|
Too Big to Fail versus Moral Hazard
By
Henry C.K. Liu
This article appeared in AToL
on September 23, 2008
“Too big to fail” is the cancer of moral hazard in the financial
system. Moral hazard is a term used in banking circles to describe the
tendency
of bankers to make bad loans based on an expectation that the lender of
last resort,
either the Federal Reserve domestically or the IMF globally, will bail
out
troubled banks.
Barely forty-eight hours after US Treasury Secretary Henry
Paulson declared his firm commitment against the danger of moral
hazard by promising
that no more taxpayer money would be used to bail-out failing financial
firms
on Wall Street except in extreme situations, US authorities succumbed
to the too big to fail syndrome in the case of American International
Group
Inc
(AIG), a giant global insurance conglomerate founded in Shanghai in
1919.
Paulson’s moral hazard aversion had prevented Lehman Brothers Inc, the
country’s fourth largest investment bank, from getting a government
bailout. Without
needed government guarantee to limit the exposure of potential buyers,
Lehman was
forced to file bankruptcy protection at mid night on Sunday (September 14, 2008).
In March, JPMorgan Chase had been provided with a $29
billion credit line from the Fed discount window in its purchase of
Bear Stearns
arranged by the Treasury. In early September, the Treasury seized
control of
two troubled government sponsored enterprises (GSE) Fannie Mae and
Freddie Mac
with a $200 billion capital injection against a $4.5 trillion
liability, concurrent
with another government arranged “shotgun marriage” that induced Bank
of
America to acquire Merrill Lynch at a fire sale price of $50 billion.
The
Treasury has been criticized and is now sensitive to criticism of
bailing out private
Wall Street firms that should have been allowed to fail from
irresponsible market
misjudgments and Paulson is eager to show that going forward it is not
government policy to increase moral hazard.
The best minds on Wall Street had been engaged to seek a
private sector solution for AIG. Goldman Sachs was hired to assess the
potential losses on AIG’s bad assets to set a fair market value for the
firm.
JPMorgan Chase and Blackstone were advising AIG on finding buyers among
private
equity firms and/or foreign sovereign funds while Morgan Stanley was
helping
the Federal Reserve to consider rescue options. After frantic efforts
to raise
funds from private sources to restore the giant insurer’s credit rating
failed,
the Federal Reserve, reportedly overriding Secretary Paulson’s moral
hazard reluctance,
arranged a last minute deal Tuesday night (September 16, 2008) to
provide AIG
an $85 billion two-year “bridge loan” from the central bank to keep it
afloat to
give it time to dispose of billions of dollars of valuable assets in an
more
orderly manner. It was an unprecedented move for the Fed, both in kind
and
scale. Normally, insrance companies are regulated by state insurance
commissions, not the Federal Reserve.
In addition to collateral in the form of illiquid AIG assets
for the $85 billion two-year bridge loan, which carries a usurious
interest
rate of 8.5 percentage points above LIBOR (London Interbank Offer Rate
that
banks lend to one another and a widely used short term interest bench
mark –
2.75% on September 17), the Fed would receive equity warrants,
technically
known as equity participation notes, for a 79.9% stake in AIG. The
issuance of
the warrants (contract to buy the shares at a pre-agreed price) to the
Fed is
designed to prevent existing AIG shareholders from profiting from a
government rescue
of the company, which has been hobbled by massive losses from exposures
on complex
structured finance instruments backed by mortgages and other debts.
Aside from the
high interest rate, the Fed can veto any dividend payments, and AIG is
expected
to sell assets over the next two years to repay its debt. Senior AIG
management
will be replaced.
The Fed repeated a pattern established with Bear Stearns in
March and with Fannie and Freddie earlier this September of wiping out
shareholders while protecting holders of debt. By now, investors have
learned
the pattern and bet on future bailouts by selling stock and buying
bonds in distressed
firms. The result pushed down a company’s share price, which can
exacerbate its
troubles. Both Morgan Stanley and Goldman Sachs became targets of this
strategy.
By all accounts, AIG qualifies as a too-big-fail candidate. What
made Fed and Treasury officials apprehensive was not simply the
prospect of
another giant bankruptcy on Wall Street, but AIG’s role as an extensive
provider of esoteric financial insurance contracts to investors who
wanted to
hedge potential losses on complex debt securities they bought. The
problem insurance
contracts take the form of credit-default swaps (CDS) which effectively
required AIG to cover losses suffered by the buyers in the event of
counterparty default. AIG was potentially liable for billions of
dollars of
risky securities that were considered safe in normal time.
An AIG collapse would cause it to default on all of its
insurance claims. Institutional investors around the world would
instantly be forced
to reappraise the value of securities insured by AIG against
counterparty
losses. This would require them to increase their capital to maintain
their
credit ratings. Small investors, including anyone who owned money
market funds or
pension funds that hold AIG issued securities, could suffer losses. On
the day
before the AIG bailout became news after market closing, the New York
money
market firm Reserve Primary Fund with $62 billion under management
announced
that it “broke the buck”, meaning that its net asset fell below the
standard $1
per share, a development all mutual funds normally would do everything
to
avoid.
During a day of emergency meetings at the New York Fed, the
Treasury and Fed reversed initial reluctance to bail out another
financial
institution. Though unspoken, the underlying conclusion was that this
was not a
takeover, not a bail out. If anyone is being bail out, it is the
central bank
which is desperately trying to create a fire break to prevent a global
capital
market collapse that it may not have enough financial resources on its
balance
sheet to support. Treasury had to announce that it is issuing $40
billion of
45-day Treasury Bills to help buttress the Fed’s balance sheet. More
will be
issued as needed by the Fed.
There are signs that the government’s firefighting measures
are less than effective. Market sentiment suggests that more financial
firms
can be expected to fail before the crisis crests. Mark-to-market
requirements
for valuing structured finance instruments and portfolios that are
structured
to appear safe in long-term probability models reduce the prospect of
disaster
to a very short fuse. A hedge that would be considered safe over a
period of a
year can suddenly be reduced to a position of high risk in a matter of
days or
even hours by market volatility. In such a market environment, the Fed,
rather
than its traditional role of market stabilizer over the long term, is
often
reduced to an emergency fire fighter in raging forest fires in a
financial
landscape infested with elements that practice arson for profit.
Still political opposition surfaced even before the Fed made
its final decision to take over AIG after the market closed. Richard
Shelby, ranking
minority Republican on the Senate Banking Committee, warned on
television
during the day: “I hope they don’t go down the road of a bailout,
because where
do you stop?’’
Representative Barney Frank, Democrat of Massachusetts and
chairman of the House Financial Services Committee, echoing rising
populist
criticism against deregulation, said Treasury Secretary Paulson and Fed
Chairman Bernanke had not requested any new legislative authority for
the
bailout at Tuesday night’s meeting. Chairman Frank complained: “The
secretary
and the chairman of the Fed, two Bush appointees, came down here and
said,
‘We’re from the government, we’re here to help them [private firms]. I mean this is one more affirmation that the
lack of regulation has caused serious problems. That the private market
screwed
itself up and they need the government to come help them unscrew it.”
House Speaker Nancy Pelosi quickly criticized the AIG rescue,
calling the $85 billion a “staggering sum”. Pelosi said the bailout was
“just
too enormous for the American people to guarantee.” Her comments
suggested that
the Bush administration and the Fed would face sharp questioning in
Congressional hearings. The White House said President Bush was briefed
earlier
in the afternoon. Actually, to put things in perspective, $85 billion,
though
no small sum, is what the US
is spending on the wars in Iraq
and Afghanistan
each week.
Abroad, the AIG bailout was viewed as a milestone marking US
rejection of free market fundamentalism to resort to government
intervention,
after decades of ideological hypocracy. In Asia,
it has
not been forgotten that during the 1997 Asian financial crisis, the
IMF,
dominated by US
ideology, set draconian conditionality for pledging $20 billion to help
South Korea
from defaulting on its foreign
currency obligations, to require the government to let ailing banks and
industrial companies to fail without government help. Many South Korean
banks
and companies were taken over by foreign competitors as a result. Now
the US
has suddenly transformed itself as the leading practitioner of state
capitalism
and economic nationalism in the name of saving the global free market
economy.
AIG’s plans for a private sector capital infusion fell apart
after its credit ratings were cut sharply on Monday, September 15,
which caused
a liquidity crisis that would leave AIG defaulting on its outstanding
obligation by Tuesday night in New York
before markets in Asia
opened on Wednesday morning there.
New York Governor David Paterson said earlier that AIG had only “a day”
to
solve its problems, and that its collapse would cause serious
dislocation for
the economies of New York State and New York City, not to mention the
rest of
the nation and the world. Estimates of losses for US financial
institutions could
reach over $200 billion as a result of AIG default.
For the short term, the market breathed a sigh of relief
from the AIG bail out. But going forward, the uncertainty over when the
Fed
will have to intervene again in which new firm, on what terms and under
what
conditions will in fact increases uncertainty at a time when
uncertainty has
caused destructive market turmoil. Each move by the Fed has been
accompanied by
comforting announcements that the move would stabilize the market, only
to have
the credibility of the central bank chipped away further by the
appearance of
new crises days later.
Two days later, as the market had time to digest the still
murky details of the Fed take over of AIG, panic in world credit
markets
reached historic intensity, prompting a frantic flight to safety of the
kind
not seen since the Second World War.
Barometers of financial stress hit peaks across the world.
Yields on short-term US Treasuries reached their lowest level since
WWII.
Lending between banks in effect dried up and investors scrambled to
pull their
funding from any institution or sector whose safety has been called
into doubt.
The $85 billion Fed bridge loan to AIG failed to curb the
surge in risk aversion. Instead, markets were hit by a fresh wave of
anxiety. Speculation
mounted that the Federal Reserve, which refused to cut rates on
Tuesday, could
be forced into an embarrassing U-turn. Amid the chaos, traders were
pricing in
32 basis points of rate cuts by the end of September – in essence
betting that
there was a 60% chance the Fed would cut rates by half a percentage
point in
coming days.
All thought of profit faded as traders piled in to the
safety of short-term Treasuries. The yield on three-month bills fell as
low as
0.02 per cent – rates that characterized the “lost decade” in Japan.
The last time they were this low was January 1941. At one point, the
intraday rate
was temporarily negative. The government was charging investors of
Tresurie for
lending it
money as a safe haven.
Shares in the two largest surviving independent investment
banks, Morgan Stanley and Goldman Sachs dropped 24% and 13.9%
respectively as
the cost of insuring their debt from default soared several percentage
points
to threaten their ability to finance their own debts in the market. A
wave of
merger talks reflected the need of investment banks to seek shelter in
large
commercial banks. Morgan Stanley was reported to be holding preliminary
merger
talks with Wachovia, itself a troubled regional bank. Rumors werer
circulating
that China Investment Corporation (CIC), China’s
$200 billion sovereign fund, which already owns 9.5% of Morgan Stanley,
or
Citic International Finance Holdings Ltd have been approached again to
come to
the aid of Morgan Stanley. Citic announced Wednesday (September 17) it
has
hired Morgan Stanley as its new financial adviser to replace collapsed
Lehman
Brothers Holdings Inc on the planned buyout offer for Citic shares by
Citic’s
parent in Beijing after Hong Kong securities regulators restricted
Lehman’s
four Hong Kong operating units from dealing with clients following the
bankruptcy filing of its US parent. Washington Mutual, a distressed
regional
lender, reportedly retained Goldman Sachs to approach potential buyers,
including JPMorgan Chase, Citigroup and Wells Fargo.
Newspapers headlined the shocking news that lending between
banks in effect halted after the AIG bail out. The TED spread – the
difference
between three-month LIBOR and three-month Treasury bill rates – moved
above 3%,
higher than the record close after the Black Monday crash of 1987. The TED spread is a measure of liquidity and
shows the degree to which banks are willing to lend money to one
another. It is
also an indicator of market perception of credit risk, as T-bills are
considered risk free while the LIBOR rate reflects counterparty credit
risk in
lending between commercial banks. As the TED spread increases, the risk
of
default (also known as counterparty risk) is considered to be
increasing, and
investors will develop a preference for safer investments.
The Securities and Exchange Commission announced drastic curbs
on naked short-selling (shorting share without owning them) to stop
sharp price
decline in share under attack. But the new rules failed to stop heavy
selling
of financial stocks. The S&P 500 fell 4.7%, led by an 8.9% drop in
financials. Price volatility in equities was near its highest level
since
March. Gold bullion price leaped 11.2% to a three-week high of $866.47
per
ounce.
Some critics are suggesting that the Fed needs to define clearly
the threshold above which it would intervene in the market. The problem
with not
being clear is that if the threshold is set too low, it increases moral
hazard,
and if it is set too high, it becomes self defeating as a way to
stabilize the
market. Further more, when the Fed set rules arbitrarily, it becomes a
cat and
mouse game to guess what the Fed would do next time. But playing cat
and
mouse with
market participants is the traditional game the Fed plays to neutralize
the
effect of rational expectation. The game is played every three months
when the
Fed Open Market Committee meets to consider the Fed funds rate target.
The way the Fed has been trying to stabilize the financial
market in this horrendous credit crisis since it burst open in August
2007 is
looking like punching new gaping holes in the throat of the patient to
deliver
more air to his lungs. One of these days, it may accidentally puncture
a
jugular vein to end the game. The lender of last resort has become a
predator
of last resort, nationalizing all dying enterprises. But it seems to be
racing
headlong onto the road of nationalization not so much as to help the
common people
as to keep dying financial dinosaurs alive. The Fed continues to
pretend that
firms likes AIG are merely going through a liquidity crunch.
The fact is that undercapitalization is by definition a
solvency problem. The problem is not that good assets are temporarily
hit with
prices below their real worth and that new capital is needed to
maintain debt
to equity ratio. The problem is that all these debts were not worth
their face
value to begin with. The high inflated market values of these assets
were held
up by circular trading of debt by assuming that they could always be
sold at
still higher prices way beyond their true worth. Now that the market is
finally
adjusting the price bubble downward and a lot of firm who were
incredibly
profitable on the way up are falling like leave in autumn in a bear
market. The
Fed is merely trying to inject money to keep prices not supported
by
fundamentals from falling. It is a prescription for hyperinflation. The
only
way to keep price of worthless assets high is to lower the value of
money. And
that appears to be the Fed unspoken strategy.
The US Treasury had briefly considered taking over AIG under
a conservatorship, as it did with the GSEs. But
it was a nonstarter, because insurance
companies, unlike Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac which are government
sponsored
enterprises, are regulated by state insurance commissions, not the
Federal
government. As an insurance company, rather than a bank, AIG was
supervised by
the state of New York
where it is
domiciled, rather than by a national regulator.
AIG’s current trouble has its roots in a decision in the
late 1980s to take over a group of derivatives specialists from Drexel
Burnham
Lambert which went bankrupt due to speculative losses in junk bonds.
AIG
Financial Products (AIGFP) wrote hundreds of billions of dollars of
derivatives,
spilling over from AIG’s insurance business. The business model rested
on
leveraging AIG’s low-cost of short-term funds to profit from high yield
long-term investments. With it’s AAA credit rating, AIG was an
attractive
counterparty for swap transactions. The Financial Products division,
unregulated because it is not an insurance entity nor a banking
operation, fell
between the regulatory crack. It expanded geometrically over the
decades into
areas such as credit-default swaps (CDS) which insure against risks of
default,
as well as originating mortgages and consumer debt. CDS are not
insurance
policies but only swap instruments that act like insurance policies.
During the
bubble years, this business model paid off with spectacular profits in
fees
when default rates were uncommonly low. Part of its expansion plan
included insuring
investors against defaults on collateralized debt obligations (CDOs),
or pools
of securities backed by unbundled risks with compensatory yields. The
$41 billion
write-downs that AIG suffered in recent months were mostly in these
swaps. .
AIG insures only “super-senior” deals, which were previously
deemed so safe by the rating agencies they held a triple-A rating. AIG
could
profit from the low return from these near risk-free instruments
because of it
low cost of funds. This advantage allowed AIG to become a key player
and
preferred counterparty in the top layer of the structured finance
market.
During the first seven years of this decade, AIGFP steadily
increased its presence in this opaque, and esoteric, corner of finance
and,
when the credit crunch started in August 2007, a significant portion of
the
insurance group’s exposure to the structured credit world was in the
form of
super-senior debt. When the credit crisis struck, the AIGFP management
expressed little concern about these holdings. As a result, AIG
announced on
December 5 that its cumulative loss had been just $1.4 billion.
However, one factor that forced AIG to conduct a U-turn in
accounting terms at the end of 2007 was that banks came under intense
pressure
from auditors in the closing months of 2007 to revalue their
super-senior
holdings. AIG’s auditors then forced it to also revise its super-senior
losses
from $1.5 billion to $6 billion, for the period ending November 30, 2007. Shortly,
afterwards, AIG
raised this estimate again to $11.5 billion – and on May 8, 2008 the company
declared that the losses had
swelled by an additional $9.1 billion.
With the ABX derivatives index continuing to decline, the
market feared that further write downs could be needed. The ABX
Index is a
series of credit-default swaps based on 20 bonds that consist of
subprime
mortgages. ABX contracts are commonly used by investors to speculate on
or to
hedge against the risk that the underling mortgage securities may not
be repaid
as expected. For regular payments of insurance-like premiums, ABX swaps
offer
protection if the securities default. A decline in the ABX Index
signifies
investor sentiment that subprime mortgage holders will suffer increased
financial losses. A rise in the ABX Index signifies investor sentiment
that
subprime mortgage holdings will perform better.
Outside its Financial Products Division, AIG holds valuable
insurance assets. These businesses include the largest commercial and
industrial insurer in the US,
and a business offering mainly car insurance to individuals. Yet these
assets
will decline in market value in a severe depression caused by the
credit crisis.
AIG also owns 59% of Transatlantic Holdings, a separately listed
reinsurer. AIG
is also one of the US’s
biggest life assurers, dominating the market for fixed annuities, a
popular
retirement savings product.
Globally, AIG is a big player in 130 countries, particularly
big in Asia. In addition, it owns one of the
world’s
biggest aircraft leasing operations and a sizeable asset management
business. With
such valuable assets, there should be no shortage of interestd buyers
for AIG’s
units in normal times. Prudential of the UK,
Warren Buffett, Allianz, Munich Re, have all indicated interested in
acquiring
some parts of AIG’s businesses. But these are not normal times.
Asset
deflation can be expected to last some years, causing the market value
of AIG
asset to stay way below the company’s current liabilities.
Maurice Greensberg, former chairman of AIG, claimed publicly
on television that the company only needs a bridge loan, not a
bail-out. The
company faces a liquidity crisis, not a solvency problem. Its core
insurance
operations, both in the US
and abroad, are financially sound, and it can raise more than $20
billion
through orderly asset sales, Greenberg said. For these reasons, a
bridge loan –
from the federal government if sufficient private capital is not
forthcoming –
will not mean a bail-out. A temporary bridge loan will prevent further
rating
agency downgrades, which would require AIG to post billions of dollars
in
additional collateral and which would likely prove fatal.
But the Fed has decided that the bridge loan needed to be
$85 billion, more than four times the amount Greenberg said the company
could
raise by selling assets. And $85 billion was in addition to the $20
billion AIG
already borrowed from its subsidiary as approved by New
York State
insurance regulators as an emergence measure. The
best accountants in the business could not
tell how much AIG would really
need to become solvent again.
Greenberg asserts that it is in US
national interest to save AIG because it operates in some 130 countries
and has
more than 100,000 employees worldwide, some 62,000 work in Asian. It
provides
credit protection to tens of thousands of financial institutions and
other
companies around the world. About 40% of its $54 billion in annual life
insurance premiums and retirement services fees is from Asia,
not counting Japan.
Its failure would pose systemic risk to the US
and the international financial systems.
According to Greenberg, AIG is not an ordinary company. It
has opened markets for the US
all over the world and, for more than three decades, stood at the
vanguard of
the liberalization of global trade in services. Its stock is owned
directly or
indirectly by millions of US citizens. And it has contributed
significantly to the US
gross
domestic product directly and indirectly over the four decades of its
existence.
Yet a case can be made that AIG contributed to the bubble
economy in the last two decades of disguising debt as wealth. It is not
clear if
Greenberg’s argument is a reason for saving AIG or a reason for
dismantling
liberalization of global trade.
It is true that allowing AIG to default on its obligations would
be more dangerous than allowing Lehman to go bankrupt. Yet it is not
clear that
keeping AIG afloat could stop this raging financial fire. AIG may be
just one
domino in a interconnected pile of falling dominos, albeit the biggest
one to
date.
AIG is faced with $441 billion of exposure to credit-default
swaps and other derivatives. Losses on these contracts have driven AIG
into a
vicious downwards spiral in which it needs ever more cash to remain a
top-rated
counterparty. JPMorgan Chase and Goldman Sachs had been charged by the
government with finding $75 billion from private sources to rescue
failing firm.
They both failed. The shares of Morgan Stanley and Goldman Sachs
themselves were
down sharply one day after the Fed issue an $85 billion bridge loan to
keep AIG
from defaulting.
Currently, the only regulatory checks on credit-default
swaps are requirements on counter-party risk. As long as AIG continued
to be over-rated
by lenient, even unrealistic, credit agency ratings, it seemed to be an
excellent counter-party. It increased its systemic importance as it
became less
stable. Regulators put unjustified faith in credit-rating agencies
whose
judgment can be impaired by conflicts of interest.
The disjointed structure of US regulatory agencies is outdated
for dealing with today’s brave new world of complex and interwoven
financial instruments.
As big financial “supermarkets” came into existence through
deregulation,
systemic risk can be short circuited while it appears to be dispersed.
National
and supranational regulators remained on the roadside on the
superhighway of
globalization. Regulators generally lack adequate mandate and expertise
to keep
pace with the supersonic speed of innovative financial products and
processes
that they are suppose to regulate.
AIG may be too big and too interconnected to fail. But governmental
measures to date to save the failing company appear to have very
limited effect
on an escalating melt down of the global financial market.
On January 11, 2006,
in Asia Times Online I pointed out the danger of credit-default swaps
in Of
debt,
deflation and rotten apples:
In the US,
where loan securitization is widespread, banks are tempted to push
risky loans
by passing on the long-term risk to non-bank investors through debt
securitization. Credit-default swaps, a relatively novel form of
derivative
contract, allow investors to hedge against securitized mortgage pools.
This
type of contract, known as asset-back securities, has been limited to
the
corporate bond market, conventional home mortgages, and auto and
credit-card
loans. Last June [2005], a new standard contract began trading by hedge
funds
that bets on home-equity securities backed by adjustable-rate loans to
sub-prime
borrowers, not as a hedge strategy but as a profit center. When bearish
trades
are profitable, their bets can easily become self-fulfilling prophesies
by
kick-starting a downward vicious cycle.
On May 17, 2007, three
months before the credit
crisis first broke out in August, while establishment pundits were
still in
adamant denial, my article: Why the Subprime Bust will Spread remained a
lonely voice; again in a January 26, 2008 article in
AToL: THE ROAD TO HYPERINFLATION - Fed
Helpless in its Own Crisis; and again in a June 22,
2008 article in AToL: Debt Capitalism Self-destructs.
Pointing
this out is not to claim I was particularly astute or prescient,
but to say that it is not possible that amid such clear signs of
impending trouble
that those in charge of billion of dollars of other people’s money,
supported
by high-priced research, were caught off guard. Criminal
dishonesty with derelict of fiduciary
duty is difficult to
deny.
Too Big to Fail is
the Cancer of Moral Hazard
“Too big to fail” is the cancer of moral hazard in the US
finance system of magnifying profit through high leverage. Moral hazard
is a
term in banking circles that describes the tendency of bankers to make
bad loan
based on an expectation that the lender of last resort, either the
Federal
Reserve domestically, or the IMF globally, will bail out troubled
multinational
banks. The term also applies to bad
loans made to borrowers that are considered “too big to fail” such as
AIG, Countrywide,
Citigroup, JPMorgan Chase, GE Capital, General Motors or borrowers such
as inept
Third World governments. In general, the principle of moral hazard
states that bailouts
encourage future recklessness. Brady bonds to bail out multinational
banks with
Latin American debts are labeled instruments of moral hazard in
conservative financial
circles.
Most bankers reject the moral hazard charge because they
welcome government intervention when it comes to protecting their
profits even
as they oppose regulations as hampering innovation and competitiveness
with
foreign banks. Bankers only want to get
government off their backs when government tries to help the
financially helpless
and the poor. Private bankers support privatization of profit and
socialization
of risks.
In global finance, the issue of moral hazard is more
complex. Economic imperialism uses moral hazard as an argument to
oppose debt forgiveness
for the poorest economies. During the
Asian financial crisis of 1997, the IMP imposed harsh
“conditionalities” (namely
high interest rates, corporate restructuring that results in lay off
and
massive unemployment, austere fiscal policies) justified by moral
hazard
arguments, punishing the poor in debtor nations for the sins of their
wayward bankers.
Many, including myself, have observed that the shrinking
intermediary role of banks in funding the economy, brought about by the
rapid
growth the non-bank credit and capital markets has increased system
risk in
recent decades.
See my September 5, 2007
AToL article: CREDIT BUST BYPASSES BANKS Part 1: The rise of the non-bank financial system
This risk manifests itself
only in a bear
market when price
corrections dissipate phantom wealth. This systemic risk exposure is
now building
up to an unprecedented crisis in both complexity and scale. The repeal
in 1999
of the Glass Steagall Act of 1933 that separated commercial banks and
investment banks allows banks to compensate for their shrinking funding
role by
moving into securitization and propriety trading through their
investment
banking subsidiaries.
There is no doubt that all of the nation’s biggest financial
conglomerates, whose commercial paper is the bellwether for the dollar
and euro
commercial paper markets, will fall from borrower defaults and their
interconnected size will be the “too big to fail” reason for Fed
intervention. It is very clear that
troubled debt-ridden corporations will now turn to the banks for help,
not
because bankers are friendlier than bondholders, but because banks have
access
to the Fed discount window. All through
his long tenure at the Fed, Greenspan’s recurring message to banks to
continue
lending during the first sign of recession was a clear signal that the
Fed
would provide all the liquidity that is needed to prevent a systemic
collapse. The trouble is that the
inter-linkage through
structured finance allows even tiny companies to trigger the demise of
firms
that are “too big to fail”.
The Nasdaq alone has made $3 trillion of market capitalization
disappear in the last nine months of 2000 during the tech bubble bust
which put
many corporate bonds under water. Unless
the Fed is prepared to inject trillions of reserves into the banking
system,
the debt crisis cannot be solved. And if the Fed does that, what will
happen to
inflation and the exchange rate of the dollar? Cash denominated in
dollars is
looking less a safe haven everyday. That is why the price of gold has
jumped
up.
It is an irony that at the very time when the US
financial system is showing signs of structural failure, the global
trend to
adopt US business models and finance practices is reaching its peak.
All over
the world, governments are rushing to privatize public assets,
securitize debts
and deregulate their transitional economies away from socialism with
the hope
of reaping the enviable results that the US
free market economy has enjoyed for decades. The
bill of this enviable boom is now fast
coming due and much of the
world will to have pay without ever having enjoyed the benefits. The “race to the bottom” syndrome in wage
competition has been enhanced by the “race toward risk” syndrome in
finance
competition.
The marketplace of ideas, not unlike financial and commodity
marketplaces, often operates on mis-information until cruelly pulled
back into
reality by unforgiving facts. In
countries around the world, much governmental and institutional aping
of US deregulation
practices is based on a misunderstanding of what a fatal virus US
neoliberal
market fundamentalism really is.
There is some truth in the popular myth that US ways are
more flexible, more willing to innovate and to adopt to change. In the
last two
decades, US
innovation and quick response to new business opportunities have
produced a record
setting long boom with only short recessions, with spectacular rise in
profits
and asset value. US
household net worth, until the recent (and early wave) market crash,
peaked at
over $58.25 trillion in Q3 2007, doubling in a decade.
It declined to $57.72 trillion in Q4.
The end of the Cold War and the global eclipse of socialist
tenets have left US
faith in market fundamentalism with the aura of a natural philosophy.
The US
calls her system capitalist democracy. In
doing so, care is taken to distinguish
democracy from
equalitarianism. Conceptually, while the
Declaration of Independence claims that “all men are created equal”,
the nation
that lives by it readily accepts the premise that men do not create
wealth
equally. The US
system rejects social democracy which aims to reduce glaring economic
disparity
between people. The US
system claims it promotes equality of opportunities rather than
equality of
rewards. It believes that the logic of
the market is the most equitable arbitrage. Free-marketeers decry
intimate
relationships between government, finance and business and oppose even
corporatism as an adjunct to the welfare state. They
believe that the market’s unforgiving
rules of selecting and rewarding
winners and penalizing losers are inherently fair, efficient and
necessary for
maximizing overall economic growth. It is obscene that when they are
punished
by market forces for their wayward manipulation that they call for
government
help for themselves in the name of the common good.
The trouble with this view of free market capitalism is that
it is a fallacy to assume that truly free markets can exist without
regulation. Markets are always constrained
by local
customs and rules, unequal conditions and unequal information access by
participants.
In fact, markets come into existence through artificial construction by
initial
participants with rules that subsequent participants must observe as an
admission price. These artificial rules
generally favor the market founders and put later comers at a perpetual
disadvantage. World Trade Organization
(WTO) rules are the
latest visible examples. Often the only
option
left to late comers is to start alternative markets hoping that they
will enjoy
the very privileges and advantages they oppose in existing markets.
Thus all markets require a wide range of regulations to check
and balance their inherent march toward inequality and unfairness.
Trade, by definition,
is based on mutually balanced weaknesses. Mutual
strength leads only to conflict, and
unequal strength leads to
conquest of the weak.
Adam Smith advocated "free trade" in the
mercantilist context as an activist government policy to breakdown the
protectionist policies of other nations while subsidizing national
industries
to compete in a tariff-free and open world market.
“Free enterprise” was first developed by
royal charters and grants from the sovereign for business operations
and for
land development within the royal domain, and for trading rights and
command of
the high seas to “freely” exploit colonies and foreign locations. In
other
words, free enterprise was launched and fostered with government aid
and grants
that private investors found too risky or whose potential rewards too
remote. Royal charters, letters patent and
copyrights
are all instruments of government for the privilege of exploiting the
resources
in the sovereign’s domain. Government and free enterprise have always
worked in
concert. Modern free enterprise manages
to prevent the monopolistic or oligarchic control of markets only by
government
action. Business always wants government
help before the market is mature and after the market is saturated. It only wants “free” markets to gain easy
profit. Business by nature abhors
competition and social responsibilty.
The notion of “too big to fail” is sacred in US
regulatory philosophy. This remains true even as the anti-monopolistic
“restraint
of trade” regulatory regime of the New Deal was steadily modified in
recent decades
to permit mergers and acquisition toward increased size and market
share to
achieve strategic advantage. The
scenario of the ideal free market is that there should be only five
entities in
every sector: two market leaders and three window-dressing market
followers to
keep regulators at bay. The US
economy has always been organized along oligarchic lines in its core
industries,
allowing a high degree of centralization while preserving only a token
degree
of competition. The rules of competition
are generally set by market leaders of every industry. Self-regulation
is the
mantra. Responding to the current crisis, US
regulators are seeking to change rules to ease bank mergers, by further
loosening rules. The Fed has announced an easing of restrictions that
had
forbidden regulated companies to transfer funds to less regulated and
more
risky affiliates, such as from commercial banks to their investment
bank
subsidiaries.
While the US
promotes globalization, US
attitude on foreign ownership of US assets remains schizophrenic. Furthermore, there is an inherent
contradiction in globalization in that while capital is allowed to move
freely
across political borders, labor is not. It
is now conveniently forgotten, when the IMF
was established by the
Bretton Woods Conference, its Articles of Agreement specifically
sanctioned
restriction on movements of capital across national borders. Until labor can also move freely, the
lopsided globalization is nothing but economic neo-imperialism. It is not a march toward one world, it is a
march towards an hierarchical world of structural inequality.
Another defining characteristic of modern US
finance is the broad access to credit. US
businesses have long enjoyed access to open credit markets. In recent
years, until
the current developing credit crunch, no US corporations of any size is
effectively shut out of the highly developed credit market, regardless
of
credit rating. Low credit ratings only
affect
the interest rate rather than credit market accessibility.
In fact, debt securitization has brought
virtual security to credit unworthiness on a massive scale. The
commercial
paper market first burgeoned in the 1960s and for four decades,
collateralized debt
obligations (CDO) dominated the global credit market, until the credit
crisis
of 2007. Securitization is a process of
turning non-marketable credit instruments into marketable ones through
pooling. Securitization creates credit
worthiness out of the theory of large numbers and the theory of
averaging to
manage the risk of default by spreading it to a large pool. When a
lender lends
to a risky company, he bears the full risk of default.
But if he invests in a collateral debt
obligation instrument, he is lending to a pool of companies whose
default rate
may be reduced to a risk level coverable by the interest rate spread. The fatal enemy of securitization is a
liquidity crisis when all exits from purportedly open markets will be
suddenly
closed, when all participants move to the sell side, leaving the buy
side empty
at any price. Today (September 16,
2008), Fed funds rate target is 2% and
prime rate posted by two-thirds of the nation’s 30 largest banks is 5%,
while
commercial paper rate is 2.7% for 211-270
days, and dealers CP (high grade unsecured notes sold through dealers
by major
corporations) is 2.75% for 90 days. The spread is not abnormal, but few
deals
are closed. There is no shortage of funds or shortage of borrowers,
just
shortage of willing lenders. It is clear
evidence that it is not a liquidity crisis. It is a confidence crisis.
Derivatives are financial instruments whose values are
derived from the value of another instrument. Among other effects,
derivatives
tend to lower the systemic credit standard of the markets by
manipulating the
assignment of risk to commensurate return. Highly-rated
corporations can now arbitrage
their high credit standing
to further lower their cost of funds by issuing long-term fixed rate
debt and
then swapping the proceeds against the obligation to pay a floating
rate. In other words, they monetize their
high
rating by taking on more risk. Simultaneously,
lower-rated corporations that
otherwise would be frozen
out of the credit markets as the credit cycles mature can use
derivatives to
lock in long-term yields by borrowing short and swapping into long-term
maturity obligations. In other words, they pay more interest to buy
higher
credit ratings, not withstanding the fact that high interest cost would
actually further lower their credit ratings. The
intermediaries, banks and other financial
institutions that make
credit markets and trade these obligations enjoy the illusion of being
relatively risk free by linking their risks system wide. The credit
ratings of
these banks appear relatively strong, but in fact they appear strong
only
because the overall credit rating of the system has declined.
When individual risks are passed on to systemic risk, individual
creditors are comforted by the safety of the "too big to fail"
syndrome, because they become part of the big system.
The growth of pension and retirement funds can be viewed as
a process in the socialization of capital formation.
This process has brought about a corresponding
growth in professional asset management based on competitive
performance
measured by short term market value, placing distorted emphasis on
technical
trends investing rather than fundamentals investing.
The quest to socialize risk has led to
indexation which works better in rising market to capture optimal
systemic
returns, but can also cause the categorical downgrade of entire
families of
debt instruments and their issuers without regard for individual
strength. This can cause unnecessary and
violent systemic
damage, as it did in Asia in 1997 and now in
the US
since 2007. This socialization of risk
associated
with the socialization of capital formation means that a financial
collapse
will affect not merely the rich investors who may be able to afford the
loss,
but the entire population who can ill afford to lose their pension.
The “too big to fail” notion then comes directly into play
and government is forced to step in, putting an end to the myth of the
free
market. Moral hazard will be in full
bloom as the nature of the beast. The
Fed has been repeatedly held hostage to the “too big to fail” syndrome
since
1930 and will again and again until it becomes the main agent to herald
socialism to the US,
as Schumpeter predicted. Creative
Destruction,
of which Greenspan is so fond, will eventually destroy capitalism with
creativity.
Leverage is another development that not only magnifies
volatility, but the abnormally high rates of leveraged return distort
market
judgment, making normally respectable returns look unattractive. Greed
becomes
standardized. Derivatives and hedging
techniques have created the illusion of safety by risk management,
while they
merely reshuffle risks system wide and heighten exponentially the
penalty of
misjudgment.
Litigiousness is a byword of the US
notion of the rule of law. Innovative contracts and financial and
business
relationship are often inadequately defined to meet rapidly changing
conditions, and disputes are settled in courts whose judgments can have
drastic
consequences to the litigating parties as well as the system. Major bankruptcies have been routinely caused
by court decisions. The tobacco legal time
bomb is a good example. It is a matter of time that a court decision
will drive
a major tabacco company into bankruptcy. Texaco was forced into
bankruptcy when
faced with a judgment that exceeded its entire market cap value, based
on the
legal definition of what constituted a valid offer in a merger.
The list of potential bankrupts is long. The
stabilizing value of legal precedents is
greatly discounted in a world of constant unprecedented judicial
developments.
Courts are frequently confronted with controversies that the judges and
their
law clerks are grossly unqualified to comprehend. Court
decisions often hark back to symbolic
posturing based on dated concepts. The anti-trust cases against
Microsoft are a
classic example: the issues raised in the case have become
operationally
obsolete as the legal process drags on, yet the courts are asked to
make
determinations based on them that will affect the future of software
monopoly.
The most fundamental flaw in US financial market system is
its inherent drive towards excess. A market boom will only end with a
market crash
unless government intervenes in mid course. The
quest for the short term maximization of
returns leads inevitably a
speculative bubble. The traditional
demand/supply business cycle has been genetically modified into a
debt-propelled cycle that requires more debt to prolong.
And the speed of the expansion dictates that
more debt can only be added by a lowering credit quality. The end
result is
always systemic implosion.
This is what Greenspan means when he refers to unbalances in
the system, that physical expansion of productivity cannot possible
keep pace
with credit expansion associated with the sudden wealth effect. In the
Greenspan era, stocks were valued at 181% of GDP at their peak in March
2000, while
at the beginning of the decade they were 60% of GDP. One of the
characteristics
of a bubble economy is the de-coupling of the equity markets from the
actual
performance of the economy.
There is clear evidence that the wealth effect does not
reflect the performance of the economy. One
of the few valid points made by Greenspan
was that the wealth effect
created imbalances that were more than conventional time lag. The Clinton
budget surplus resulting from credit-induced extended long boom was
merely a
false signal of the illusionary soundness of the US
economy. GDP was measuring the size of the
debt bubble rather than the size of the real economy.
Some economists had been vocal that the Clinton
budget surplus was in fact an indicator of economic trouble ahead. Those who proudly pointed to the budget
surplus as the Clinton
administration
greatest achievement have come to look extremely foolish in 2008.
Private debt,
both consumer and corporate, has been growing at record pace in the US
for the
past two decades, drawing funds from lenders all over the globe. Much
of this
debt was taken on by telecom companies whose revenues fell as much as
90%
through deregulation. Asecond wave of debt went into the housing bubble.
As the equity markets collapse from earnings shortfalls
caused by an expanding market capitalization outpacing slower earnings
growth,
the political pressure for the Fed to inject more debt into the system
by lower
interest rates always becomes irresistible.
The emergence of an unregulated open credit market
diminishes significantly, though not totally, the ability of central
banks to
manage the economy through conventional monetary policy measures,
because of
the banks’ shrinking intermediary role in the credit market. A credit binge in which loose lending to
borrowers of dubious credit worthiness is always followed by a credit
crunch,
as surely as gluttony leads to obesity that will outgrow the wardrobe.
Bad loans are made in good times, as Greenspan is fond of
quoting. A credit crunch is an
interruption in the supply of credit which can be caused by destruction
of the
lenders' incentive through a decline in regulatory protection, or
massive
defaults by borrowers on loans taken out during a credit binge. When that happens, the central bank’s only
option is to alter the financial structure to reconnect credit supply
in a
timely manner. And in the current
markets of electronic trading, timeliness is a matter of hours, not
weeks. The
futility of the Fed’s traditional time lag response is exacerbated by
speed of
oncoming danger.
Yet Greenspan told Congress in his July 1999
Humphrey-Hawkins testimony: “But identifying a bubble in the process of
inflating may be among the most formidable challenges confronting a
central
bank, putting its own assessment of fundamentals against the combined
judgment
of millions of investors.” Investor
judgments
are now mostly based on technical analysis while the Fed is still
looking at
fundamentals.
This explains why the record of the Fed’s recognition of
market trends has been consistently six months late. Yet the Fed cannot
afford
to wait for market discipline to correct a credit crunch. And because
of the recognition
time lag, coupled with the diminished ability of the Fed to affect
market
decisions, and the compressed chain reaction time of collapse, each
subsequent
intervention would need to be escalated or overshot to achieve
comparable
effect, which in turn increases moral hazard to fuel the next abuse. It is intervention inflation, similar to the
narcotic syndrome of pushing towards the edge to reach new highs which
always
leads to fatal overdosing.
The global financial upheavals since 1997 have damaged not
only financial markets, but national economies along their paths. The
Mexican
crisis of 1994, the South Korean crisis of 1997-98 (the only one in
Asian the US
intervened because Brazilian investors were holding Korean bonds), and
the Brazilian
crisis of 1998, the Russian bond crisis of 1998, Argentina and Turkey
in 2000,
are all victims who have become permanent patients in the critical care
unit of
the IMF. Yet the US economy has been immune mostly because the Fed,
taking advantage
of dollar hegemony, which is the unique position of the dollar as the
anchor
currency in the existing international finance architecture, and its
ability to
print dollars unimpeded, applied a bailout standard on the US economy
much less
demanding than what the US required of the IMF for other economies. In recent decades, the Treasury and the White
House have effectively usurped much of the Fed's alleged independence
through
the back door of foreign exchange rate policy which narrows domestic
interest
rates options. A strong dollar policy is
part of US
financial hegemony. It is a national
security
position of the White House that the Fed must support. Now the Treasury
is
again ordering the Fed around in the nation of national economic
security.
The credit bubble has been largely responsible for the
spectacular growth of the financial infrastructure. The narrow focus on
rising
market capitalization value has obscured the high leverage in the US
economy and to a lesser degree in the global economy.
Global equity markets rebound within months
out of the debris of sequential financial crises while the local
economies stay
depressed for years. Recovery is
proclaimed all over Asia while
people remain jobless and
desperately poor. Stock options became
currency not only for management compensation and corporate mergers,
but for
the general working population in the so-called New Economy and for
seeding new
enterprises. Loans collateralized by
inflated market capitalization are preferred to liquidation as a devise
to
skirt capital gain taxes. These loans
magnify growth in a rising market and they magnify contraction in a
falling
market.
The Fed eased in 1998 after the Russian default. History
would decided whether the Fed did the
right thing by allowing Russia
to default. But there is now cleared
evidence that the Fed panicked and eased excessively after the Russian
default
and after the LTCM bailout, thus exacerbating the post 1998 bubble,
foreclosing
the prospect of a soft landing.
A bubble is formed when there is aggregate overstating of
financial value. Its existence saps real
growth because profit can then be earned more easily from speculation
than from
increased productivity. That was the
virus that seriously wounded the Japanese economy and kept it depressed
for
over a decade. It is now killing the US
economy.
The phenomenon that turned the dollar into the base currency
for world trade is oil related. The US
abandoned the Bretton Woods regime of gold-backed fixed exchange rates
in 1971
but the dollar remained the anchor currency for world trade. The 1973 oil embargo gave APEC control of the
oil market and pricing power. But oil is transacted with dollars. The
black
gold trade reinforced the dollar as the international trade currency,
despite
the fact that it has not been backed by US monetary and fiscal
discipline for
decades.
Gold everybody wants but nobody needs. But oil, everybody
needs in the modern world. The pricing
of oil then becomes the true anchor for the value of the dollar, not
the Fed's
monetary measures. When the price of oil
rises, the dollar depreciates in real terms. When it falls, the dollar
appreciates. For most of last decade, the US
has managed
to keep oil prices low, around $10/barrel, reaping the benefit of a
strong
dollar with low inflation. But cheap oil
price discourages conservation and exploration which eventually will
cause oil
prices to rise. $90 oil is expensive
only in relative terms to recent historical prices, but its impact on
the
economic bubble is significant.
The rise in oil prices in 1973 was handled by the recycling
of oil dollars into US assets. It was
the same strategy used to finance the US
trade deficit in a decade of globalization, until 1997. By the 1980s,
as oil dollars
accumulated, the US
economy, beset by the burst of a credit bubble which produced
stagflation, was
unable to absorb further investment at expected returns. The
transnational
financial institutions then discovered Third World
lending which produced high returns commensurate with high risk. But as Walter Wriston proclaimed: "Banks
go bankrupt, but countries don't." Thus
oil money can earn high returns without
commensurate risk in Third World loans, as
governments will always bailout such loans. As history
recorded, Third World borrowers defaulted en
mass. By 1982, nine US
banks had lent Mexico
alone $13.4 billion, representing 50% of their combined capital. To
handle the
impact of sovereign default, Mexico
temporarily closed its foreign exchange window and converted all
foreign currency
accounts into pesos and demanded a debt restructuring which the banks
reluctantly complied. The US
banking system was seriously weaken as a result of Third
World
debt.
U.S. Treasury Secretary Nicholas Brady, in the 1980s in
association with the IMF and World Bank sponsored the effort to
permanently
restructure outstanding sovereign loans and interest arrears into
liquid debt instruments. Brady Bonds
represent the restructured bank
debt of Latin American and other emerging nations that over-borrowed
from U.S. Designed to prevent
financial meltdown for lenders and borrowers alike, Bradys are normally
collateralized by US zero-coupon bonds of various maturities. That
means
principal is guaranteed, but most bonds' coupons are not.
If a country can't make its interest
payments, investors can collect 100% of their principal when the bonds
come
due. But they lose out on interest, and they have tied up their money
for years
instead of putting it into a paying investment. And because the bonds
no longer
pay interest, their value in the secondary market plummets to only a
fraction
of their face value. This market is extremely volatile, reacting to
moves in US
bond prices and especially to bad news from emerging nations, such as
the
Mexican peso devaluation of 1994.
Hedge funds, insurance companies, and other institutional
investors have been willing to take that chance lately. Meanwhile, the
managers
of US
open-end
mutual funds dedicated to emerging-market debt are insisting that Brady
bonds
have gone main stream. Countries involved in the Brady Plan
restructuring: Argentina, Brazil,
Bulgaria, Costa Rica,
Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Mexico, Morocco, Nigeria, Philippines,
Poland,
Uruguay.
Some countries like Mexico,
Venezuela,
and Nigeria
have attached to their Par and Discount bonds rights or warrants which
grant
bondholders the right to recover a portion of debt or debt service
reduction as
stated in the Exchange Agreements, should their debt servicing capacity
improve. In effect, some are known as Oil Warrants because they are
linked to
oil export prices and thus to the oil export receipts.
The collateral consists of funds maintained
in a cash account usually at the Federal Reserve Bank in New
York and typically invested in AA- or better
securities,
for the purpose of paying the interest should a debtor country not
honor an
interest payment. A rolling interest guarantee (usually 12 to
18 months
or 2 to 3 coupon payments) remains in effect as
each successive coupon payment is made. The collateral continues to
guarantee payment
for the next successive unsecured coupon. In the event the collateral
is used, there
is no obligation to replace it.
In the 1987 crash, Greenspan, merely nine weeks as Chairman,
flooded the system with reserves by having the FOMC buy massive
quantities of government
securities from the market, and announced the next day that the Fed
would
"serve as liquidity to support the economic and financial system." Some accuse Greenspan for bringing on the
crash by raising the discount rate 50 basis points to 6%.
Portfolio insurance has been identified as
having exacerbating the crash. The
technique involves selling stock futures when stock prices fall to
limit or
insure a portfolio against large losses. This
gives index arbitrageurs the opportunity
to benefit from lower
future prices by buying futures in Chicago
and selling the stock market in New York,
adding selling pressure in the market. But
the fundamental cause of the 1987 crash
was the trend of corporation
moving to debt from equity financing. Corporate new debt tripled in a
decade,
with debt service taking up 22% of internal cash flow.
Total non-financial debt was 225.5% of GDP in
2007, compared to 182.9% in 1987, and 139.2% in 1977. Corporate credit
ratings
deteriorated but the lending did not cease because funds were being
raised in
the non-bank credit markets. Home mortgages were 80.4% of GDP in 2007
compared
to 40.8% in 1987. GSE mortgage pool was 53.1% of GDP in 2007 compared
to 40.6%
in 1987. It is clearly show a housing bubble of debt.
Historians have identified the causes of the 1930 Depression
as:
1) Too much savings in relation to consumer power due to
income disparity;
2) Over capacity due to excessive investment from surplus
capital;
3) Over stimulation through the growth of debt through new
intricate system of inter linked debt obligations;
4) Legalized price fixing through mergers and acquisitions;
big corporations maintain price and cut production instead of lowering
prices, resulting
in massive unemployment;
5) Economic growth too heavily dependent of big ticket
durable goods that cannot sell in a depression thus slowing recovery;
6) Exhaustion of public confidence and optimism; and
7) The collapse of international trade (Smoot-Hawley Tariff
Act).
8) Irresponsible foreign lending (the US
was a creditor nation with a credit balance about twice the size of the
total
foreign investment in the US.)
All of these causes are still present today at a larger
scale and faster reaction time, with the exception that the US
is now the world’s biggest debtor nation.
Greenspan testified in 1998: “We should note that were banks
required by the market, or their regulator, to hold 40 percent capital
against
assets as they did after the Civil War, there would, of course, be far
less
moral hazard and far fewer instances of fire-sale market disruptions.
At the same
time, far fewer banks would be profitable, the degree of financial
intermediation
less, capital would be more costly, and the level of output and
standards of
living decidedly lower. Our current economy, with its wide financial
safety
net, fiat money, and highly leveraged financial institutions, has been
a
conscious choice of the American people since the 1930s. We do not have
the
choice of accepting the benefits of the current system without its
costs.”
Well, the costs are coming headlong like a runaway freight
train.
Whole testimony:
http://www.bog.frb.fed.us/boarddocs/testimony/1998/19981001.htm
Experts note that each financial crisis is unique, which
probably is true in detail. These
experts also seek comfort in the observation that the identified
excesses of
past crashes have been dealt with through new regulatory measures,
which is
also undeniable. Yet financial crisis
have persistent common threads in that they seem to defy precise
anticipation and
that their occurrence leave serious structural damage.
Thus the
requirement of
a conservative debt to equity ratio is needed to protect the system
from policy
misjudgment. Yet the US system prospers
on living on the edge through maximization and socialization of risk,
thus building
in failure or collapse that hurts no just the willing risk takers, but
the
general public who has been put into risky situations they cannot
afford by the
sales talks of sophisticated risk management.
Will history compare Clinton to Coolidge and Bush II to Hoover?
September 19, 2008 .
|
|
|
|
|