The Socialist Revolution Started
90 Years Ago in China
By
Henry C.K. Liu
Part
I:
The Beginning
Part II:
Lessons
of Other Revolutions
Part III: Lessons of the
Soviet Experience
Part
IV: The Situation in China
Part V: Economic Surplus and Capital Formation
This article appeared in AToL
on November 19, 2009
For an underdeveloped feudal economy transitioning towards a
modern industrial growth path, one that is not isolated by hostile
forces such
as foreign embargos, the problem is not that economic surplus being too
small,
but that the way the economic surplus is produced and appropriated is
not
conducive to capital formation. In feudal economies, the main forms of
economic
surplus are land rent, usury interest rates and middleman profit. Only
a small
part of the surplus is capitalist profit in feudal economies because
land
assets had not found ways to become monetized capital which remained
trapped in
land that was not commercially traded.
Participants in the feudal economy, its agrarian sector in
particular, were predominantly landlords, moneylenders and commodity
traders,
while capitalists played no major role. The participants in a feudal
economy
produced their surpluses from narrow direct financial margins by
rack-renting
tenant farmers, squeezing debtors through usurious interest rates,
hoarding to
manipulate prices, etc., but the surplus was not invested to increase
productivity or output. These types of surplus were merely income
transfers from
the property-less class to the class that monopolized property in the
form of
land or money, and who had little incentive to improving labor
productivity.
Landlords in feudal societies were generally conservatives who felt
threatened
by changes, even changes towards productivity. They consumed their
surplus
through non-agricultural construction such as luxurious goods and grand
estates. Traders by definition were not interested in increasing
production,
only in high profit margins. Usurers were interested only in
transferring to
themselves, from distressed debtors, ownership of collateralized assets
that
required no further capital investment.
At the time of the founding of the People’s Republic in
1949, China’s
feudal economy was producing surpluses that were mostly
socio-economically
unproductive. The developmental problem then was how to transform these
structural socio-economic unproductive forms of surplus into new
productive
forms, leading to a rise in capital formation and hence in national
income.
Under capitalism, the approach to transformation was a
conservative, socially elitist and narrowly based one of reforming but
preserving the system of landed private property. Land reform took the
path of
paying financial compensation to landlords, and redistributing the land
thus
acquired through the market by selling to those who had money to buy.
This
method structurally limited land redistribution to a minority with
money, or
with access to money, and excluded the majority of the peasants who
worked on
the land and who needed land most. Thus, capitalism of the landed elite
was
promoted at the expense of a broad-based peasant socialization of
capital.
By contrast, the revolutionary socialist path was a
socio-economically broad-based one of abolishing private ownership and
the
associated system of rent and interest on debt. This was achieved by
seizing
the landed property of rentiers
without compensation, namely confiscating it in the name of the people,
followed by a free and egalitarian redistribution to peasants who
actually
worked on the land, and writing off all outstanding confiscatory
mortgages.
Given their improved economic status, the peasants then would evolve
capitalist
efficiency production “from below”.
In Japan,
the conservative path was exemplified by the Meiji land reform during
1869 to
1873, which abolished the feudal right to rent-cum-tax of the nobility (daimyo
and the samurai) only by paying them
compensation, namely, the
capitalized value of their rents as cash and bonds; and then taxed the
farmers
heavily to finance the compensation.
After World War II, US occupation regime in Japan under
General Douglas MacArthur, whom historian William Manchester labeled an
American Caesar,
instituted land reform in 1945, under which all land with
resident lords in excess of 1 cho (2.45 acres) was acquired
and
redistributed to the tenants on it at a nominal payment, while absentee
landlords were not allowed to keep even 1 cho, but had to
surrender all
their land for redistribution.
The insistence of the US
occupation regime in Japan
in the post-war period on land reform, up to that time the most
comprehensive
ever in Asia, arose from US
perception that the twin pillars of Japanese militarism had rested on
the zaibatsu,
monopolistic conglomerate, and the prevalence of petty tenancy, as
opposed to
owner-occupied land.
In contrast, the revolutionary path was exemplified by the
confiscation and free redistribution of land in the Soviet
Union
after 1917, and by the land reform program in China
after 1949. In this revolutionary approach, the egalitarian and free
redistribution of land to peasant households was thought of as the
successful
completion of an essentially capitalist task of doing away with feudal
property, and as a transitional phase to the eventual establishment of
production cooperatives and collectives, in which individual ownership
of the
material means of production would be replaced by cooperative and
collective
ownership in enlarged units.
Prior to land reform in China in1952, the total of land lord
net income in rural areas by way of land rent, usury interest and
profit
amounted to 16.9% of the value added in agriculture. Adding a 2.1% tax
paid by
land owners, a total of 19% of value added in agriculture (9.39 billion
yuan at
1952 prices) was taken from the farming peasants. Of this total, some
4.5
billion yuan was retained by farming peasants after land reform and 4.9
billion
went to the government in new taxes.
Thus the peasants benefited, and at the same time the new
socialist state had access to resources released by land reform to
support
socialist construction which included road building, hydroelectricity
development, free education and health care. This transfer of surplus
from the
agrarian sector to the state budget, expressed as a percentage of total
gross
and net domestic investment in the economy in 1952, amounted to 34.7%
and
44.8%. Land reform thus contributed significantly to needed development
finance.
Yet further capital formation for socialist development
needed to come from development planning since the increased income of
peasants
after land reform, while in theory could provide more saving for
investment,
was too low and given the residual abysmally low standard of living of
the
peasants before land reform, all he additional income from land reform
was
immediately consumed, for on a per family basis it worked out only to
about 55
yuan in 1952.
Thus egalitarian land reform, while eliminating a parasitic
landlord and taxation system, did not in itself generate a rapid rise
in
productive investment needed for output growth. In effect, poverty was
being
equitably shared by egalitarian land reform unsupported by wealth
creation
government measures.
Yet egalitarianism by itself is never the cause of poverty
or prosperity. It is just that egalitarianism can enhance prosperity
more
effectively when effective wealth creation policies are functioning.
A case in point in history is that of the founding Civil
Emperor (Wendi)
of the Sui dynasty (518-618), who, after his
coronation, took five
thousand buffalos from government lots and distributed them free to
impoverished farmers, helping to restore farm production.
He also opened state land reserves to the
landless, forbade the military to draft men under the age of
twenty-one,
reduced the annual tax burden by as much as 80%, shared with the people
revenues from state monopolies on wine and salt, exempted the elderly,
those
over fifty, from taxes and reduced the state’s take from farm harvests
by one
third. A central bureaucracy was
established and staffed with literati selected on merit through public
examinations. As a result, within a few
years of his socialist reign, the economy recovered totally from three
centuries
of war and destruction and grew with unprecedented prosperity. By the final year of his fifteen-year reign,
the state grain reserve was so large that it was sufficient to feed the
nation
for the next sixty years, albeit the population was only 50 million in
size.
In recent centuries, both as a result of population growth
and shrinkage of territory from persistent Western imperialist
encroachments, China
has become an agricultural economy deficient in cultivatable land for
the size
of its population. Thus China,
like England
in
earlier centuries, must either adopt an industrial policy to support
agricultural imports, or an emigration policy, or a population policy.
In the socialist perspective, land reform in itself is a
bourgeois measure taking socioeconomic evolution no further than the
French
Revolution had over two centuries ago. Land reform constituted a
necessary
condition for further institutional change towards a cooperative
society.
The urgent need to amalgamate peasant efforts for the
purpose of socialist investment is underscored by the accelerating
level of
environmental degradation and deforestation in China
before 1949 and after 1979. Countering the massive problems of
large-scale
deforestation, soil erosion and land degradation could not be
realistically
done on an individual basis or through the market mechanism. It
requires the
socialization of hundred of million of individual households on a
network of
local projects, not driven by individual profit incentives but by a
unified
sense of national purpose. In 1949, abysmally low standards of public
sanitation and health care, the prevalence of epidemic diseases from
snail
infested canals and mosquito infested water, called for a massive
collective
investment effort towards cleaning up the environment and initiating a
health
care system to provide service to those who needed it regardless of
their
purchasing power. Since 1979, public social infrastructure in
education, health
and pension has been allowed by policy to regress towards pre-1949
levels.
Latent
Economic Surplus Trapped by Unemployment and Underemployment
Marx observed that the internal contradiction of capitalism
is not the competition it fosters or its indifference to inequality.
Rather, it
is the structural problem of surplus labor which under the labor theory
of
value, translates into surplus value. To Marx, capitalism is a
self-terminating
system because it structurally deprives the worker of significant
portion of
the value of his work. Capitalism is built on the concept that value is
a
function of marginal utility which justifies the exploitation of many
by a few.
For Marxists, it follows that latent surplus value can
mobilized for the purpose of capital formation by the reduction of
unemployment
and underemployment of labor. In China,
this is particularly true for rural labor. Neoclassical economics,
based on the
concept of scarcity, invented the concept of surplus labor, deriving
from the
concept of surplus people as those who are economically unnecessary.
Market
fundamentalism creates in market economies the phenomenon of labor with
zero
marginal utility. This views flies in the face of reality that nations
with
large populations are economic powerhouses if full employment is
ensured by
policy. (Please see my July
28, 2005
article: Scarcity
Economics and Overcapacity)
The fallacy comes from treating labor as a commodity to be
traded in the market, a residual mentality of the slave society.
Economics
exists for the benefit of people. People exist as a matter of nature,
not for
making any economic system more efficient. The very idea of surplus
people in
an economy is obscene.
Market operations cannot deal effective with the employment
problem as long as employment is restricted to booster narrow economic
efficiency through a market mechanism. Full
employment must be a goal in all economic
systems, not structural
unemployment, as in the concept of non-accelerating inflation rate of
unemployment (NAIRU), defined as the rate of unemployment at which
there is
neither upward pressure on inflation (from producers taking advantage
of the
market power given them by bottlenecks, and from workers using the
market power
provided by a tight labor market to try to realize wage growth
aspirations
higher than the rate of productivity growth) nor downward pressure on
inflation
(from customers taking advantage of the market power given them by
excess
capacity, and from firms using the market power provided by high
unemployment
to try to decrease the rate of wage growth). Market capitalism thus
falls short
because it must use unemployment as a device to restrain inflation. Excess capital formation derived from
unemployment and underemployment leads structurally to overcapacity due
to
demand rising at a slower rate than productivity from overinvestment.
Capital formation can also be achieved with a system of
voluntary deferred wages where in every worker agrees to work longer
hours
without corresponding increase in pay in order to accumulate capital
with which
to increase productivity so that less labor can command higher wages in
the
future.
However, such a system will only work if the capital so
accumulated is collectively own and the benefits of additional
productivity is
equitably shared among workers who made the temporary sacrifice. Thus
mobilizing voluntary economic surplus towards capital formation can
only take
place in a socialist system. Under a capitalist system of private
ownership of
the means of production, only oppression of workers can produce capital
formation.
In China
in the 1950s, cooperatives with 300 households and people’s communes
with 3,500
households played a key role in voluntary mobilization of economic
surplus
toward productive capital formation to increase productivity.
During the crucial period of the transition to advanced
cooperatives, an awareness of the potential of cooperatives to mobilize
surplus
labor was recorded in Mao’s writings. In 1954, Mao wrote: “Under
present conditions of production
there is already a surplus of roughly one-third of labor power. What
required
three people in the past can be done by two after cooperative
transformation,
an indication of the superiority of socialism. Where can an outlet be
found for
this surplus labor power of one-third or more? For the most part, still
in the
country-side. …The masses have unlimited creative power. They can
organize
themselves to take on all spheres and branches of work where they can
give full
play to their energy, tackle production more intensively and
extensively, and
initiate more and more undertaking for their own well being.” (Mao
Zedong, Selected
Works, Beijing:
Foreign
Languages Press, 1978, p. 269.)
Local adaptations and variations were to take place within a
broad national policy of promoting undertakings in the following
sectors:
physical capital formation via land reclamation, hill terracing,
reforestation
and irrigation; infrastructure (roads, bridges and buildings);
hydroelectric
energy; rural businesses and industries; and human capital formation
(public
sanitation, health clinics and schools). The possibilities were
certainly
nearly limitless at this time given the existing abysmally low levels
of
material, educational and health development in the countryside. On
land
reclamation and reforestation Mao Zedong stressed the need for “state organized land reclamation by
settlers the plan being to bring 400 to 500 m. mu
of wasteland under cultivation in
the course
of three five year plans”. He went on to say: “I think
the barren
mountains in the north in particular should be afforested, and they
undoubtedly
can be. Do you comrades from the north have courage enough for this?
Many
places in the south need reforestation too. It will be fine if in a
number of
years we can see various places in the south and north clothed
with
greenery.”
Mao Zedong confidently expected, even within the advanced
cooperatives and before full collectivization, that the annual labor
days
employed per worker would rise substantially and that female
participation
rates would also rise as more rural undertakings were established,
existing
labor surplus thereby mobilized and increasing supply elicited: “Before
the cooperative transformation of agriculture,
surplus labor-power was a problem in many parts of the country. Since
then many
cooperatives have felt the pinch of a labor shortage and need to
mobilize the
masses of the women, who did not work in the fields before, to take
their place
on the labor front…. For many places the labor shortage becomes evident
as
production grows in scale, the number of undertakings increases, the
efforts to
remake nature become more extensive and intensive, and the work is done
more
thoroughly.”
Further, he goes on to say: “Things in this country also
show us that an outlet can be found in the villages for rural labor
power. As
management improves and the scope of production expands, every
able-bodied man
and woman can put in more work-days in the year. Instead of over one
hundred
workdays for a man and a few score for a woman as described in this
article the
former can put in well over two hundred workdays and the latter well
over one
hundred or more.”
The timing of the shift to the large-scale communes was not a happy
one; it
coincided with a run of very poor harvests complicated by floods in
some parts
of the country and attacks of pests in others. There was a very
substantial
downward deviation of output from the trend during 1959 to 1963, and
this has
complicated the evaluation of the shift ever since. There is a severe
problem
of causal identification here: it is arguable that even without the
institutional change to communes, output would have fallen anyway, for
agricultural output is subject to cyclical patterns of movement. Many
Western
scholars who are disposed to criticize the idea of large-scale
collective
production have, however, tended incorrectly to place the main burden
of the
output decline on the shift to the communes. What is probably true is
first,
that the decline which would have taken place anyway, was exacerbated
by the
initial severe management problems entailed in the shift.
The geopolitics of the Sino-Soviet split was a key factor.
In 1960, the Soviet Government unilaterally broke up 600 aid contracts
with
China, and notified the Chinese Government that it would withdrew all
its 1,390
experts, and stop sending the agreed upon 900 new experts. The Soviet
experts
left with all their blueprints, plans and materials. The Soviet
Government also
stopped delivering urgently needed equipment and parts to China.
As result, the construction and operation of over 250 large industrial
enterprises
had to be suspended. This put a halt to heavy industrial development
and
greatly exacerbated China’s
economic difficulties in the following decade.
Since 1979, average income in rural areas has lagged far
behind the average in cities, giving China
one of the highest income disparity measures in the world. Many farmers
still work
on tiny, state-allocated plots of land for a small fraction of the
year,
investing little in agriculture. While they are entitled to 30-year
land-use
contracts, the state retains ownership of rural land, and local
authorities sometimes
seize or reallocate farm land to suit their non-agricultural
development
priorities.
Rural land disputes are perhaps the biggest source of social
unrest in China.
Protests and riots in rural areas number in the thousands each year,
according
to national police estimates. They are often incited by allegations of
corruption and illegal land seizures.
Many farmers leave the land to seek work in cities, but they
are still classified as farmers under the country’s population control
policies
and tend to work in low-wage factory or construction jobs on a seasonal
basis.
Advocates for land reform say the proposed changes would
create more asset wealth for farmers and strengthen land security,
which would
in turn encourage peasants to invest in farming and increase
productivity.
A law enacted in 2002 allows limited land-use trades between
individual farmers, but does not permit unrestricted trade between
farmers and
companies, straight sales of land-use rights or the option to use the
land as
collateral to obtain a loan.
The major state news organizations reported that rural land
reform was at the top of the agenda for the plenary session. China
Daily, the
country’s official English-language newspaper, reported, “The meeting
is
expected to make it easier for farmers to lease or transfer the
management
rights of their land, measures that have become necessary as many
farmers move
to cities as migrant workers.”
Private ownership of land is not allowed under the
Constitution, and rural land is still effectively controlled by
township- and
village-level leaders. Officials characterize the proposed policy
changes as
allowing the farmers to lease or trade their 30-year land-use contracts
to
individuals or companies.
The issue remains a delicate one. Many party traditionalists
strongly favor collective land ownership. They have argued that China’s
economy is still not robust enough to absorb hundreds of millions of
rural
laborers full time. They also defend the system of allocating small
plots of
land to all rural families as guaranteeing farmers at least a
subsistence
income.
But repeated efforts to enliven the rural economy without
freeing up land have failed, and proponents of moving toward partial
privatization appear to have the upper hand.
One point under discussion is whether land contracts should
be extended to 70 years from 30 years, a move that would
give
farmers more security and presumably increase the value of their
land-use
rights.
In the Soviet Union, the percentage of planned output
achieved by
important industries at the end of successive five-year plans, in
“value-added”
terms, was impressive. The first five-year plan (1928-32) achieved 75
percent
of its target, the second (1932-37), 76 percent. The plan ending in
1950
achieved 94 percent and 1955 achieved 99 percent. Yet the area of
trouble in
Soviet planning was in agriculture, not so much in the state farms but
in the
collective farms made of small farmers. The knotty problem of reward
and
incentive in collective enterprise has yet to be solved by human
ingenuity. The
same was also true in China. When China abandoned collective farming, the
agricultural
problem also eased, but it was not solved, even today. In the US, free-market principles never touched
agriculture,
which has remained a fortress of government subsidy.
On June 27, 1981,
the sixth plenary session of the 11th Central Committee Congress of
Communist
Party of China adopted unanimously an official resolution on certain
question
related to the Founding of the Nation: Concerning economic development
during
the Mao Zedong era:
The
accomplishment we have achieved over the past 32 years is still
significant. To
neglect or denied our accomplishment, and to neglect or deny the
successful
experience we gained from these achievements, would be a serious
mistake.
From 1953 to
1956, the nation’s gross value of industrial output on average
increased
progressively every year by 19.6%. The total agricultural output value
on
average increased progressively every year by 4.8%. The economic
development
was relatively rapid, the economic effect relatively good and the
proportional
balance between the major sectors of the economy relative well
coordinated. The
market was prosperous with price stability. The livelihood of the
people
improved remarkably.
In April, 1956, Comrade Mao Zedong summarized in
his
speech "Discusses Ten Big Relations":
"Our country’s
initial socialist
construction experience, and proposed the task of exploring a path
towards
socialist construction that would suit our national conditions.
After the
completion of basic socialist transformation, our party leads all of
the
nation’s various nationalities to start to change over to the
comprehensive
large-scale socialist construction. Until the eve of the decade-long
Great
Cultural Revolution, despite having encountered serious setbacks, we
still
achieved the very great accomplishments.
A very major
part of the material and technical foundation we now depend on to carry
on the
program of modernization had been built during that period. The
backbone
strength behind the effort for national economic cultural construction
and
their work experience had also been mostly cultivated and accumulated
in this
period. This had been the Party’s main task in this period."
On top of rising income, farmers during the Cultural Revolution decade
enjoyed
free education and free rudimentary health care, which they never
enjoyed
before or after. In 1965, with the launch of the Cultural Revolution,
Mao
expanded the
idea of health for the masses beyond infectious disease. Mao
proclaimed: “In
health and medical work, put the stress on rural areas.” With that, China's
cadre of “barefoot doctors” was born. These health care programs were
called
“rural cooperative medical systems” (RCMS) and strove to include
community
participation with the rural provision of health services. It became a
model
health care program much admired and copied by the world’s developing
countries.
Barefoot
Doctors - A Peasant Medical Force
Hundred of thousand of peasants – young men and women mostly
in their 20s with some general education were selected for an intensive
three-
to six-month course in medical training. They were instructed in
anatomy, bacteriology,
diagnosing disease, acupuncture, prescribing traditional and Western
medicines,
birth control and maternal and infant care. They came to be known as
barefoot
doctors because some of them were not even equipped with shoes.
The barefoot doctors continued their farming work in the
commune fields, working alongside their comrades. Their proximity also
made
them readily available to help those in need. They provided basic
health care:
first aid, immunizations against diseases such as diphtheria, whooping
cough
and measles. They provided health education. They taught hygiene as
basic as
washing hands before eating and after using latrines. Illnesses beyond
their
training, the barefoot doctors referred on to physicians at commune
health
centers.
Ten years after the Cultural Revolution, there were an
estimated 1 million barefoot doctors in China.
In the 1970s, the World Health Organization and leaders in some
developing
countries -- even the Soviet Union -- began to
consider China's
program as an alternate model to Western-style health care. They were
looking
for inexpensive ways to deliver health care to rural populations; China
had seemed to set up a successful model.
But the barefoot doctors program largely fell apart after
1979. The central government provided less financial support for the
program,
and the country’s emerging free-market system began forcing farmers to
pay for
their health care. The World Health Organization recently ranked China
as fourth-worst out of 190 countries for equality of health care. To
correct
the regression, the government recently adopted an universal medical
insurance
program.
Yet 40 years after the program began, the program still
holds allure, and lessons, for health officials around the world
looking for a
solution for inadequate rural health care. There is also recognition
outside of China
that the
country did go much further than other countries of comparable wealth
in
reducing infectious diseases, such as polio, smallpox and
schistosomiasis
during this period,
On a visit in 1972, American doctor Victor Sidel praised the
program for supplying health care where previously there had been none;
he also
singled out the barefoot doctors themselves for their role as patient
advocates.
Next: Socialist Democracy and the Great Proletariat Cultural
Revolution
|