Federal Reserve Power
Unsupported by
Credibility
By
Henry C.K. Liu
Part I: No Exit
This article appeared in AToL on September
11, 2009 as Boogged
Down at the Fed
Ben S. Bernanke, a Republican who was first
appointed by
President Bush nearly four years ago as Chairman of the Board of the
Federal
Reserve, has been reappointed to a second term by Democratic President
Obama.
The announcement during the President’s summer vacation in Martha’s
Vineyard
served to divert attention from unwelcome figures released on August 25
by the White House budget office that
forecast a cumulative $9
trillion fiscal deficit from 2010-2019, $2 trillion more than the
administration estimated in May. The federal government will spend
$2.98
trillion in fiscal 2009, $3.766 trillion in fiscal 2010 and $5.307
trillion in
fiscal 2019, all substantially more than projected revenue.
Moreover, the figures show the national debt doubling by 2019 to $20.78 trillion,
reaching
three-quarters of the projected gross domestic product (GDP), with
alarming projections
of additional $2 trillion from $12.8 trillion in 2009 to $14.5 trillion
in 2010.
In fiscal 2008, according the Bureau of the Public Debt, a division of
the Treasury
Department, the federal government paid $451 billion in interest on the
debt.
In July 2008, the Treasury was paying an average interest rate of
4.382%
on that debt. A year later, in July 2009, Treasury was paying an
average
interest rate of 3.418%, even as the Fed was doing its utmost to keep
interest
rates down. If interest rates go up in the out years as expected,
the Treasury
would be forced to pay more per year to service the national debt—even
if the
debt itself did not grow.
The President characterized Bernanke’s
reappointment as
seeking to keep “a mood of stability in the financial markets” while
acknowledging that economic recovery can be expected to be a long way
off. The reappointment was a sign of
continuity of
long-standing Fed monetary policy in contrast to Obama’s campaign
rhetoric of “change
we can believe in.”
Bernanke is closely identified with Fed policies
that had
landed the global economy in its current sorry state. Many,
particularly conservative
Republicans, Blue Dog Democrats, and even progressives, are concerned
about
Obama’s proposals to expand the powers of the Fed, in view of its
history of
persistent failure to spot and preempt pending systemic financial
crises.
Critics question the wisdom of giving an institution with such poor
record of
performance the prime role as a systemic risk regulator in the proposed
regulatory overhaul of the financial system.
Opposition to the reappointment of Bernanke can
be traced to
three aspects. The first is ideological: despite Bernanke’s
subscription to
Milton Friedman’s non-provable counterfactual conclusion that central
banks can
eliminate market crashes with timely and aggressive monetary easing,
Bernanke is
on the same ideological side of his predecessor – serial bubble wizard
Alan
Greenspan – who had argued that monetary authorities are best
positioned to
clean up the mess after the bursting of asset bubbles than to pre-empt
the forming
of the bubble itself. This ideological fixation of the Fed proper role
as a
cleanup crew rather than the preventive guardian of good systemic
health, which
Greenspan has since acknowledged as a grievous error, eventually led to
the
systemic financial collapse of 2007. (Please see my August 24, 2007 AToL
article: Central Bank Impotence and Market Liquidity)
The second aspect is analytical: Bernanke, as
Fed
chairman-designate waiting confirmation, argued in a speech on March 29, 2005 while still a
Fed
governor, that a “global savings glut” has depressed US
interest rates since 2000. Echoing this view, Greenspan testified
before
Congress on July 20 that this glut is one of the factors behind the
so-called “interest
rate conundrum”, i.e., declining long-term rates despite rising
short-term
rates. In reality, there was no savings glut, only a dollar glut that
went
overseas as US
debt from trade deficits and returned to the US
as savings of low income Asians because of dollar hegemony in which
Asians
cannot spent dollars in their domestic economies without inflation.
(Please see
my January 11, 2006
AToL
article: Of Debt, Deflation and Rotten Apples)
The third aspect relates to policy: Bernanke is a card carrying market
fundamentalist who believes that markets can best be self regulated. He
and
Greenspan repeatedly opposed financial market regulation beyond even
ideological
grounds to argue also on operational ground that US regulation would
merely
drive market participants overseas to less regulated jurisdictions and
that the
US will not accept international coordination that threatens national
sovereignty. On regulation, Bernanke is of the school of “if I don’t
smoke,
somebody else will”. (Please see my January 10, 2004 AToL article: Fed’s Pugnacious Policies Hurt Economies)
Need to Rein In the Wayward
Financial Sector
In the aftermath of the
outbreak of the financial
crisis in July 2007, summit meetings of world leaders have since
repeatedly
focused on the need of international coordination of financial
regulatory
regimes. In an interview with the Financial Times, UK Prime Minister
Gordon Brown
expressed hope that the third G20 leaders summit meeting in Pittsburgh
in
September 2009 would agree on a “global compact for growth” that would
include
coordinated steps to withdraw stimulus packages and government support
for
banks, adding that the UK could not be expected to take action
unilaterally on
outsized banker remuneration.
Adair Turner, chairman of the Financial Services
Authority
(FSA), Britain’s
top banking supervisor, now supports the idea of new global taxes on
financial
transactions, warning that a “swollen” financial sector paying
excessive
salaries has grown too big for society. This is an idea that is
equivalent to a
financial parallel to the Kyoto Protocol on climate change, which for
years the US
had dragged
its feet in supporting.
In an interview in Prospect
magazine published on August 27, Lord Turner says the debate on
bankers’
bonuses has become a “populist diversion” from the real need for more
drastic
measures to cut the financial sector down to size. He also says the FSA
should
“be very, very wary of seeing the competitiveness of London
as a major aim”, claiming the city’s financial sector has become a
destabilizing factor in the British economy. The Bernanke Fed has yet
to take
similarly progressive positions in response to the financialization of
the US
and global economies and the role Wall Street plays in them.
On all three aspects, there are no signs that
Bernanke has
turned a new leaf intellectually or professionally from his sordid
past. And his
dysfunctional fixations have impaired the effectiveness of the Fed’s
unconventional
policy directions and unprecedented rescue actions in dealing with the
two-year-old financial crisis. The Fed’s radical surgery is only
revolutionary
in operational protocol, aiming to keep the patient alive longer with
the
disease rather than to cure the disease.
Bernanke the Incredible Hero
Yet for Wall Street, Bernanke has become the
hero of the
hour. Not surprisingly, since his self-described “bold and creative”
actions in
the financial crisis have saved Wall Street from imminent total
suicidal collapse
at the expense of the long-term health of the economy and the
sustainable strength
of the dollar.
This is the hero who on March
28, 2007,
some 100 days before worldwide spread of the US subprime mortgage
crisis, told
the Joint Economic Committee of Congress: “To date, the incoming data
have
supported the view that the current stance of policy [with Fed Funds
rate
target at a high 5.25%] is likely to foster sustainable economic growth
and a
gradual ebbing in core inflation.” Bernanke
challenged market expectations of
early Fed interest rate cuts,
saying he was comfortable with rates on hold despite adverse economic
data.
This is the monetary equivalent of the captain of the Titanic ordering
“steady
as she goes” with a huge iceberg 100 yards ahead.
In the same testimony, Bernanke signaled that
Fed policy had
not shifted to even a neutral policy stance “away from an inflation
bias”, let
alone an accommodating stance in response to an imminent crisis that he
failed to
see coming at him like a runaway train at full speed. His remarks
helped prompt
a near 100-point fall in the Dow Jones Industrial Average the next day.
Bernanke also brushed aside comments by Alan
Greenspan, his
predecessor who at last began to see the light, that the expansion
looked to be
“ageing”, implying the possibility of a recession on the horizon. More
ominously, Bernanke played down the threat from the subprime mortgage
market on
even the US
financial
system, let alone the global system which the US
component dominated. He missed entirely the fast closing window of
opportunity
to stop the housing bubble from bursting abruptly with massive timely
injection
of money into the banking system.
Instead, Bernanke told Congress in a tone devoid
of any
sense of urgency: “The magnitude of the slowdown has been somewhat
greater than
would be expected given the normal evolution of the business cycle.”
And he
dismissed as alarmist the concern of some market analysts and
participants over
the clearly visible signs of distress in the subprime mortgage market
and its serious
systemic impact globally.
“At this juncture . . . the impact [of the
distressed
subprime mortgage market] on the broader economy and financial markets
. . .
seems likely to be contained," he said in a statement that will go down
in
history as being as infamous as President Hoover’s “prosperity is just
around
the corner” after the 1929 market crash.
Bernanke also told Congress that consumer
spending “has
continued to be well maintained so far this year,” and consumption
“should
continue to support the economic expansion in the coming quarters.” The economy has not recorded an expansion in
the
5 quarters since that pathetic pronouncement and the consumer spending
well has
run dry.
Eleven days earlier, and four months before the
credit
crisis broke out in July, I had warned my readers about the
inevitability of a
global systemic crisis in my March 17, 2007 AToL article: Why
the
Subprime Bust Will Spread.
It is a puzzle that the Chairman of the Federal
Reserve, even
with the benefit of a huge research and analysis staff, supported by
privileged
access to early data, backed by a peerless academic reputation, could
miss what
appeared obvious to a lowly independent observer relying on the mass
media for
information.
Two years before the credit crisis first broke
out in July
1007, I wrote in my September
14, 2005
article on AToL: Greenspan - the Wizard of Bubbleland:
The Kansas City
Federal Reserve
Bank annual symposium at Jackson Hole, Wyoming is a ritual in which
central bankers
from major economies all over the world, backed by their supporting
cast of
court jesters masquerading as monetary economists, privately
rationalize their
unmerited yet enormous power over the fate of the global economy by
publicly
confessing that while their collective knowledge is grossly inadequate
for the
daunting challenge of the task entrusted to them, their faith-based
dogma
nevertheless should remain above question.
That dogma is based on a
single-dimensional theology that sound money is the sine qua non
of
economic well-being. It is a peculiar ideology given that central
banking as an
institution derives its raison
d’etre from the rejection of a rigid gold standard in favor of
monetary
elasticity. In plain language, central banking sees as its prime
function
the management of the money supply to fit the transactional needs of
the
economy, instead of fixing the amount of money in circulation by the
amount of
gold held by the money-issuing authority.
Thus central bankers believe in
sound money, but not too sound please, lest the economy should falter.
Their
mantra is borrowed from the Confessions of St
Augustine: “God, give me chastity and continence
- but
not just now.”
This year [2005], the annual
august gathering in August took on special fanfare as it marked the
final
appearance of Alan Greenspan as Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board
of
Governors. Among the several interrelated options of controlling the
money
supply, the Federal Reserve, acting as a fourth branch of government
based on
dubious constitutional legitimacy and head of the global central
banking snake
based on dollar hegemony, has selected interest rate policy as the
instrument
of choice for managing the economy all through the 18-year stewardship
of Alan
Greenspan, on whom much accolade was showered by invited participants
in the
Jackson Hole seminar in anticipation of his retirement in early
2006.
Greenspan’s formula of reducing
market regulation by substituting it with post-crisis intervention is
merely
buying borrowed extensions of the boom with amplified severity of the
inevitable bust down the road. The Fed is increasingly reduced by this
formula
to an irrelevant role of explaining an anarchic economy rather than
directing
it towards a rational paradigm. It has adopted the role of a clean-up
crew of
otherwise avoidable financial debris rather than that of a preventive
guardian
of public financial health.
Greenspan’s monetary approach has
been when in doubt, ease. This means injecting more money into
the
banking system whenever the economy shows signs of faltering, even if
caused by
structural imbalances rather than monetary tightness. For almost
two
decades, Greenspan has justifiably been in near-constant doubt about
structural
balances in the economy, yet his response to mounting imbalances has
invariably
been the administration of off-the-shelf monetary laxative, leading to
a
serious case of lingering monetary diarrhea that manifests itself in
run-away
asset price inflation mistaken for growth.
In my article: The
Fed Created Serial Bubbles by Policy, posted on June 18, 2009 on
the
website of NewDeal20.org, a project of the Franklin and Eleanor
Roosevelt
Institute, I repeated my observation:
Greenspan,
notwithstanding his
denial of responsibility in helping throughout the 1990s to unleash the
equity
bubble, had this to say in 2004 in hindsight after the bubble burst in
2000:
“Instead of trying to contain a putative bubble by drastic actions with
largely
unpredictable consequences, we chose, as we noted in our mid-1999
congressional
testimony, to focus on policies to mitigate the fallout when it occurs
and,
hopefully, ease the transition to the next expansion.”
By the next expansion, Greenspan
meant the next bubble which manifested itself in housing. The
mitigating policy
was a massive injection of liquidity into the banking system. There is
a structural
reason why the housing bubble replaced the high-tech bubble.
Alan Greenspan, who from 1987 to
2006 was chairman of the Board of Governors of US Federal Reserve - the
head of
the global central banking snake by virtue of dollar hegemony -
embraced the
counterfactual conclusion of Milton Friedman that monetarist measures
by the
central bank can perpetuate the boom phase of the business cycle
indefinitely,
banishing the bust phase from finance capitalism altogether.
Going beyond Friedman, Greenspan
asserted that a good central bank could perform a monetary miracle
simply by
adding liquidity to maintain a booming financial market by easing at
the
slightest hint of market correction.
This ignored the fundamental law
of finance that if liquidity is exploited to manipulate excess debt as
phantom
equity on a global scale, liquidity can act as a flammable agent to
turn a
simple localized credit crunch into a systemic fire storm.
Ben Bernanke, Greenspan’s
successor at the Fed since February 1, 2006, also believes that a
“good”
central banker can make all the difference in banishing depressions
forever,
arguing on record in 2000 that, as Friedman claimed, the
1929 stock market crash could have
been avoided if the Fed had not dropped the monetary ball. That belief
had been
a doctrinal prerequisite for any candidate up for consideration for the
post of
top central banker by President George W Bush. Yet all the Greenspan
era proved
was that mainstream monetary economists have been reading the same
books and
buying the same counterfactual conclusion. Friedman’s “Only money
matters”
turned out to be a very dangerous slogan.
Both Greenspan and Bernanke had
been seduced by the convenience of easy money and fell into an
addiction to it
by forgetting that, even according to Friedman, the role of central
banking is
to maintain the value of money to ensure steady, sustainable economic
growth,
and to moderate cycles of boom and bust by avoiding destructively big
swings in
money supply. Friedman called for a steady increase of the money supply
at an
annual rate of 3% to achieve a non-accelerating inflation rate of
unemployment
(NAIRU) as a solution to stagflation, when inflation itself causes high
unemployment.
Fight Fire by Throwing Sound Money out the Window
Now in August 2009, two years after the credit
crisis
imploded in a global full fledge financial crisis, as central bankers
from
around the world gathered again at their annual August ritual in
Jackson Hole,
the imperative of sound money, the key dogma of central banking, is
temporarily
discarded to the waste basket in order to bail out the world’s
financial system
that has collapsed from excess debt made possible by easy money with
more easy
money from central banks to shift the debt to the public sector.
The justification is the need to first put out
the raging
fire before arresting the responsible arson through a dragnet of
regulatory reform.
Yet the Fed’s way of fighting the raging fire was to pour on it more
oil in the
form of easier money. It is a case of the arson performing the role of
the fire
fighter, to direct the fire away from its path towards the few who
caused it,
towards innocent victims in the general population. Part of the fire
has since
burned itself out inside a firebreak built by an expanded Fed balance
sheet,
but the fire itself is far from being totally extinguished and is
spreading
underground in a classic coal mine burn that can be expected to smolder
for
years.
Irresponsible Optimism
In this context, the gathering central bankers
at Jackson Hole reportedly expressed growing
confidence that the worst of the
global financial crisis is over and that a global economic recovery is
beginning to take shape.
This is an irresponsibly optimistic assessment
that borders
on fantasy, by a powerful fraternity of questionable legitimacy and
bankrupt credibility.
The global financial system may be showing signs of zombie stirring
caused by
bailout money from the Fed and other central banks, but the toxic
assets that
plight the global economy have not been extinguished and still pose a
major
threat to real recovery. The global economy is still in need of
intensive care
with a debt virus that is mutating into a strain stubbornly resistant
to
monetary cures.
Transferring Private Debt into Public Debt
What the Fed has done in the past two years is
to transfer
massive amounts of private sector toxic debt to the public sector by
‘aggressively and innovatively’ expanding the Fed’s balance sheet. This approach may require a decade or more to
unwound the massive amount of toxic debt in the system, both in the
private and
public sectors, delaying true economic recovery.
The approach adopted by the Treasury and the Fed
to deal
with a financial crisis of unsustainable debt created by excess
liquidity is to
inject into the economy more liquidity in the form of new public debt
denominated
in newly created money and to channel it to debt-laden institutions to
re-inflate
a burst debt-driven asset price bubble.
The Treasury does not have any power to create
money. Its
revenue comes mainly from taxes. But it has the ability to issue
sovereign debt
with the full faith and credit of the nation. When the Treasury runs a
deficit,
it has to borrow from the credit market, thus crowding out private debt
with
public debt.
The Fed has the authority to create new money
which it can
use to buy Treasury securities to monetize the public debt. But while
the Fed
can create new money, it cannot create wealth which can only be created
by work.
Unfortunately, the Fed’s new money has not been going to
workers/consumers in
the form of rising wages from full employment to restore fallen
consumer demand,
but instead has been going only to debt-infested distressed
institutions to
allow them to de-leverage toxic debt. Thus deflation in the equity
market
(falling share prices) has been cushioned by newly issued money, while
aggregate wage income continues to fall to further reduce aggregate
demand that
will cause companies to layoff workers to reduce overcapacity. Until
this
vicious cycle is broken by proper monetary and fiscal policies, no
economic
recovery can come.
Falling demand deflates commodity prices, but
not enough to
restore demand because aggregate wages are falling faster. When
financial
institutions de-leverage with free money from the central bank, the
creditors
receive the money while the Fed assumes the toxic liability by
expanding its
balance sheet. De-leverage reduces financing costs while increases cash
flow to
allow zombie financial institutions to return to nominal profitability
with
unearned income while laying off workers to cut operational cost.
Thus we have financial profit inflation with
price deflation
in a shrinking economy. What we will have going forward is not Weimar
Republic
type price hyperinflation, but a financial profit inflation in which
zombie
financial institutions turning nominally profitable in a collapsing
economy.
The danger is that this unearned nominal financial profit is mistaken
as a sign
of economic recovery, inducing the public to invest what remaining
wealth they
still hold only to lose more of it at the next market melt down which
will come
when the profit bubble bursts.
Ballooned Fed Balance Sheet
On April
3, 2009,
Bernanke, Fed Chairman since February
1, 2006, opened his speech at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond
2009 Credit Markets Symposium held in Charlotte,
North Carolina as
follows:
In ordinary
financial and economic
times, my topic, “The Federal Reserve’s Balance Sheet," might not be
considered a "grabber.” But these are far from ordinary times. To
address
the current crisis, the Federal Reserve has taken a number of
aggressive and
creative policy actions, many of which are reflected in the size and
composition of the Fed's balance sheet. So, I thought that a brief
guided tour
of our balance sheet might be an instructive way to discuss the Fed's
policy
strategy and some related issues. As I will discuss, we no longer live
in a
world in which central bank policies are confined to adjusting the
short-term
interest rate. Instead, by using their balance sheets, the Federal
Reserve and
other central banks are developing new tools to ease financial
conditions and
support economic growth.
Bernanke then outlines some principles of a new
creative Fed
balance sheet policy at an unusual time when financial markets and
institutions
both in the US and globally have been under extraordinary stress for
more than
a year and a half. He asserts that relieving the disruptions in credit
markets
and restoring the flow of credit to households and businesses are
essential for
the gradual resumption of sustainable economic growth. To achieve this
critical
objective, the Federal Reserve has worked closely and cooperatively
with the
Treasury and other agencies. Such collaboration is not unusual. The Fed
has
traditionally worked in close concert with other agencies in fostering
stable
financial conditions, even as it maintained independent responsibility
for
making monetary policy.
While the Fed has been creative in deploying its
balance
sheet, using a multiplicity of new programs (and coining a multiplicity
of new
acronyms), Bernanke claims it has done so prudently. As much as
possible, the
Fed has sought to avoid both credit risk and credit allocation in its
lending
and securities purchase programs. Fed programs have been aimed at
improving
financial and credit conditions broadly, with an eye toward restoring
overall
economic growth, rather than toward supporting narrowly defined sectors
or
classes of borrowers.
Credit Easing, Not Quantitative Easing
In pursuing its strategy, which Bernanke calls
“credit
easing”, instead of the traditional “quantitative easing”, the Fed has
also
taken care to design its programs so that it can unwound them as
markets and
the economy revive, at least in theory. In particular, these activities
must
not constrain the exercise of monetary policy as needed to meet
congressional
mandate to foster maximum sustainable employment and stable prices.
This may
mean Fed emergency programs cannot be fully unwound for decades, thus
hampering
the achievement of sustainable long-term full employment and price
stability.
On March
23, 2006,
the Fed under Bernanke stopped tracking M3, the broadest measure of US
money supply, arguing it had not been used in interest rate decisions
for some
time, as if that was a rational justification rather than an
operational
neglect that needed to be corrected. The term ‘credit easing’ reflects
the
Fed’s focus on bank balance sheets, rather than ‘quantitative easing’
which
describes the boosting of the money supply.
Bernanke’s credit easing did not help consumer
credit which decreased
at an annual rate of 5-1/4% in the Q2 2009. Revolving credit decreased
at an
annual rate of 8-1/4%, and non-revolving credit decreased at an annual
rate of 3-1/2%.
In June, 2009, consumer credit decreased at an annual rate of 5%.
Consumer credit peak at $2.6 trillion in Q3,
2008 and fell to
$2.5 trillion in June 2009 falling $100 billion. Outstanding consumer
credit
has been contracting for five months straight, falling $10.3 billion
from May
to June 2009 and down 4.9% on an annual basis. Credit throughout the US
economy has been flat or in decline as banks tightened their lending
standards,
and as over-burdened businesses and households frantically tried to pay
down
debt accumulated during the boom.
A look at money rather than credit, however,
shows clearly the
effect of Fed credit easing policies. Broad money growth began to
accelerate
early 2009 in the US.
Fed purchases of private sector toxic financial assets provide distress
US
companies and households with additional funds. Instead of spending,
the
recipients of such funds prudently paid down debt to avoid insolvency.
But the European Central Bank, which still
tracks money
supply, show no comparable upturn.
How and When
The Fed’s monetary myopia shifts the problem of
exiting emergency
policies from ‘how’ to ‘when’, with the flawed assumption that pain in
the
future must necessarily be less acute. Focusing on lagging indicators,
which
reflect past situations, increases the chances that the Fed will
overshoot both
in degree and duration with policy stance. Credit expansion through Fed
credit easing
can also cause excess money creation as de-leveraging runs its course.
Hyman
Minsky observed: whenever credit is issued, money is created.
Writing in defense of his strategy in the
Financial Times on
July 21, 2009 on The
Fed’s Exit Strategy, Bernanke asserts that Federal Reserve
reduction of the
Fed Funds rate target nearly to zero, together with greatly expanded
Fed
balance sheet as a result of Fed purchases
of longer-term securities and targeted lending programs aimed at
restarting the
flow of credit, “have softened the economic impact of the financial
crisis” and
“improved the functioning of key credit markets, including the markets
for
interbank lending, commercial paper, consumer and small-business
credit, and
residential mortgages.”
Bernanke acknowledged that Fed accommodative
policies will
likely be warranted for “an extended period”. Yet
he did not address the issue of what
happens to the value of the
dollar during this extended period. The US Treasury will not go
bankrupt, but
the US dollar can fall to a level that will threaten the US
economy with bankruptcy.
At some point after the extended period,
Bernanke wrote, as
economic recovery takes hold, the Fed will need to tighten monetary
policy to
prevent the emergence of an inflation problem down the road. Bernanke
reports
that the Federal Open Market Committee, which is responsible for
setting US
monetary policy, has devoted considerable time to issues relating to an
exit
strategy, with confidence that the Fed has the necessary tools to
withdraw
policy accommodation, when that becomes appropriate, in a smooth and
timely
manner. Thus the question is not ‘how,
but ‘when’.
Bernanke notes that the Fed’s exit strategy is
closely tied
to the management of the Federal Reserve balance sheet. When the Fed
makes loans
or acquires securities, the funds enter the banking system and
ultimately
appear in the reserve accounts held at the Fed by banks and other
depository
institutions. These reserve balances now total about $800 billion, much
more
than normal. And given the current economic conditions, banks have
generally
held their reserves as balances at the Fed.
The Fed and Liquidity Trap
This is known as the Fed pushing on a credit string with Fed money
given to
banks sitting idle in reserve accounts at the Fed because banks cannot
find
credit worthy borrowers. Keynes called this phenomenon a liquidity trap
as
nominal interest rate lowered to near zero, liquidity preference in the market fails to stimulate the economy to
full employment. In an earlier speech, Bernanke had refered to a
statement made
by Milton Friedman about using a “helicopter drop” of money into the
economy,
presumably for everyone equally, to fight deflation, earning his
nickname
Helicopter Ben. But Ben’s helicopter so far is still sitting idle on
the ground
while shiploand of taxpayer money have been railroaded to distress
institutions.
But Bernanke explains that as the economy
recovers, banks
should find more opportunities to lend out their reserves. Yet he was
vague
about how the economy would recover beyond a general faith that what
goes down
will eventually go back up. Yet in the history of nations, many have
gone down
without recovering their former greatness.
Bernanke argues that recovery when it comes
would produce
faster growth in broad money (for example, M1 or M2) and easier credit
conditions, which could ultimately result in inflationary
pressures—unless the
Fed adopts countervailing policy measures. When the time comes to
tighten
monetary policy, the Fed must either eliminate these large reserve
balances or,
if they remain, neutralize any potential undesired effects on the
economy.
Bernanke believes that, to some extent, reserves
held by
banks at the Fed will contract automatically, as improving financial
conditions
lead to reduced use of the Fed’s short-term lending facilities, and
ultimately
to their wind down. He points out that short-term credit extended by
the Fed to
financial institutions and other market participants has fallen to less
than
$600 billion as of mid-July 2009 from about $1.5 trillion at the end of
2008.
In addition, reserves could be reduced by about $100 billion to $200
billion
each year over the next few years as securities held by the Fed mature
or are
prepaid.
However, Bernanke admits that reserves likely
would remain
quite high for several years unless additional policies are undertaken.
He
asserts that even if Fed balance sheet stays large for a while, the Fed
still has
two broad means of tightening monetary policy at the appropriate time:
paying
interest on reserve balances and taking various actions that reduce the
stock
of reserves. The Fed could use either of these approaches alone;
however, to
ensure effectiveness, it likely would use both in combination.
Congress granted the Fed authority in the fall
of 2008 to
pay interest on balances held by banks at the Fed. This is a
controversial
development because it reduces pressure on banking to lend money in the
economy
to finance economic activities.
Currently, the Fed pay banks an interest rate of
0.25%. Bernanke
indicates that when the time comes to tighten policy, the Fed can raise
the
rate paid on reserve balances as it increases the federal funds rate
target.
Needless to say, this will retard economic recovery as it gathers steam.
Banks generally will not lend funds in the money
market at
an interest rate lower than the rate they can earn risk-free at the
Federal
Reserve. Moreover, they can be expected to compete to borrow any funds
that are
offered in private markets at rates below the interest rate on reserve
balances
because, by so doing, they can earn a spread without risk.
Thus the interest rate that the Fed pays would
tend to put a
floor under short-term market rates, including its policy target, the
federal-funds rate. Raising the rate paid on reserve balances also
discourages
excessive growth in money or credit, because banks will not want to
lend out
their reserves at rates below what they can earn at the Fed. Thus
market forces
are really dictated by the Fed.
Considerable international experience suggests
that paying
interest on reserves effectively manages short-term market rates. For
example,
the European Central Bank allows banks to place excess reserves in an
interest-paying deposit facility. Even as that central bank’s
liquidity-operations substantially increased its balance sheet, the
overnight
interbank rate remained at or above its deposit rate. In addition, the
Bank of
Japan and the Bank of Canada have also used their ability to pay
interest on
reserves to maintain a floor under short-term market rates. But these
countries
do not pretend they operate on a free market economy but a mixed market
economy.
Despite this logic and experience, the
federal-funds rate
has dipped somewhat below the rate paid by the Fed, especially in
October and
November 2008, when the Fed first began paying interest on reserves.
This
pattern partly reflected temporary factors, such as banks’ inexperience
with
the new system. But it may also be interpreted as a measure on how weak
the
economy actually was.
However, Bernanke observed that this pattern
appears also to
have resulted from the fact that some large lenders in the
federal-funds
market, notably government-sponsored enterprises such as Fannie Mae and
Freddie
Mac, are ineligible to receive interest on balances held at the Fed,
and thus
they have an incentive to lend in that market at rates below what the
Fed pays
banks in order to compete for scarce funds.
Under more normal financial conditions, the
willingness of
banks to engage in the simple arbitrage noted above will tend to limit
the gap
between the federal-funds rate and the rate the Fed pays on reserves.
Bernanke
argues that if that gap persists, the problem can be addressed by
supplementing
payment of interest on reserves with steps to reduce reserves and drain
excess
liquidity from markets—the second means of tightening monetary policy.
Four Options to Tightening Monetary Policy
According to Bernanke, the Fed has four options
for tightening
monetary policy: First, the Federal Reserve could drain bank reserves
and
reduce the excess liquidity at other institutions by arranging
large-scale
reverse repurchase agreements with financial market participants,
including
banks, government-sponsored enterprises and other institutions. Reverse
repurchase agreements involve the sale by the Fed of securities from
its
portfolio with an agreement to buy the securities back at a slightly
higher
price at a later date.
Repos are useful to central banks both as a
monetary policy
instrument and as a source of information on market expectations. Repos
are
attractive as a monetary policy instrument because they carry a low
credit risk
while serving as a flexible instrument for liquidity management. In
addition,
they can serve as an effective mechanism for signaling the stance of
monetary
policy.
Repo markets can also provide central banks with
information
on very short-term interest rate expectations that is relatively
accurate since
the credit risk premium in repo rates is typically small. In this
respect, they
complement information on expectations over a longer horizon derived
from
securities with longer maturities.
The secondary credit market is where Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac,
so-called GSEs
(government sponsored enterprises, or simply agencies) which were
founded with
government help during the New Deal in the 1930s to make home ownership
easier
by purchasing loans that commercial lenders make, then either hold them
in
their portfolios or bundle them with other loans into mortgage-backed
securities for sale in the credit market. Mortgage-backed securities
are sold
to mutual funds, pension funds, Wall Street firms and other financial
investors
who trade them the same way they trade Treasury securities and other
bonds. Many participants in this market source their funds in the
repo
market.
In this mortgage market, investors, rather than banks, set mortgage
rates by
setting the repo rate. Whenever the economy is expanding faster than
the money
supply growth, investors demand higher yields from mortgage lenders.
However,
the Fed is a key participant in the repo market as it has unlimited
funds with
which to buy repo or reverse repo agreements to set the repo rate.
Investors
will be reluctant to buy low-yield bonds if the Fed is expected to
raise
short-term rates higher. Conversely, prices of high-yield bonds will
rise
(therefore lowering yields) if the Fed is expected to lower short-term
rates.
In a rising-rate environment, usually when the
economy is
viewed by the Fed as overheating, securitized loans can only be sold in
the
credit market if yields also rise. The reverse happens when the economy
slows.
But since the Fed can only affect the repo rate directly, the long-term
rate
does not always follow the short-term rate because of a range of
factors, such
as a time-lag, market expectation of future Fed monetary policy and
other macro
events. This divergence from historical correlation creates profit
opportunities for hedge funds, or dangers of loss if the hedge funds
bet wrong.
When hedge funds as a group command enormous financial position, it is
possible
that the Fed will view them also as being “too big to fail” and adopt
policy
stance that will reduce their chances of loss, but stance that may not
be good
for the economy long term.
The “term structure” of interest rates defines the relationship between
short-term and long-term interest rates. Historical data suggest
that a
100-basis-point increase in Fed funds rate has been associated with
32-basis-point change in the 10-year bond rate in the same direction.
Many convergence
trading models based on this ratio are used by hedge funds. The failure
of
long-term rates to increase as short-term rates rose beginning late
winter 2003
can be explained by the expectation theory of the term structure which
links
market expectation of the future path of short-term rates to changes in
long-term rates, as St Louis Fed President William Poole said in a
speech to
the Money Marketeers in New York on June 14, 2005. The market
simply did
not expect the Fed to keep short-term rate high for extended periods
under then
current conditions. The upward trend of short-term rates was
expected by
the market to moderate or reverse direction as soon as the economy
slowed. (Please
see my September 29, 2005
AToL article: The
Repo Time
Bomb)
The second of the four options to tighten
monetary policy is
for the Treasury to sell bills and deposit the proceeds with the
Federal
Reserve. When purchasers pay for the securities, the Treasury’s account
at the
Federal Reserve rises and reserve balances decline. The Treasury has
been
conducting such operations since the fall of 2008 under its
Supplementary
Financing Program. Although the Treasury’s operations are helpful, to
protect
the independence of monetary policy, the Fed must take care to ensure
that it can
achieve its policy objectives without reliance on the Treasury.
The third option is to use the authority
Congress gave the
Fed to pay interest on banks’ balances at the Fed. The Fed can offer
term
deposits to banks—analogous to the certificates of deposit that banks
offer
their customers. Bank funds held in term deposits at the Fed would not
be
available for the federal funds market.
The fourth option, if necessary, is for the Fed
to reduce
reserves by selling a portion of its holdings of long-term securities
into the
open market.
Each of these policies would help to raise
short-term
interest rates and limit the growth of broad measures of money and
credit,
thereby tightening monetary policy.
Economic Conditions Not Likely To Require
Monetary
Tightening
Overall, the Federal Reserve has many effective
tools to
tighten monetary policy when the economic outlook requires it to do so.
However,
Bernanke thinks economic conditions are not likely to warrant tighter
monetary
policy for an extended period. The Bernanke Fed will calibrate the
timing and
pace of any future tightening, together with the mix of tools to best
foster its
dual objectives of maximum employment and price stability.
The Exit Dilemma
Yet since the Fed’s exit strategy is predicated
on an
eventual economic recovery, the exit strategy itself by definition
cannot
possibly be a component that brings about early recovery. Bernanke has
not told
the world what the Fed’s game plan for recovery is, only the Fed’s
ability to
combat inflation when recovery comes.
An economy that has collapsed under the burden
of excessive
debt cannot recover until such debt has been extinguished. And debt can
only be
extinguished by wealth creation, not by creating more debt with easy
credit.
And wealth can only be created by employment and not by financial
manipulation.
Yet the Fed’s response to financial crisis thus far has been to delay
the
extinguishment of debts in the financial system to save it from
collapsing.
Recovery is not automatic and must be brought about by market
correction or countervailing
policies to bring about full employment. A depression begins when the
business
cycle fails to cycle for long periods, keeping unemployment permanent.
Principles for a New Resolution Regime
In his April
3, 2009
speech, Bernanke said the Fed is also committed to working with the
Administration and the Congress to develop a new resolution regime that
would
allow the US
government to effectively address, at an early stage, the potential
failure of
systemically critical nonbank financial institutions. Bernanke concedes
that
the lack of such a regime greatly hampered the Fed’s flexibility in
dealing
with the failure or near-failure of such institutions as Bear Stearns,
Lehman
Brothers, and American International Group (AIG).
The principles Bernanke outlined were recently
formalized in
a joint Federal Reserve-Treasury statement: (1) the
Fed will
cooperate closely with the Treasury and other agencies in addressing
the
financial crisis; (2) the Fed in its lending activities should avoid
taking
credit risk or allocating credit to narrowly defined sectors or classes
of
borrowers; (3) the Fed’s independent ability to manage monetary policy
must not
be constrained by its programs to ease credit conditions; and (4) there
is a
pressing need for a new resolution regime for nonbanks that, among
other
things, will better define the Fed’s role in preventing the disorderly
failure
of systemically critical financial institutions.
Yet, by treating risk-prone investment banks
with the same
Fed protection that supposedly risk-averse commercial banks enjoy, the
Fed is
essentially financing risk taking with tax payer money and allowing the
high
returns from high risk to bypass taxpayers. If a private institution
rescues a
distressed investment bank from imminent collapse, it will end up
owning the
entity and all its future profits. But all taxpayers got was a
repayment of the
Fed loans with low interest and warrants to buy stocks in the banks at
a set
price over ten years, while the investment bankers walked off with huge
bonuses
even when their banks were losing money. While the government is
reported to
have made a $4 billion profit from its rescue investments of $700
billion,
analysts say that private investors would have realized a $12 billion
return by
paying market price rather than the bloated price that the government
paid.
Fed’s Balance
Sheet as a Tool of Monetary Policy
Bernanke observed that the severe disruption of
credit
markets that began in the summer of 2007 and the associated tightening
in
credit conditions and declines in asset prices have weighed heavily on
economic
activity in the US
and abroad. The Fed has responded belatedly by reluctantly easing
short-term
interest rates, beginning only in September 2007, three months after
the credit
crunch began. A whole year later, only in October 2008, as the
financial crisis
intensified, did the Federal Reserve participate in an unprecedented
coordinated
rate cut with other major central banks.
At the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)
December 2008
meeting, nine months after the March 14, 2008 JP Morgan Chase takeover
of Bear
Stearns with loans from the New York Fed then under now Treasury
Secretary Tim
Geithner to prevent a potential market crash that would result from
Bear
Stearns becoming insolvent; and three months after Lehman Brothers file
bankruptcy, with Merrill Lynch being forced to sell itself to Bank of
America for
$50 billion, and with insurance giant American International Group (AIG) suffering losses stemming from the credit
crisis, seeking a $40 billion lifeline from the Fed, without which the
company
might have only days to survive, the FOMC reduced its target for the
federal
funds rate close to its lower bound, setting a target range between 0
and ¼%.
And with deflation expected for some time, the Committee indicated that
short-term interest rates were likely to remain low for an extended
period.
Danger of Keeping Low Interest Rates Too Long
Since then some economists have voiced concern
that the Fed is
in danger of putting itself in a position of holding interest rate too
low for
too long for the long-term health of the economy and the future
strength of the
dollar. The short-term benefits of low interest rate may be neutralized
by the
long-term cost of high inflation exacerbated by a falling dollar.
Still, Bernanke
asserts that with conventional monetary policy of interest rate
targeting having
reached its limit, any further policy stimulus requires a different set
of
tools.
New Tools
Bernanke says that the Fed has been a global
leader in
developing such tools. In particular, to further improve the
functioning of
credit markets and provide additional support to the economy, the Fed
has
established and expanded a number of liquidity programs and recently
initiated
a large-scale program of asset purchases. These actions have had
significant
effects on both the size and composition of the Federal Reserve’s
balance
sheet. Notably, the balance sheet has more than doubled, from roughly
$870
billion before the crisis to roughly $2.11 trillion by the week ending November 5, 2008.
A good source of information on Fed balance
sheet is a new
section of the Board’s website, entitled Credit and Liquidity Programs
and the
Balance Sheet. This section brings together much diverse
information about the Fed's balance sheet, including some only recently
made
available, as well as detailed explanations and analyses.
For decades, the Fed’s assets consisted almost
exclusively
of Treasury securities. Since late 2007, however, Fed holdings of
Treasury
securities have declined, as its holdings of other financial assets
have
expanded dramatically. Fed assets are grouped into three broad
categories: (1) short-term
credit extended to support the liquidity of financial firms such as
depository
institutions, broker-dealers, and money market mutual funds; (2) assets
related
to programs focused on broader credit conditions; and (3) holdings of
high-quality securities, notably Treasury securities, agency debt, and
agency-backed mortgage-backed securities (MBS). The Federal
Reserve also has provided support directly to specific institutions in
cases
when a disorderly failure would have threatened the financial system.
This is
the too-big-to-fail syndrome.
Liquidity
Programs
for Financial Firms
The first of these categories of
assets--short-term
liquidity provided to sound financial institutions: commercial banks
and
primary dealers, as well as currency swaps with other central banks to
support
interconnected global dollar funding markets, for up to 90 days -totals
almost
$860 billion by April 2009, representing nearly 45% of the assets on
Fed
balance sheet.
Bernanke points out that from its beginning, the
Federal Reserve,
through its discount window, has provided credit to depository
institutions to
meet unexpected liquidity needs, usually in the form of overnight
loans. The
provision of short-term liquidity is, of course, a long-standing
function of
central banks. In August 2007, conditions in short-term bank funding
markets
deteriorated abruptly, and bank funding needs intensified sharply. In
response
to these developments, the Federal Reserve reduced the spread of the
primary
credit rate--the rate at which most institutions borrow at the discount
window--relative to the target federal funds rate, and also made it
easier for
banks to borrow at term.
However, as in some past episodes of financial
distress,
banks were reluctant to rely on discount window credit to address their
funding
needs. The banks’ concern was that their recourse to the discount
window, if it
became known, might lead market participants to infer weakness--the
so-called
stigma problem. The perceived stigma of borrowing at the discount
window threatened
to prevent the Federal Reserve from getting much-needed liquidity into
the
system.
To address this issue, in late 2007, the Federal
Reserve
established the Term Auction Facility (TAF), which provides fixed
quantities of
term credit to depository institutions through an auction mechanism.
The
introduction of this facility seems largely to have solved the stigma
problem,
partly because the sizable number of borrowers provides anonymity, and
possibly
also because the three-day period between the auction and auction
settlement
suggests that the facility’s users are not relying on it for acute
funding
needs on a particular day.
As of April
1, 2009,
the Fed had roughly $525 billion of discount window credit outstanding,
of
which about $470 billion had been distributed through auctions and the
remainder through conventional discount window loans.
What the Fed did in reality was that against a
general
commitment to transparency and openness, it instituted a program that
hides
from the market the real liquidity condition of major banks. It turned
out that
quite a few of the major banks that escaped the stigma of weakness
would have in
fact faced insolvency without Fed help. Market participants were
deprived of
this important decision relating to the distressed banks.
September 7, 2009
Next: Facing
a Lost Decade Ahead
|