2009
– The Year Monetarism
Enters Bankruptcy
By
Henry C.K. Liu
This article appeared in AToL
on January 6, 2009
The invasive dominance of monetarism in macroeconomics has
been total ever since central bankers, led by Alan Greenspan, who from
1987 to
2006 was Chairman of the Board of Governors of the US Federal Reserve,
the
head of
the global central banking snake by virtue of dollar hegemony, embraced
the
counterfactual conclusion of Milton Friedman that monetarist measures
by the
central bank can perpetuate the boom phase the business cycle
indefinitely, banishing
the bust phase from finance capitalism altogether.
Going beyond
Friedman,
Greenspan asserted that a good central bank could perform monetary
miracle by
simply adding liquidity to maintain a booming financial market by
easing quantitatively at the
slightest hint of market correction, ignoring the fundamental law of
finance
that if liquidity is exploited to manipulate excess debt as phantom
equity on
a global scale, liquidity can act as a flammable agent to turn a simple
localized
credit crunch into a systemic fire storm.
Ben Bernanke, Greenspan’s successor at the Fed since February
1, 2006, also believes that a “good” central banker can make all the
difference
in banishing depressions forever, arguing on record in 2000 that, as
Friedman
claimed, the 1929 stock market crash could have been avoided if the Fed
had not
dropped the monetary ball. That belief had been a doctrinal
prerequisite for any
candidate up for consideration for the post of top central banker by
President George
W. Bush. Yet all the Greenspan era proved was that mainstream monetary
economists have been reading the same books and buying the same
counterfactual
conclusion. Friedman’s “Only money matters” turned out to be a very
dangerous
slogan.
Both Greenspan and Bernanke had been seduced by the convenience
of easy money and fell into an addiction to it by forgetting that, even
according
to Friedman, the role of central banking is to maintain the value of
money to
insure steady, sustainable economic growth, to moderate cycles of boom
and bust
by avoiding destructively big swings in money supply.
Friedman had called
for a
steady increase of the money supply at an annual rate of 3% to achieve
a
non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU) as a solution
to
stagflation when inflation itself causes high unemployment. Stagflation
is a de
facto invalidation of the Phillips Curve which shows a negative
correlation
between the rate of unemployment and the rate of inflation.
There is of
course
irrefutable logic within the workings of a capitalistic labor market in
support
of the concept of structural unemployment. Yet the conceptual flaw in
NAIRU is
its acceptance of a natural rate of unemployment as a justification to
abandon
the socioeconomic goal of full employment. When unemployment of 6% of
willing
workers
is accepted as structural in an economic system, the fault is with the
system,
just as if a hospital accepts an annual mortality rate of 6% of its
curable
patients as structural, the hospital’s operation needs to be
reexamined. The
fundamental flaw in market capitalism is its inherent failure to
deliver full
employment as a social goal.
Monetary easing should only be tolerated in times of real
systemic financial distress in the economy. It should never be
administered as
a convenient anesthetic to forestall market corrections. Instead,
Greenspan in
his 18 years at the Fed had repeatedly treated every cyclical market
downturn
as a potential systemic crisis that justified massive liquidity
injection by
the central bank, only to create larger and larger serial price bubbles
as new phantom
cycles of growth to defy financial gravity.
Yet while the laws of finance can sometimes be violated with
delayed penalty, they cannot be permanently overturned. The fact
remains that central
banks cannot repeatedly use easy money to fund serial economic bubbles
without
cumulative consequence. Undetectable debt can be disguised by
structured
finance as phantom equity, but it remains as liabilities at the end of
the day.
Risk can be spread globally system-wide but it cannot be eliminated.
The result
will be a global financial meltdown when this massive Ponzi scheme on
the part
of central banks is finally exposed.
Greenspan, by his cavalier application of massive liquidity
to sustain phantom serial monetary booms, has driven the narrow
validity of monetarism
into policy bankruptcy. Bernanke, by his blind faith in the power of
misguided monetarist
measures to deal with a global credit crisis created by decades of
runaway
monetary indulgence, has unwittingly neutralized even the antibiotic
power of
Keynesian fiscal countermeasures against demand deficiency in a
monetary bust
from excessive debt. Deficit financing in a recession does not work
without a
reservoir of fiscal surplus from a previous boom.
The Fed under Greenspan and Bernanke had violated the basic
rules of both monetarism (money supply management) and Keynesianism
(demand
management). Fed monetary policy created false prosperity with excess
money
supply to fund debt manipulation and simultaneously to support income
disparity
as a source for capital formation to exacerbate overcapacity amid
demand
weakness.
The Greenspan Fed repeatedly provided easy money in massive
scale to fund serial asset price bubbles that were passed off as
economic
growth. And deregulated finance globalization endorsed enthusiastically
by
Greenspan led to wide income disparity in the entire global economy.
Thus
income in every economy eventually failed to support rising asset
prices pushed
up by debt to unsustainable levels. This forced the excess phantom
capital in
the global economy to seek growth from manipulation of debt
collateralized by a
price bubble that was destined to collapse from inadequate cash flow.
Structured finance allows general risk in all debts to be unbundled
into tranches in a hierarchy of credit rating, allowing even the most
conservative to participate in the debt bubble by holding the supposing
safe
low-risk tranches. But the safety of these low-risk tranches is merely
derived
from an expected low default rate of the riskier tranches. As default
rate of
the high-risk tranches rises, the safety of the supposedly low-risk
tranches vanishes.
With runaway “supply-side” voodoo economics keeping wage income in
check during
the boom phase in corporate profits, the resultant overcapacity from
demand lag
resulting from low wages shuts off investment opportunities for
productive
expansion and forces the excess money supply into speculative
manipulation of
debt, giving birth to restructured finance and sophisticated, circular
hedging
of risk.
A decade of excess money had produced a credit overcapacity
which was solved by a systemic under-pricing of risk and a lowering of
credit standards
for so-called sub-prime borrowers. While sub-prime mortgage was at
first mostly
a housing sector problem, the derivative effects of sub-prime failure
quickly infested
the entire global financial system. These interconnected factors that
fueled
the spectacular process of serial bubble formation at unprecedented
rate and on
unprecedented scale to support the false claim of neoliberal finance
capitalism
as the most effective and efficient economic system in history turned
out to be
the same factors that brought the entire global capitalist financial
system built
on debt crashing down in July 2007.
Since Greenspan left the Fed in 2006, a year before the global
crash, when mainstream analysts were still praising him as a god-sent
savior of
debt-propelled finance capitalism, it was left to Bernanke to continue
the
Greenspan magic to keep the good times rolling perpetually. Not
unexpectedly, when
the liquidity-fed debt tsunami hit the financial sector in July 2007,
Bernanke
confidently assumed that the Greenspan Put would again save the
financial
system from another collapse of the latest of Greenspan’s serial
bubbles.
When pressed by Congresswoman Rosa DeLauro (D-Conn.) during
a hearing whether the economy was in a recession, Bernanke dismissed
the
question with the professorial hubris reserved for a college freshman
that “recession”
is only a technical description of economic conditions. “Whether it’s
called a
recession or not is of no consequence,” declared the former Princeton
professor. Still, as there was even at the time general consensus that
market
confidence had emerged as a major issue, whether a slowdown is
classified
officially as a recession has serious consequences in market attitude.
Bernanke’s
arrogant brush-off to a perfectly valid commonsense question from a
concerned legislator
presumed to be unwashed in economics theory showed how disconnected the
elitist
high priest central banker was to earthy reality.
Bernanke was complacently confident he could stop the wave
of massive financial destruction caused by decades of abuse of
liquidity excess
by again adding more liquidity through massive creation of new money.
The Fed
under Bernanke, instead of saving the economy from the cancer of debt,
actually
continues to be part of the problem by feeding the spreading debt
cancer.
(Please see
my October 23, 2008
AToL
article: US
Government Throws Oil on Fire)
Eight years earlier, Bernanke had declared his faith in aggressive
monetarism when he wrote in the September/October 2000 Issue of Foreign Policy an article entitled: A Crash Course for Central
Bankers:
“A collapse in US
stock prices certainly would cause a lot of white knuckles on Wall
Street. But
what effect would it have on the broader US
economy? If Wall Street crashes, does Main
Street
follow? Not necessarily. Consider three famous episodes: the U.S.
stock market crash of 1929, Japan’s
crash of 1990-1991, and the US
crash of 1987.
The 1929 U.S.
crash and the sharp decline in Japanese stock prices were both followed
by
decade-long economic slumps in each country. (The Japanese depression,
despite
much whistling in the dark by the country’s policymakers, still
lingers.) By
contrast, the macroeconomic fallout from the 1987 tumble on Wall Street
was
minimal. Why the difference?
A closer look
reveals
that the
economic repercussions of a stock market crash depend less on the
severity of
the crash itself than on the response of economic policymakers,
particularly
central bankers. After the 1929 crash, the Federal Reserve mistakenly
focused
its policies on preserving the gold value of the dollar rather than on
stabilizing the domestic economy. By raising interest rates to protect
the
dollar, policymakers contributed to soaring unemployment and severe
price
deflation. The US central bank only compounded its mistake by failing
to
counter the collapse of the country’s banking system in the early
1930s; bank
failures both intensified the monetary squeeze (since bank deposits
were
liquidated) and sparked a credit crunch that hurt consumers and small
firms in
particular. Without these policy blunders by the Federal Reserve, there
is
little reason to believe that the 1929 crash would have been followed
by more
than a moderate dip in US
economic activity.
The downturn
following the
collapse of Japan’s
so-called bubble economy of the 1980s was not as severe as the Great
Depression. However, in some crucial aspects, Japan
in the 1990s was a slow-motion replay of the U.S.
experience 60 years earlier. After effectively precipitating the crash
in stock
and real estate prices through sharp increases in interest rates (in
much the
same way that the Fed triggered the crash of 1929), the Bank of Japan
seemed in
no hurry to ease monetary policy and did not cut rates significantly
until
1994. As a result, prices in Japan
have fallen about 1% annually since 1992.
And much like US
officials during
the 1930s, Japanese policymakers were unconscionably slow in tackling
the
severe banking crisis that impaired the economy’s ability to function
normally.
Central bankers
got
it right in
the United States
in 1987 when they avoided deflationary pressures as well as serious
trouble in
the banking system. In the days immediately following the October 19th
crash,
Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan—in office a mere two
months—focused his
efforts on maintaining financial stability. For instance, he persuaded
banks to
extend credit to struggling brokerage houses, thus ensuring that the
stock
exchanges and futures markets would continue operating normally. (US
banks, which unlike their Japanese counterparts do not own stock, were
never in
any serious danger from the crash.) Subsequently, the Fed’s attention
shifted
from financial to macroeconomic stability, with the central bank
cutting
interest rates to offset any deflationary effects of declining stock
prices.
Reassured by policymakers’ determination to protect the economy, the
markets
calmed and economic growth resumed with barely a blip.
There’s no
denying
that a collapse
in stock prices today would pose serious macroeconomic challenges for
the United States.
Consumer spending would slow, and
the US
economy would
become
less of a magnet for foreign investors. Economic growth,
which in any case has recently been at unsustainable levels, would
decline
somewhat. History proves, however, that a smart central bank can
protect the
economy and the financial sector from the nastier side effects of a
stock
market collapse.”
In his 2000 article of faith, Bernanke was openly endorsing
the “Greenspan Put”, the
monetary stance from late 1980s on during which whenever the economy
slowed, the
Fed would come to its rescue by radically lowering the Fed funds rate
target
even to the point of negative real yields as measured against
inflation, and
kept it there until a new boom bubble was solidly formed. The Greenspan
Put repeatedly
pumped liquidity into the market to avert the price correction
consequences of
speculative excesses that caused the 1987 crash, then the geo-economic
consequences of the First Gulf War in 1991, then the contagion effects
from the
Mexican Peso Crisis of 1994, then the Asian Financial Crisis of 1997
and the Russian
default that caused the collapse of LTCM in 1998, then the phantom Y2K
digital threat,
then the bursting of the Internet dot.com bubble in 2000 and then the
market
panic from the 2001- 9/11 terrorist attacks to launch the sub-prime
housing
bubble that burst in July 2007.
Accordingly, Bernanke was complacently confident that another
application of the Greenspan Put can again handle the burst of the
housing
bubble in July 2007. He appeared to have no inkling that the economy
had been drawn closer each time since 1978
into a
perfect storm of structured finance run amok.
On May 17, 2007,
three months before the credit crisis broke out, Bernanke said in a
speech on The
Subprime Mortgage Market at
the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago’s 43rd Annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition:
“…
given
the fundamental factors in place that should support the
demand for housing, we believe the effect of the troubles in the
subprime
sector on the broader housing market will likely be limited, and we do
not
expect significant spillovers from the subprime market to the rest of
the
economy or to the financial system. The vast majority of
mortgages,
including even subprime mortgages, continue to perform well. Past
gains
in house prices have left most homeowners with significant amounts of
home
equity, and growth in jobs and incomes should help keep the financial
obligations of most households manageable.”
The top US
central banker did not see what Greenspan
later called “the crisis of a century” coming at him at full speed to
hit him
in the face in four weeks. Even on August 31, 2007, six weeks after the
credit
crisis broke out in mid July, Bernake still spoke with surprising calm
confidence in a speech on Housing,
Housing Finance, and Monetary Policy, delivered at the Federal
Reserve Bank
of Kansas City’s Annual Economic Symposium at Jackson Hole, Wyoming:
“Importantly,
the easing of some traditional institutional and regulatory
frictions seems to have reduced the sensitivity of residential
construction to
monetary policy, so that housing is no longer so central to monetary
transmission
as it was. In particular, in the absence of Reg Q ceilings
on deposit rates and with a much-reduced role for deposits as a source
of
housing finance, the availability of mortgage credit today is generally
less
dependent on conditions in short-term money markets, where the central
bank
operates most directly.
Most
estimates suggest that, because of the reduced sensitivity of
housing to short-term interest rates, the response of the economy to a
given
change in the federal funds rate is modestly smaller and more balanced
across
sectors than in the past. These results are embodied in the
Federal Reserve’s large econometric model of the economy, which implies
that
only about 14% of the overall response of output to monetary policy is
now
attributable to movements in residential investment, in contrast to the
model’s
estimate of 25% or so under what I have called the New Deal system.
The
econometric findings seem consistent with the reduced synchronization
of the housing cycle and the business cycle during the present
decade. In
all but one recession during the period from 1960 to 1999, declines in
residential investment accounted for at least 40% of the decline in
overall
real GDP, and the sole exception--the 1970 recession--was preceded by a
substantial
decline in housing activity before the official start of the downturn.
In
contrast, residential investment boosted overall real GDP
growth during the 2001 recession. More recently, the sharp
slowdown in
housing has been accompanied, at least thus far, by relatively good
performance
in other sectors. That said, the current episode demonstrates
that
pronounced housing cycles are not a thing of the past.
My
discussion so far has focused primarily on the role of variations in
housing finance and residential construction in monetary
transmission.
But, of course, housing may have indirect effects on economic activity,
most
notably by influencing consumer spending. With regard to
household
consumption, perhaps the most significant effect of recent developments
in
mortgage finance is that home equity, which was once a highly illiquid
asset,
has become instead quite liquid, the result of the development of home
equity
lines of credit and the relatively low cost of cash-out
refinancing.
Economic
theory suggests that the greater liquidity of home equity should
allow households to better smooth consumption over time. This
smoothing
in turn should reduce the dependence of their spending on current
income,
which, by limiting the power of conventional multiplier effects, should
tend to
increase macroeconomic stability and reduce the effects of a given
change in
the short-term interest rate. These inferences are supported by
some
empirical evidence.”
Bernanke was still twiddling his theoretical
thumb in the comfort
of his institutional bunker while the whole financial world was falling
under a
credit fire storm. With the awesome data collection capability at his
disposal,
the Fed Chairman’s radar apparently totally missed the possibility of
systemic
collapse of the non-bank credit market on structured finance from
chain-reaction
effects of rising subprime mortgage default. As the housing bubble
burst, home
equity loans collateralized by inflated home prices were putting most
home
mortgages under water and an increasingly large number of home equity
borrowers
in default. The sudden reversal of the wealth effect was about to
destroy the
global economy, albeit with a time lag, as Bernanke gave his reassuring
speech based
on faulty economic theory.
Before the credit crisis developed in July 2007, institutional
clients of global money center banks had a range of non-bank options to
access
funds. Such options included the $1.2 trillion short-term commercial
paper
market collateralized by solid asset price and cash flow prospects.
Interest
rates for commercial paper were normally lower than bank credit rates.
Borrowers used banks credit mostly as a temporary backup in the
unlikely event
that a rollover of maturing commercial paper debt faced unforeseen
temporary difficulties.
The credit market went into shock when the commercial paper
market abruptly and effectively seized and stayed frozen to all
borrowers in mid
July. Banks suddenly had to rely solely on inter-bank funding to
provide promised
credit to clients at a time when cash supply was expected to be
squeezed by the
usual year-end liquidity shortage. Banks all over the world whose costs
of
borrowing are based on the London Interbank Offer Rate (LIBOR) market
found
LIBOR jumping to 202 basis points (2.02 percentage points) above US
Treasuries
in the third quarter of 2007.
Only after the
commercial paper seizure hit the LIBOR did the Federal Reserve
belatedly
realize that the credit market was not clearing efficiently. Half of
the world’s
outstanding finance of $150 trillion which includes financing for
derivative
trades is routinely tied to LIBOR rates. The risk of global recession
from widespread
toxic infection of the entire credit market caused by rising defaults
of US subprime loans was creating panic in the market.
The Fed and the Treasury, official guardians of a stable financial
market, were
the last parties to know that a systemic crisis was about to implode
and had
only hours to act from their offices in New York when government
officials were
told by major US financial institutions management that they would be
unable to
meet their global obligations when markets opened in Asia.
Again, an injection of liquidity to forestall an imminent
financial crisis was administered by the Fed, notwithstanding that the
crisis
was in essence an insolvency problem of too much debt with insufficient
revenue.
Illiquidity was merely the outcome, not the cause. Corporate profit, as
measured by the Commerce Department, fell $19.3 billion in the third
quarter
2007, as domestic earnings dropped to $41.2 billion. Yet the drag from
sagging
US sales and huge financial write-downs from credit losses were offset
by still
robust earnings abroad, amplified by a weakening US dollar. Operating
profits
for S&P 500 companies fell 2.5% in the third quarter, the first
drop in
more than five bubble years. Much of the damage was initially
concentrated in
the financial sector, where operating earnings fell 25%, as banks and
brokerage
houses suffered losses from subprime mortgages holdings and related
investments.
The credit crisis that imploded in July 2007 was not a Black
Swan event that could not be predicted. It actually began in late 2006
when inevitable
residential subprime defaults that had been warned by a few lonely
voices on
the Internet from a few sober analysts years earlier were finally being
reported
in the general print media and popular TV programs on finance. The
general
consensus continued to claim the economy to be fundamentally sound.
Pundits at
the Wall Street Journal, CNBC and Bloomberg told the clueless public to
take
advantage of buying opportunities as the market headed south.
By the end of the first quarter of 2007, speculative institutional
buyers of investment properties at overblown prices began having
problem
accessing easy credit to close their overpriced deals. Nervous
investors in high-yield
fixed income debt began redirecting their funds towards risk-free
Treasury
notes and bills, driving prices up and interest rates down. Balance
sheet loans
(cash generated from operations) from banks and insurance companies
were still
available but at far more conservative credit terms and higher rates.
Still,
mainstream analysts were insisting the sky was not falling.
The pace of securitization, including commercial
mortgage-backed securities (CMBS) issuances, slowed moderately during
2006 and
2007 from the fast pace set between 2002 and 2005, especially for
high-leverage
private sector issuers. The trend was hailed as a successful soft
landing by
mainstream pundits while in reality any slight loss of upward price
momentum is
lethal for a debt bubble.
The stock and bond markets reacted to the rising rate of
delinquencies among subprime residential borrowers as the housing
bubble
deflated. Investors lost confidence in even the top-rated tranches of
the
securitized subprime loans and all asset-backed securities became
illiquid.
Hedge funds managed by Lehman, Bear Stearns, Merrill Lynch, Goldman
Sachs and
others that had purchased subprime asset-backed securities (ABS)
reported huge losses
as their portfolios were marked to market. Globally, off shore hedge
funds and major
banks in Germany
and France
that
invested in subprime ABS also reported significant losses. Investors
seeking to
increase returns had leveraged their ABS holdings which, when applied
to a
market decline, exponentially drove prices even lower.
Large US
investment banks had pooled subprime
residential asset-back securities (ABS) totaling $383 billion and sold
the
paper to investors worldwide in 2006. By September 2007, 21% or about
$80
billion of the mortgage securities were in default, plus another $20
billion sold
by smaller firms. There were $18 trillion of all forms of outstanding
ABS, and
market analysts estimated at the time that marked-to-market losses
would be in
the range of $400 to $600 billion. Yet media reports cited only about
$150
billion of acknowledged losses as of the end of 2007. The trough, of
which no
one had any reliable estimate, remained in the unknown future despite
the
Federal Reserve’s frantic rate reductions, which by December 2008 has
reached
near zero.
The impact of the
subprime defaults had been magnified as firms purchased for a fee
slices of
these original-rated pools and repackaged the assets a second time,
rated them
a second time, and later sold them as lower-tiered units at higher
yields to investor
with bigger risk appetite. The impact has been global as most
international
money center banks have offices in all major financial centers around
the
world. (Please see my November 27-29, 2007 AToL
three-part series on Pathology
of
Debt)
Going forward, the
credit crisis will bring down the retail and office real estate sectors
in all
economies as a global re-pricing of risk alters the viability of
maturing medium-term
loans coming due in coming years. From early mid-2004 to mid-2007 real
estate
developers, lenders and property owners used a menu of complex
financial instruments
to gain access to low-cost funds and shift risk off their balance
sheets to the
investing public. Easy access to credit had driven capitalization rates
way down
and debt-financed deal volumes up to new record levels every year since
2002. Institutional-grade
assets had been priced using exponents in future cash flow assumptions
in an
upward-bending positive parabolic curve. It is inescapable that when
global
credit markets turn sour, the effect is an equally downward-bending
negative
parabolic curve.
To be fair, Bernanke was in good company among establishment
experts of equally unjustified complacency. Brookings Policy Brief
Series #164 dated October 2007, three months
after the credit
crisis imploded, used as headline: Credit
Crisis: The Sky is not Falling. The brief by Anthony Downs, who
describes
himself on his website as the “World’s
Leading Authority” on real estate and urban affairs, asserts
that
“… the facts
hardly
indicate a
credit crisis. As of mid-2007, data show that prices of existing homes
are not
collapsing. Despite large declines in new home production and existing
home
sales, home prices are only slightly falling overall but are still
rising in
many markets. Default rates are rising on subprime mortgages, but these
mortgages—which offer loans to borrowers with poor credit at higher
interest
rates—form a relatively small part of all mortgage originations. About
87
percent of residential mortgages are not subprime loans, according to
the
Mortgage Bankers Association’s delinquency studies. Subprime
delinquency rates
will most likely rise more in 2008 as mortgages are reset to higher
levels as
interest-only periods end or adjustable rates are driven upward. Unless
the U.S.
economy dips dramatically, however, the vast majority of subprime
mortgages
will be paid. And, because there is no basic shortage of money,
investors still
have a tremendous amount of financial capital they must put to work
somewhere.”
However, while this complacent view was widely held in the financial
establishment, not everybody was drinking the Cool-Aid. Instead of
“tremendous amount of financial capital”, the entire financial sector
was
seriously undercapitalized as distressed debts added up losses.
Warnings had
been publicly aired months before the credit crisis imploded in July
2007 by a
few lonely voices of more sober analysts that the subprime mortgage
bubble would
burst and its effect would spread globally, granted that such warnings
had been
summarily dismissed by the establishment media. (See my March 17, 2007
AToL
article:
Why
the Sub-prime Mortgage Bust Will Spread)
By December 2008, eighteen months after the credit crisis
broke out in July 2007, events have conclusively proved that Bernanke’s
faith
in the magic of the Greenspan Put had been misplaced. Decades of
misapplication
of Friedmanesque monetarism had driven the doctrine into theoretical
bankruptcy.
Monetarist measures not only fails to revive an economy caught in a
global debt
tsunami, there is also clear evidence that the liquidity cure devised
by
Greenspan has eventually run out of ammunition as the serial bubbles
get bigger
each time to paper over the previous one. The Greenspan Put does not
work for a
stalled economy facing a liquidity trap of absolute preference for
cash. It only
adds more water to a raging flood of debt to threaten even the
shrinking remaining
high ground.
The flaw in his faith in self-regulating monetarism that
Greenspan openly confessed before Congress apparently did not get
through to
Bernanke who continues to apply the Greenspan Put. Bernanke’s futile
monetary
moves to save wayward financial institutions only managed to increase
the immunity
of the deeply wounded economy against any Keynesian fiscal cure by the
next
occupant of the White House and his economic team. Bernanke made the
same
mistake of obstinate denial in the early phases of the economic
meltdown from a
debt crisis even after his acceptance eight years earlier of Friedman’s
counterfactual conclusion that the Fed in 1930 failed to act in time to
effectively
respond to the oncoming disaster with bold monetary countermeasures.
Again, the
world missed another opportunity to test if preemptive Keynesian fiscal
cures
will work.
More fundamentally, rather than a timely monetary cure as
proposed by Friedman in hindsight, Hoover
should have applied Keynesian demand management through fiscal spending
to
maintain full employment immediately after the 1929 crash, if not
before. No
recovery from speculative excess can be expected without a
policy-induce rise
in employment and wage income to catch up with an asset price bubble.
It was
true in 1929; and it is true today.
Unfortunately, the rescue approach by the Bush
administration led by Treasury Secretary Henry Paulson and the Bernanke
Fed has
been focused on saving distressed financial institutions by providing
taxpayer
money to restructuring bad debts and de-leveraging overblown balance
sheets.
This approach inevitably pushes already stagnant wage income further
down with more
layoffs and ruthless renegotiation of already draconian labor contracts
to cut operating
cost. All this does is to reinforce the downward market spiral by
transferring financial
pain to innocent workers while not helping the economy with needed
revival of
consumer demand.
Trillions of good taxpayer money are being thrown after bad
debts concocted by unprincipled financiers into a crisis black hole.
This money
would have to be repaid in coming years by tax payers while
Supply-siders are
clamoring for tax cuts for corporations, on capital gain and for high
income
earners. This means the future tax bill to pay for the Greenspan put
will be
borne by low and middle income wage earners. Thus far in this financial
crisis,
the Bernanke Fed has not sowed the seeds for a quick recovery but for a
decade or
more of stagflation for the US
and the global economy.
January 1, 2009
Next: Central Banking Practices
Monetarism at the Expense of
the Economy
|