis from hurting consumers.
Under the Senate Bill, the Federal Reserve will oversee
banks with assets of $50 billion or more, together with a vaguely
defined
“systemically risky [non-bank] institutions”. In other words, the same
players
who brought on the crisis and the bailout with tax payer money are
still
running the show, albeit with a new, improved script. Water Downed Reform
Bill
The Senate Bill is criticized by reformers in the following
areas:
- A new systemic risk council stuffed with the same players:
the Federal Reserve, the Treasury, the FDIC and the SEC would be a
sham, as a
75% majority vote on the council can overturn any rulings of the CFPA.
- Over the counter (OTC) derivatives are to be regulated but
as in the House Bill. But there are enough loopholes and exemptions to
render
regulation meaningless.
- Shareholder vote on executive compensation will be
non-binding only.
- The Volcker Rule to limit bank proprietary trading appears
to be dead on arrival. - The
proposal to audit the Fed is not even mentioned, so
much for oversight discovery on $2 trillion dollars in loans the Fed
has given
Wall Street.
- Smaller bank holding companies, if they hold a federal
charter, would be overseen by a new regulator formed out of the Office
of the
Comptroller of the Currency, which already oversees national banks.
- The Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), which
already oversees state-chartered banks that are not members of the Fed
system,
would gain oversight over those that are. No-Holds-Barred Bank Lobbying
J P Morgan Chase and Company reportedly spent $6.2 million
in 2009, up from its pre-crisis annual spending of around $4 million,
on
lobbying lawmakers against regulatory reform proposals that would
further
restrict credit-card lending and increase fees on federal depositor
insurance.
Citibank spent over $7 million in 2007, $6.5 million in 1908 and $4.8
million
in 2009 on lobbying.
J P Morgan chairman, James Dimon, called proposed consumer
protection measures “Un-American”. Having earlier embraced the Trouble
Asset
Relief Program (TARP) by receiving $25 billion in government bailout
money as a
“patriotic duty” even though his bank allegedly did not need the money,
Dimon
protested publicly against the Treasury’s requirement of banks that had
received
TARP money raise fresh capital from the market before they exit from
TARP, as
it would force banks to pay high cost for the funds.The bank repaid the $25 billion of Tarp fund
in June 1009, but continued to fight with the government on the value
of
warrants it needed to buy back from the Treasury Department to
officially
conclude the transaction. J P Morgan ultimately waived its right to buy
the
warrants as part of the initial TARP terms so that Treasury could hold
an
auction to get a higher price that netted the Treasury $936 million
gain in
December 2009.
A request from White House Chief of Staff Rahm Emmanuel to
ahigh Morgan executive, former Commerce
Secretary William Daley, a scion of a prominent Chicago Democratic
political
dynasty, asking for the bank’s support for the proposed creation of a
new
consumer protection agency, was vetoed by Dimon on grounds that
sufficient
consumer safeguards are already in place.
In a recent 36-pge annual letter to shareholders, Dimon
wrote: “It is critical that the reforms actually provide the important
safeguard without unnecessary disrupting the health of the overall
financial
system.”In other words, no fundamental
reform will be accepted. Post WWII Recessions
and the Marshal Plan
While WW II ended the Great Depression, the first post-WWII
recession occurred between 1948 and 1949, lasting 10 months, with a GDP
decline
of 1.58%, unemployment reaching 7.9% and deflation as measured by the
CPI
falling 2.07%. The recession ended with military spending in arming
NATO as
Truman launched the Cold War and millitary spending in the Korean War
which
also jumped started the “Asian Tigers” economies with massive US
procurement in Asia. The revival of the
war-torn
Japanese economy began with US military spending in the Cold War in Asia,
half a decade after the Marshall Plan and NATO spending jump-started
the
revival of war-torn Europe. Soviet rejection of
the
Marshall Plan marked the beginning of the Cold War.
The Marshall Plan was created as part of the Truman Doctrine
of containment of Soviet communism. It was more than an altruistic aid
program
to help Europe recover from war damage. It
sought to
restructure Western European economies away from its prewar socialist
direction
and launch them on a new path towards US
style market capitalism under a new monetary regime based on a
gold-backed
dollar worked out at Bretton Woods, and to keep budding European social
democracy from mutating into populist communism through electoral
politics. The
strategic geopolitical purpose was to integrate Western
Europe
firmly into the postwar Pax Americana of free market fundamentalism and
a
regional anti-Soviet military alliance in the form of the North
Atlantic Treaty
Organization (NATO) based on collective security, having rejected the
lesson of
the role of interlinked alliances in igniting WWI. For the first two
decades of
its existence, the US
supplied all of the military materiel of NATO. The Marshall Plan was
the
linchpin of US
strategy to neutralize a perceived rising Soviet threat. It helped to
trigger
the Cold War which undeniably had its economic benefits for the
capitalist
system at the expense of the socialist system.Truman
left the national debt at 74.3% of GDP
by the end of his
presidency. The Eisenhower
Recessions
There were three short, mild recessions during the
Eisenhower presidency (1953-61). The first occurred between 1953 and
1954,
lasting 10 months, with GDP declining 2.53%, unemployment reaching 5.9%
and
inflation at 0.37%. The second recession under Eisenhower occurred
between 1957
and 1958, lasting 8 months, with GDP declining 3.14%, unemployment
reaching
7.4% and inflation of 2.12%. The third Eisenhower recession occurred
between
1960 and 1961, lasting 10 months, with a slight decline of GDP of
0.53%, but
unemployment reaching 6.9% and inflation of 1.02%. The standard
Eisenhower cure
for recessions was new military contracts to the industrial sector. Eisenhower left the national debt at 56% of
GDP. Eisenhower left office with a warning to the nation of the danger
of a
military-industrial complex. The Kennedy/Johnson
Recessions
The Kennedy presidency, cut short by assassination on November 22, 1963, was
spared of
recessions as Kennedy maintained high government spending by continuing
the
Cold War and the arms race with the Soviet Union,
topped
with the Apollo program to land a man on the moon. The Kennedy tax cut
in the
Revenue Act of 1964, pushed through in 1964 by Johnson, was 1.9% of the
Net
National Income as measured by the Net National Product, more than the
Reagan
tax cut of 1.4% in the Economic Recovery Act of 1981. Popular image and
political rhetoric notwithstanding, Reagan was not the most aggressive
tax
cutter in US
history, not was he the most conservative in fiscal affairs.
Despite heavy spending on the Vietnam War, a short recession
occurred between 1969 and 1970 during the last year of the Lyndon B.
Johnson
presidency, lasting 11 months, with GDP declining 0.16%, unemployment
reaching
5.9%, but inflation climbed to 5.04%. The economy managed to produce
simultaneously for both guns and butter, but war expenditure robbed LBJ
of the
funds needed to finance his Great Society dream.JBJ
left the national debt at 42.5% of GDP,
substantially lower than Ronald Reagan did. The Nixon Recession
The presidency of Richard Nixon saw one recession between
1973 and 1975 as Nixon winded down the Vietnam War. The recession was
the
longest since the Great Depression, lasting 16 months, with a GDP
decline of
3.19%, unemployment reaching 8.6% but inflation rose to an
unprecedented
14.81%. It was the first stagflation recession rather than a
deflationary
recession. Nixon left the national debt at 37.1% of GDP at the end of
his first
term and Ford left the national debt at 36.3% of GDP. The Carter Recession
Jimmy Carter had one short recession in 1980 during his
presidency (1977 to 1981), lasting 6 months, with a GDP decline of
2.23%,
unemployment reaching 7.8%, unacceptably high for a self-proclaimed
populist
president, with inflation still at 6.3% despite the Volcker Fed’s
bloodletting
monetarist measures to fight run-away inflation. Nevertheless, Carter
left the
national debt at 33.4% of GDP, the lowest since WWII. The Reagan Recessions
Under Ronald Reagan, the country had two recessions, the
first between 1981 and 1982, lasting a long 16 months to match the
Nixon
recession record, with GDP declining 2.64%. But unemployment reached
double
digit for the first time since the Great Depression, to 10.8%, with
inflation
hitting 6.99%. The Reagan tax cut of 1981, coupled with Reagan military
budget,
left the US
with a national debt of 51.9% of GDP, compared to Jimmy Carter’s 33.4%.
The First Bush
Recession
The 1987 crash did not produce an official recession, thanks
to Greenspan’s magic wand of monetary laxative. In the 1988
presidential
election, George H.W. Bush defeated Democratic challenger Michael
Dukakis
because the Greenspan Fed, with aggressive intervention, prevented the
1987
stock market crash from developing into a recession. But a recession
occurred
between 1990 and 1991 in the aftermath of the Savings and Loan Crisis,
lasting
8 months, with a GDP decline of 1.36%, unemployment reaching 6.8% and
inflation
of 3.53%.
In the 1992 presidential election, Bush, appearing oblivious
about the effect of the ailing economy on the voting public, lost the
election
to Bill Clinton (43.0% of the vote against Bush’s 37.4% of the vote),
with
billionaire conservation populist Ross Perot as an independent
candidate
spoiler (18.9% of the vote). Clinton’s
campaign slogan of “it’s the economy, stupid!” took advantage of Bush’s
decline
in the polls which had reaching as high as 89% immediately following
the Gulf
War (2 August 1990 –
28 February
1991).
Bush left the national debt at 64.1% of GDP. The Clinton Prosperity and its Costs Clinton
presided
over the longest period of peace-time economic expansion in American
history,
which included balanced budgets and fiscal surpluses. But there was a
price to
pay. His Third Way
economic
approach, a centrist program of privatization, deregulation and
globalization
as espoused by Antony Giddens, paved the way for the crisis of the
financial
sector in 2007 with endless easy money provided by the Greenspan Fed.
The
Clinton prosperity, fueled by neoliberal market fundamentalist
ideology, became
the root cause of the financial crisis two decades later, even though
Clinton
left the national debt at 57.3% of GDP, 6.8 percentage points lower
than when
Bush left it, but 23.9 percentage points higher than when Carter left
it.. The Second Bush
Recession and the 2007 Market Failure
The dot com bust led to the recession of 2001 as George W
Bush entered the White House. The recession, a parting gift from Clinton
policies, was shortened by Greenspan’s monetary response to the 9/11
terrorists
attacks. As a result, the recession lasted only 8 months, with a real
GDP
decline of 0.73%, unemployment falling to 5.5%, below the 6% structural
unemployment line, lowest since WWII and with inflation at 0.68%. But
the
financial tsunami was building in the deregulated financial markets
fueled by
brave new financial innovation of derivatives and finally exploded in
mid 2007
to launch a market meltdown that earned it the label of the Great
Recession.George W Bush left the
national debt at 69.2% of GDP at the end of his two terms.
Ronald Reagan, George HW Bush and George W Bush were the
only presidents who left the national debt higher than it was when they
entered
the White House. So much for the Republican claim of being the party of
fiscal
conservatism.
The entire Obama presidency to date has been mired in
recession which started in the George W. Bush presidency. Obama’s
approval
rating was 50% when he took office in January 2009 and rose to 68% by
April. It
fell to 44% in the latest CBS News Poll in April, 2010, the lowest
level of his
tenure in office so far. That compares to 49% in late March, just
before he signed
the healthcare reform bill into law. Learning the Wrong
Lessons
Despite claims of having learned from the errors of
passivity allegedly made by the Fed in the 1930s, and that the
resultant,
supposedly wiser measures taken by the Bernanke Fed having prevented a
market
freefall, the jury is still out on whether this new massive
interventionist
approach will save the world from another Great Depression and at what
cost. As
students in Econ 101 learn, there is no free lunch in economics. Free
lunches
are found mostly in Ponzi and pyramid schemes, even if they are
concocted by
governments.
To date, the Great Recession that began in 2007 has already
lasted 30 months so far. There is no end yet in sight. Impaired markets
remain
anemic, still facing a possible double dip, with unemployment reaching
9.7% and
expecting to stay high for a long time, consumer price index (CPI)
rising
2.76%, and asset price deflation by more than half from its peak to
reverse
wealth effects on households. On the domestic horizon are a massive
pension
fund crisis, a commercial real estate loan default crisis and a crisis
of state
and local government fiscal insolvency. On the global horizon are a
sovereign
debt crisis, a foreign exchange crisis and a pending global trade war. The Painful Failure
of Monetarism
Applying the counterfactual conclusion of Milton Friedman on
the errors the Fed that led to the Great Depression, the Fed under
Greenspan
and Bernanke signed on to Friedmanesque monetarism to make extended use
of the
Fed nearly unlimited power to provide liquidity to override business
cycles in
free markets. This approach robbed the free market economy of its self
correction adjustment to produce serial bubbles in a managed market on
the
supply side, in opposition to the Keynesian approach of demand
management.
In contrast to Fed passivity after the 1929 crash, the
Bernanke Fed in 2007 at first made massive funds available to
distressed banks
and other financial institutions. But it simultaneously used open
market
operation to sterilize any enlargement of the monetary base and to
prevent any
increase in total bank reserves in the system. While the Fed in 1929
failed to
inject liquidity into the banking system, the Fed in 2007 failed to
cause the
massive liquidity it injected into the banking system to flow into the
broader
economy to increase demand. Imbalance of excess supply and inadequate
demand
reduced the Fed to the equivalent of pushing on the credit string. The Fed as Market Maker
of Last Resort in a Failed Market
As the crisis intensified in the second half of 2007, the
Fed used Section 13 (3), a seldom used authority granted by Congress
during the
Great Depression, to provide emergence loan to distressed non-bank
firms. The
Fed also lowered the Fed funds rate target in quick succession,
effectively to
near zero, below which the Fed cannot go. Thus the Fed essentially ran
out of
its only bullet.
In addition, the Fed purchased large amounts of US
Treasuries to inject liquidity into the credit markets, particularly in
the
repo and commercial paper markets. The Fed also bought distressed
agency debt
and toxic mortgage-backed securities at face value to provide liquidity
to
large financial institutions holding the most senior debts, in effect
expanding
to unprecedented levels the Fed’s balance sheet, the monetary base and
broader
monetary aggregates.
The 2007 financial crisis began with the collapse of the
residential real estate debt bubble in the US,
which had been financed by highly leveraged sub-prime mortgages that
were
securitized in structured finance instruments of hierarchical levels of
risk
and compensatory returns. These securitized instruments were sold to
both
institutional and retail investors worldwide who mostly bought them
with highly
leveraged debt. When prices of these instruments collapse from
foreclosed
mortgages, investors were unable to meet margin calls and defaulted en
mass,
causing a global chain of counterparty defaults. As the market for
these
securities and derivative contracts failed, the Fed acted as a market
maker of
last resort for these toxic instruments and contracts. The result was
most of
the toxic securities and liabilities ended up on the Fed’s balance
sheet. Structured Finance, the
Fatal Virus
Structured finance allows general risk normally embedded in
all debts to be unbundled into structured instruments of hierarchical
of credit
ratings, allowing even the most conservative institutional investors,
those
mandated by law to hold only investment grade securities, to
participate in the
debt bubble by holding the supposedly safest, low-risk senior debt
instruments.
But the real world safety of these high-rated AAA, allegedly low risk
senior
instruments is merely derived from the unrealistically expected
low-default
rate of their riskier components. As the default rate of the high-risk,
subprime mortgages rose from the bursting of the debt bubble of easy
money
created by an indulgent Fed, the safety of the supposedly low-risk,
high
credit-rated senior debt vanished.
With runaway “supply-side” voodoo economics keeping wage
income in check during the boom phase in corporate profits, the
resultant
overcapacity from demand lag resulting from stagnant low wages shut off
investment opportunities for productive expansion of the economy and
forced the
excess money supplied by an accommodating Fed into speculative
manipulation of
debt, giving birth to structured finance that permitted the disguise of
debt
proceeds as revenue, providing a false sense of security by
transferring unit
risks into systemic risk hidden from unit balance sheets, and through
sophisticated, circular risk hedging schemes. The nonexistence of a
systemic
balance sheet made systemic imbalance legally invisible, supported by
free
market fundamentalism ideology, notwithstanding challenges from a few
lonely
independent voices that were routinely shut off from the mainstream
media and
authoritative academic journals. There were a few clear minds that
refuse to
buy into the grand self delusion, but their voices were kept in the
intellectual
wilderness.
The Fed’s Credit Oversupply
– Midwife for Neoliberal Finance Capitalism
Two decades of excessive money creation produced a Fed-induced credit
oversupply, which led to a system-wide under-pricing of risk and a
lowering of
credit worthiness standards to generate a whole category of so-called
subprime
borrowers whose credit rating and income stream did not meet
conventional
lending criteria. While subprime mortgages were at first merely a
housing
sector problem, the derivative effects of failure in structured finance
quickly
infested the entire global financial system.
The interconnected factors that fueled the spectacular boom
in serial bubbles formation at an unprecedented rate and on an
unprecedented
scale provided support for the false claim of neoliberal finance
capitalism to
be the most effective and efficient economic system in history. This
unsubstantiated myth lasted more than four decades.It turned out that these same factors behind
the boom also brought the entire global finance capitalist system,
built on
debt, crashing down in July 2007. The Implosion of
Under-priced Risk and the Fed’s Fire-Fighting Response
The first weak link in the global network of under-priced
risk to fail began in London on August 9, 2007 when the London
Inrerbank Offer
Rate (LIBOR) and related funding rates jumped sharply higher after the
French
bank BNP Paribas announced that it was halting redemptions for three of
its
high-flying investment funds to avoid forced liquidation.
The Bernanke Fed tried to clam jittery markets on August 10
by repeating the famous Greenspan announcement that had successfully
calmed market
jitters in the1987 crisis: “The Federal Reserve is providing liquidity
to
facilitating the orderly functioning of the financial markets,” adding:
“as
always, the discount window is available as a source of funding.”
A week later, on August 17, with the credit market still
frozen, the Federal Reserve Board of Governors voted to reduce the
primary
discount rate by 50 basis points to 5.75% from the 6.25% set since June
2006.
It also extended the maximum term of the discount widow to 30 days. The
Fed
also invited banks not yet visibly in distress to borrow from the
discount
window to try to remove the traditional stigma associated with discount
borrowing for distressed borrowers.
Starting in September 2007, the Fed Open Market Committee
(FOMC) lowered its target for the Fed funds rate in the first of many
cuts,
three cuts in 2007 totaling 100 basis points (one percentage point),
and seven
cuts in 2008 totaling 425 basis points (4.25 percentage points) that
ended at
essentially zero by December 2008 and has kept it there for 16 months
so far at
this writing (April 2010). The penalty
of such long period of near zero interest rate will have to be reckoned
with in
future years.
At no other time in history had the Fed kept the Fed funds
rate target near zero for so long. The visible result so far has been
massive
carry-trades through interest rates arbitrage by institutional
speculators and
hedge funds borrowing in low interest markets to invest in high
interest
markets for easy profit, exposing their trades to exchange rate risks.
The
discount rate followed suit, falling 0.5% on December 16 2008 and stayed there for
15 months until February 19,
2010 when it was raised
25 basis points to 0.75% to calm inflation expectation.
Still, financial strain reemerged in November 2007 despite
the August 17 cut in the Fed funds rate target and the discount rate
three
months earlier. On December
12, 2007,
the Fed had to arrange a currency swap with the European Central Bank
(ECB) and
the Swiss National Bank to provide a source of dollar funding to
European
Financial markets. Over the following 10 months, the Fed arranged
currency
swaps with a total of 14 other central banks around the world.
On the same day, the Fed also created the Term Auction
Facility (TAF) to lend directly to banks for fixed terms to overcome
the low
volume of discount window lending on account of traditional stigma
associated
with discount window borrowing, despite persistent stress in interbank
funding
markets.
By December 28, 2009,
the Fed had provided $3.48 trillion of new bank reserves
through TAF auctions. Under fractional reserve in normal times, at a
reserve
rate is 10%, the maximum amount of new deposits that can be created by
$3.48
trillion of new bank reserves would be $34.8 trillion and the maximum
increase
in the money supply would be $27.84 trillion. This was a massive
injection by
any standard. The money supply expanded by nearly twice the size of the
GDP. It
produced the equity market rally of the spring of 2010 but did little
for the real
economy.
April 12, 2010