How Supply Side Economics of a Low Tax
Regime Pushes Down Wages By Henry C.K. Liu This article
appeared in AToL
on December 15, 2009 and on NewDeal
2.0 on December 16, 2009
In recent decades, an
intuitive myth has been pushed on the
unsuspecting public by Supply Side economists that low taxes encourage
corporations, employers and entrepreneurs to create high paying jobs.
But the
counterintuitive historical truth is that a progressive income tax
regime with
over 90% for top bracket incomes actually encouraged management and
employers
to raise wages. The principle behind this truth is that it is easier to
be
generous with the government’s money. In the past, when top
corporate income tax rate was at over
50% and personal income tax rate at over 90%, both management and
employers had
less incentive to maximize net income by cutting cost in the form of
wages. Why
give the government the money when it could be better spent keeping
employees
happy. The Reagan Revolution, as
inspired by voodoo Supply Side
economics, started a frenzy of income tax rate reduction that invited
employers
to keep wages low because cost savings from wages would produce profits
that
employers could keep instead of having it taxed away by high tax rates. It follows that the low
income tax rate regime leads
directly to excess profit from stagnant wages which leads to
overinvestment
because demand could not keep pace with excess profit due to low wages.
Says
Law on “supply creating its own demand”, which Supply Side economists
lean on as
intellectual premise, holds true only under full employment with good
wages, a
condition that Supply Side economists conveniently ignore.To keep demand up, workers in a low wage
economy
are offered easy money in the form of sub-prime debt rather than as
paying
consumers with living wages, creating more phantom profit for the
financial
sector at the expense of the manufacturing sector. This
dysfunctionality
eventually led to the debt bubble that burst in 2007 with global
dimensions.
The
State Theory of Money (Chartalism) holds that the acceptance of a
currency is
based fundamentally on a government’s power to tax. It is the
government’s
willingness to accept the currency it issues for payment of taxes that
gives
the issuance currency within a nation. The Chartalist Theory of Money
claims
that all governments, by virtual of their power to levy taxes payable
with
government-designated legal tender, do not need external financing and
should
be able to be the employer of last resort to maintain full employment.
The
logic of Chartalism reasons that an excessively low tax rate will
result in a
low demand for the currency and that a chronic budget surplus is
economically
counterproductive because it drains credit from the economy. The
colonial
administration in British Africa learned that land taxes were
instrumental in
inducing the carefree natives into using its currency and engaging in
financial
productivity.
Thus, according to Chartalist theory, an economy can finance its
domestic
developmental needs to achieve full employment and sustainable optimum
growth
with prosperity without any need for foreign loans or investment, and
without
the penalty of hyperinflation. But Chartalist theory is operative only
in
closed domestic monetary regimes.
Countries
participating in free trade in a globalized system, especially in
unregulated
global financial and currency markets, cannot operate on Chartalist
principles
because of the foreign-exchange dilemma. For a country participating in
globalized trade, any government printing its own currency to finance
domestic
needs beyond the size of its foreign-exchange reserves will soon find
its
currency under attack in the foreign-exchange markets, regardless of
whether
the currency is pegged to a fixed exchanged rate or is free-floating.
The only
country exempt from this rule, up to a point, is the US because of
dollar
hegemony. (Please see my April 11, 2002 AToL article: Dollar Hegemony)
Thus
all economies must accumulate dollars before they can attract foreign
capital.
Even then, foreign capital will only invest in the export sector where
dollar
revenue can be earned. Thus the dollars that Asian economies accumulate
from
trade surpluses can only be invested in dollar assets in the United
States, depriving local economies of
needed
capital. This is because in order to spend the dollars from trade
surplus, the
dollars must first be converted into local currency, which will cause
inflation and unemployment
because the wealth behind the new local currency has been shipped
overseas. The
only protection from such exchange rate attacks on currency is to
suspend
convertibility, which then will keep foreign investment away. The Income Tax Regime The UnitedState did not have an income tax for the first 133
years of its
existence. Government revenue came from protective tariffs on imports.
Corporation
income tax was first adopted in 1909 while personal income tax was
first
adopted in 1913. Corporate income brackets
are not directly comparable over time
because the definition of “income” changes over time due to revised tax
laws,
changing accounting practices, and structural changes in the economy
such as
globalization of trade and finance, and the corporate taxpayers’
ever-growing
sophistication in legal tax avoidance. Thus the calculation of actual
tax
burdens on the economy or effective tax rates is a highly complex
undertaking. The principle of taxing
corporations as legal persons separate
from their shareholders was established by the Revenue Act of 1894 in
which definitions
of taxable income and tax rates were applied to the corporation without
regard
to the status of its owners. The Civil War era (1861-1865) tax acts had
taxed
corporate
income on the owners through the individual income tax. The 1894
Revenue Act
was ruled
unconstitutional by the Supreme Court, but the principle survived after
a technically
constitutional way of taxing corporate income was enacted by Congress
in 1909.
When the individual income tax was revived in 1913 after the 16th
Amendment
removed all question of constitutionality, a separate corporation
income tax
was kept parallel to it. This tax structure has remained to this day. A rational contradiction
exists between the corporation
income tax and the individual income tax, because corporations, legal
person in
the eyes of commercial law, are owned, directly or ultimately
indirectly, by real
person individuals who immediately or ultimately receive an entitled
share of
the corporations’ net income. This can result in the same income being
double
taxed, and various ways of lessening this irrationality have been
included in
the tax system. And if a corporation is partly owned by other
corporations, the
question of multiple taxations arises. The “double taxation”
burden are reduced at times by
allowing corporations to be pass-through entities that are not taxed,
allowing
deductions or credits for dividends, and reducing the rates on capital
gains
separate from income. Different corporate and individual tax rates can
also
result in opportunities to shelter income from tax through rate and
bracket
arbitrage, especially if corporate tax rates at a given income bracket
are lower
than those faced by the owners. From the beginning of the
income tax regime, there were restrictions
or compensatory taxes on excessive accumulations of undistributed
corporate
profits and special rules and rates for individuals who incorporate to
avoid high
taxes. Another problem with imposing a corporate tax is that the
corporate form
is used for many different kinds of entities, ranging from ordinary
for-profit businesses
to religious, charitable, and other nonprofit organizations.
Organizations not
organized or operated for profit were originally exempt from the
corporate tax,
and those devoted to religion, charity, education, and other goals
deemed
socially desirable as specified in Internal Revenue Code section
501(c)(3))
still are. However, by 1950, otherwise exempt organizations were made
subject
to the ordinary corporate tax rates on business income unrelated to
their
exempt purposes. In finance, the line
separating mutual and cooperative
organizations from for-profit businesses often cannot be clearly drawn.
Mutual
savings institutions were made taxable in 1951, except credit unions,
which are
still tax exempt, but paid little tax until their reserve deductions
were
revised in 1963. Mutual insurance companies have always been subject to
tax,
but usually under special rules. Even now, mutual property and casualty
companies with annual premiums of under $350,000 are tax-exempt, and
those with
premium income between $350,000 and $1,200,000 are taxed only on
investment
income. Rural electrical and telephone cooperatives are not taxed on
member income;
other cooperatives are subject to the regular corporate rates but are
allowed
to deduct distributions to members which are taxed at individual rates
to members.
Regulated investment companies such as mutual funds and real estate
investment
trusts (REIT - pooled real estate investment funds) are subject to the
corporation income tax, but are allowed to deduct income allocated to
shareholders if they allocate virtually all of their incomes. The most
prevalent organization that avoids the corporation income tax, however,
is the
“S corporation” (named for
the
subchapter
of the Code that defines it). Since 1958, closely held
companies meeting certain other
restrictions could avoid paying the corporate tax by electing to
allocate all
income to the shareholders, who are then taxed on it at individual tax
rates.
More than half of all corporations now file as S corporations. The treatment of
affiliated groups of corporations has also
been a problem. Corporations that own each other or are subject to the
same ownership
or control (defined in various ways over the years) have been subjected
to several
different tax regimes. They have variously been required to consolidate
their income
statements for tax purposes (1917-1921), forbidden to do so except for
railroads and a few other companies (1934-1941), allowed the option but
required
to pay at a higher tax rate (1932-1933, 1942-1963), and allowed the
option
without penalty (1922-1931, 1964 to the present). The history of corporate
tax rates from 1909 to 2002 as applied
to whatever the then-current definition of “taxable income” was so
complex in
the definition of the income base that a given tax rate from one year
is not necessarily
comparable to that for another, especially for widely separated years.
Initially,
the tax was generally imposed on corporate profits as defined under
general
accounting principles. Tax rules quickly diverged from accounting
rules,
however, since it was clear that the goals of the two systems were not
the
same. Accounting rules guard against the temptation to overstate
income, while
tax rules must guard against the desire to minimize income. The tax law
now
includes very specific definitions of many items of income and
deductions, and
many pages specifying when and how to account for the items; and many
of these definitions
and specifications have changed so dramatically over the years that
even
experts disagree on proper interpretation. The deduction for the
depletion of oil and gas deposits is
an example. It was first included as a tax-defined deduction in 1913
which allowed
the producer of any mineral a “reasonable” deduction not to exceed 5%
of the
value of the deposit. In 1918, as a war measure, a specific deduction
for oil and
gas deposits was enacted as “discovery value” depletion, which allowed
deductions far in excess of the value of the deposit. This was limited
to a
percentage of net income from the property in 1921 (100%) and 1924
(50%). In
1926, discovery value depletion was replaced by a deduction of a flat
percentage
of net income from the property (27.5% from 1926 to 1969). In 1969, the
percentage was reduced to 22%, and, in 1975, percentage depletion was
repealed
for all except smaller “independent” producers, for whom the rate was
reduced to
15%. The rules were tightened further in 1986 and liberalized again for
“marginal” production in the 1990’s. Obviously, attempting to determine
the actual
tax rate on oil and gas income over the years is a challenging task. Interpreting the
historical tax rates is further complicated
by the use of tax credits and the possibility of additions to tax.
Credits are
direct deductions from the tax figure calculated by the stated rates
and are,
thus, in reality a reduction in the tax rate. For example, credit for
taxes
paid to foreign governments has been allowed since 1918. Before that,
they could
be taken as a deduction in computing taxable income. Credits for
various
investments and for other policy goals were introduced in the 1960’s
and have
continued to the present; in 2002, there were more than a dozen credits
that
could reduce the stated tax rate. Because they interact with one
another and
with other features of the tax system, it is not even possible to
estimate what
the tax rates would be if they were taken into account. Finally, there
are
additional taxes that affect these rates. The general ones, such as the
excess profits
taxes or the separate tax on capital gains which could have reduced the
rates,
and the ones applying to significant classes of taxpayers, such as
“personal
holding companies” or “personal service corporations”.
In
the Tax Reform Act of 1986, Congress lowered the top corporate income
tax rate
from 46% to 34% the largest reduction since the tax was enacted in 1909. The top rate was 53% for income over $25,000
from 1942 to
1949. Corporate Income Tax
Rates from 1993 to 2002: $15,000,000-$18,333,333
bracket - 38 % Over $18,333,333 bracket
- 35% Foreign Corporations: Companies incorporated
outside the U.S. are taxed on business income earned in the U.S. at the regular corporate rates, but may be
taxed on
investment income at special statutory or treaty rates. US Corporations with
Foreign-source Income: The US taxes the worldwide income of US corporations;
however,
since 1918, taxes paid to foreign governments on foreign-source income
can be
credited against the US tax otherwise due on that income. Before 1918,
the foreign
taxes were allowed as a deduction against worldwide income. US Possessions
Corporations: Since 1921, corporations
earning most of their incomes in a U.S. possession were subject to reduced taxes. From
1921 to
1976, they were taxable only on U.S.-source income; since 1976, they
have
received a credit for manufacturing income earned in a possession
(including Puerto Rico).
The credit is now being phased out and is scheduled to end after 2005. Affiliated groups: Corporations that are
closely affiliated through stock
ownership have usually been allowed to consolidate their financial
statements
for tax purposes and file one return for the group, but there have
always been
restrictions and, sometimes, they have been charged an additional tax
for the
privilege. In 1932 and 1933, consolidated returns were subject to an
additional
tax of .75 percent. In 1934 and 1935, only railroad companies were
allowed to
file consolidated returns, and the additional tax was 1 percent. From
1936 to 1941,
there was no additional tax, but the privilege was restricted to
railroads and
a few other companies. From 1942 to 1964, most domestic affiliated
groups that met
the stock ownership and other requirements could file consolidated
returns, but
the surtax on such a group was increased by 2 percentage points. The
additional
tax on consolidated returns was repealed, effective December
31, 1963. The most important type
of income to have
received special
rates was "long-term" capital gains. From 1942 through 1987, the tax
rate was capped at a maximum rate lower than the highest corporate
rate. Although
there is currently no special rate for corporations’ capital gains,
long-term capital
gains are still treated separately from other income in the tax code. The
tax rate on long-term gains was reduced in 2003 to 15%, or to 5% for
individuals in the lowest two income tax brackets. Short-term capital
gains are
taxed at a higher rate: the ordinary income tax rate. The reduced 15%
tax rate
on eligible dividends and capital gains, previously scheduled to expire
in
2008, has been extended through 2010 as a result of the Tax Increase
Prevention
and Reconciliation Act signed into law by President Bush on May 17, 2006 (P.L. 109-222).
In 2011
these reduced tax rates will “sunset,” or revert to the rates in effect
before
2003, which were generally 20%. President Obama's budget, announced on February 25, 2009, calls for
the
Capital Gains Tax to be reverted to the 20% rate before the Sunset date
of
2011.
During World War
I, the
Great Depression, World War II, and
the Korean War, additional taxes were imposed on what were called “war
profits”
or “excess profits.” Taxes on Undistributed
Profit In addition to taxes
based on net income, there have been
from time to time taxes based on accumulated earnings that were not
distributed
to shareholders, designed to limit tax avoidance at the individual
stockholder
level. Taxes on “undue” accumulations have been imposed (though seldom
paid)
since the inception of the income tax. These were supplemented, since
1934, by
a “personal holding company” tax, equal to the highest individual
income tax
rate, on the undistributed earnings of closely held companies
accumulating
investment income. There was also a Depression-era tax on accumulated
earnings. History of Personal
Income Tax When the personal income
tax was
introduced in 1913, the top bracket was 7% for income over $5,000. By
1918, the
top rate had risen to 77% for income over $1,000,000. In 1921, the
administration of
Warren Harding lowered the top rate to 58% for income over $200,000. A
year
earlier, under Woodrow Wilson, income over $200,000 was taxed at 68%
while the top
rate was 72% for income over $1,000,000. In 1924, the administration of
Calvin
Coolidge lowered the top rate to 46% for income over $500,000. In 1924,
the top
rate was dropped sharply to 25% for income over $100,000.This rate stayed unchanged until to produce
the Roaring Twenties of sizzling speculation on margin while wages
stagnated
that ended in the crash of 1929. In 1932, the top rate
rose back to
63% for income over $1,000,000 and the rate for income over $100,000
was raised
to 56%. It was academic because very few people had income of these
brackets. In
1936, the top rate was 79% for income over $5,000,000 while the rate
for income
over $1,000,000 was raised to 77%. But there was no employment and no
corporate
profit to make a difference until the war started after Pearl Harbor
on December 7, 1941. Until the war started
people were willing to work just for food so there was no demand for
goods to
produce corporate profit. In 1941, the top rate was
raised
to 81% for income over $5,000,000. In 1942, to help pay for the war,
the top
rate was raised to 88% for income over $200,000 in a wartime price
control
regime. In 1944, the top rate was raised to 94% for income over
$200,000. In
1946, the top rate was lowered to 91% for income over $200,000. The
post war
economy took off to produce a new middle class as the majority of the
population. There were waiting lines, not at the unemployment offices,
but long
waiting lists for new cars and houses and television sets. In 1955, the top rate was
91% for
income over $400,000 to adjust for inflation with a median income of
$3,358. That rate stayed until
1966 when
it was lowered to 77% for income over $400,000 with a median income of
$5,306. In 1965, the top rate
was lowered
70% for income over $200,000. That rate stayed until 1982 with minor
rise in
the top bracket to income over $215.400. The period between 1965 and
1982 was
the gold years of US economy,
with high employment and high consumption, a period when guns and
butter was
both in ample supply. In 1982, the top rate was
lowered
to 50% for income over $85,000 with a median income of $13,950, while
the $85,600 bracket was taxed at
59% a
year earlier. In 1987, the top rate was lowered to 38.5% for income
over
$90,000. In 1988, the top rate was lowered to 33% for income over
$71,900 and
28% for income over $149.250. In 1991, the top rate was lowered to 31%
for
income over $32,000 with a median income of $20,469. In 1993, the top
rate rose to 39.6% for income
over
$250,000. In 2003, the top rate fell to 35% for income over income over
$311,950. In 2009, the top rate is 35%
for income over $372,950 with a median income of $33,168.
Wages began to stagnate as the tax on top icome bracket fell, while the
financial
elite
was keeping luxury goods maker busy by using the pension fund of worker
to move
jobs to low wage economies overseas. As American workers marvel at the
low
price import at Walt Mart, and their pension funds were giddy with high
returns, their own jobs at home are disappearing as the wages and
benefits ofr
those still working fall below living wage levels The average American wage
earner
has very little reason to support a lowering of the top rates in a
progressive
income tax regime if they understand that employers would rather give
tax
savings to employees in higher wages than pay high taxes to the
government,
given the same after-tax net profit. But the Wall Street
Journal or
CNBC would never tell workers that basic truth. Rather, workers are
told that
high taxes lead to high unemployment to scare wage earners into voting
for still
lower progressive rates that only benefit those who have been
oppressing
workers with the workers’ own pension money. December 10, 2009