Milton Friedman
and the Money Matters Controversy
By
Henry CK Liu
This article appeared in AToL on
September 5, 2008
The University of Chicago announced plans
last June to
establish a high-power research institute in economics to be named
after Milton
Friedman, a high profile free market monetarist professor at the
university
from 1946 to 1976, who was widely regarded as the intellectual leader
of the
Chicago School of monetary economics, which stresses the overwhelming
importance
of the quantity of money as an instrument of government economic policy
and as
a determinant of business cycles and inflation. He was also an
outspoken public
defender of free markets which he inevitably linked with political
freedom. But the plan is facing strong vocal oppositon from none other
than Friedman's own colleagues in the university.
Friedman was the 1976 recipient of the Nobel/Sveriges
Riksbank Prize in economics. The press release of the award cited
Friedman’s
coining of the term “money matters” or even “only money matters” as an
arresting
slogan for monetarism. On November
17, 2006, one day after his death at age 94, the Wall Street
Journal printed an opinion piece by Friedman entitled: Why
Money Matters.
The official press release on the award explained the choice
of Friedman as follows: “This strong emphasis on the role of money
should be
seen in the light of how economists - usually advocates of a narrow
interpretation of Keynesian theory - have, for a long time, almost
entirely
ignored the significance of money and monetary policy when analyzing
business
cycles and inflation. As far back as the beginning of the fifties,
Friedman was
a pioneer in the well-founded reaction to the earlier post-Keynesian
one-sidedness. And he succeeded - mainly thanks to his independence and
brilliance - in initiating a very lively and fruitful scientific debate
which
has been going on for more than a decade. In fact, the
macro-econometric models
of today differ greatly from those of a couple of decades ago as far as
the
monetary factors go - and this is very much thanks to Friedman. The
widespread
debate on Friedman’s theories also led to a review of monetary policies
pursued
by central banks - in the first place, in the United
States. It is very rare for an
economist to
wield such influence, directly and indirectly, not only on the
direction of
scientific research but also on actual policies.”
The press release was factual in some respects and outright
inaccurate in others. It is accurate that Friedman strongly emphasized
the role
of money. But it is inaccurate to describe Friedman as having reversed
the
“narrow interpretation” of Keynesian theory because “only money
matters”
is
literally a narrowing spotlight among the broad range of factors that
Keynesian
theory normally considers in formulating economic policy, including
monetary
factors. It is accurate to say Friedman was an early pioneer in
reaction to
post-Keynesianism, but it is not accurate to label post-Keynesianism
one-sided.
In fact “only money matters” sounded definitively one-sided to most
listeners.
Friedman’s reaction to Keynesianism is hardly well-founded, though it
is
admittedly reactionary. As the press
report noted, Friedman’s emphasis of money is important to the analysis
of the
business cycle and inflation. But
business cycles are not the economy, only one aspect of it. In fact,
Friedman’s
fundamental flaw is his fixation on the business cycle as expressed by
the
stock market, rather than looking at the whole economy with a wide
range of
meta-finance concerns such as agricultural economics, labor economics,
population economics, the economics of war, pollution, development,
etc. The
list is long and interlinked and any economist ignoring any of part of
the list
runs the risk of being one-sided.
The market is merely the transactional record of the
economy. Students of the market economy tend to confuse business, which
is transacted
in the market, as the whole economy itself. That is the problem with Business
School
economists who really should
be called “busi-nomists” rather than eco-nomists because by definition
and by design
they are not concerned with eco, a
Greek word “oikos” meaning house. The word describes the complex
symbiotic
relationships of all living organisms in relation to their environment in the eco-system. Business is ony a
subsystem
of the
socio-economic ecosystem. The goal of busi-nomists is to keep the
business
cycle
from recurring crashes even if it means destroying the economy in the
process. To
achieve this goal, central banking was invented.
This is not to denigrate business experts. All experts,
however narrow, perform useful functions and brilliant experts deserve
admiration. It is just that they should refrain from fantasizing that
they are generalists
dealing with the economy. Business
exists to make profit for the businessman and there is nothing wrong
with that
as long as ethical rules are observed. Unlike business, the economy
exists to
enhance progress in civilization. The former is artificial, the latter
is actual.
The key problem of the recent decades of Friedman monetarism has not
been that
money matters but that it matters too much.
Friedman had also written extensively on public policy,
always with primary emphasis on the preservation and extension of
individual
freedom, going beyond economics. His books, periodical columns, media
personal
appearances and a 1980 ten-part series on Public Television with the
grand
title of Freedom to Choose, followed by a second three-part series in
1984
which together commanded more air time than the 10-part series by
Kenneth Clark
on Civilization, made him an influential national opinion molder beyond
economics. In time, Friedman readily transformed himself from the role
of a
social scientist to that of a globe-trotting, faith-peddling evangelist
of what
a disillusioned Japanese central banker later called snake oil
economics.
In 1988, Friedman was awarded the National Medal of Science
by the National Science Foundation and the Presidential Medal of
Freedom by
President Reagan. Thus encouraged, Friedman went on to publish in 2002 Capitalism and Freedom, a passionate echo
of official calls for extending individual economic freedom and
limiting
government action, except in foreign affairs. Free trade, officially
endorsed
by pseudo-science, has since become the central focus of US
“transformational” foreign policy to spread freedom around the world.
It is
Adam Smith turned up-side-down.
President George W Bush defended the free trade agenda in
moralistic terms. “Open trade is not just an economic opportunity, it
is a
moral imperative,” he declared in a May 7, 2001 speech. “Trade creates jobs for the
unemployed. When we
negotiate for open markets, we’re providing new hope for the world’s
poor. And
when we promote open trade, we are promoting political freedom.”
While such
claims remain highly controversial when tested by actual data, it
explains why
Milton Friedman, a free trade economist, was awarded the Presidential
Medal of
Freedom by President Reagan.
Phyllis Schlafly, syndicated conservative columnist,
responded three weeks later in an article: Free Trade is an
Economic Issue,
Not a Moral One. In it, she notes while conservatives should
be happy
to finally have a president who adds a moral dimension to his actions,
“the
Bible does not instruct us on free trade and it’s not one of the Ten
Commandments. Jesus did not tell us to follow Him along the road to
free trade.
… Nor is there anything in the U.S. Constitution that requires us to
support
free trade and to abhor protectionism. In fact, protectionism was the
economic
system believed in and practiced by the framers of our Constitution.
Protective
tariffs were the principal source of revenue for our federal government
from
its beginning in 1789 until the passage of the 16th Amendment, which
created
the federal income tax, in 1913. Were all those public officials during
those
hundred-plus years remiss in not adhering to a “moral obligation” of
free
trade?” Hardly, argues Schlafly whose views were noteworthy
because US
politics was at that time enmeshed in a struggle between
strict-constructionist
paleo-conservatives and moral-imperialist neo-conservatives.
Despite the
ascendance of neo-imperialism in US
foreign policy, protectionism remains strong in US
political culture, particularly among conservatives and in the labor
movement.
And now in 2008, a new populism is rising against the US
version of free trade.
Redefining humanist morality, the US
asserts that world trade is a moral imperative and as such free trade
promotes
democracy, political freedom and respect for human rights in trade
participating nations. Unfortunately, income and wealth equality
are not
among the benefits promoted by free trade. Even if the validity
of this
twisted ideological assertion is not questioned, it clearly contradicts
US
practice of trade embargo against countries the US
deems undemocratic, lacking in political freedom and deficient in
respect for
human rights. If trade promotes such desirable conditions, such
practice
of linking trade to freedom is tantamount to denying medicine to the
sick.
Love is blind and infatuation disguises faults as virtues.
As Rudyard Kipling fell in love with the pageantry of colonialism and
saw
racial exploitation as the “White Man’s Burden”, Nobel economist
Friedman fell
in love with colonial Hong Kong, seduced by the
wine-and-dine hospitality of its colonial masters and elite compradors
before China
reclaimed sovereignty of it in 1997. Friedman mistook Hong
Kong’s
colonial economic system as a free market, despite Hong Kong’s
long history of highly orchestrated colonial command economic
structure. The Hong Kong economy that Friedman
loved prospered from Cold War geopolitical
tension, not free market principle. The Asian Financial Crisis that
broke out
in Thailand
on July 2, 1997,
one day after China
took back Hong Kong, put monetarist market
fundamentalism in the public opinion dog house in Asia.
The new Milton Friedman Institute will be funded with seed
money from the University of Chicago to launch a campaign to raise $200
million
from private donors who are expected to give $1 million or more each,
no doubt
from sources that have benefited royally by Friedman’s wacky ideas.
Edward Snyder, dean of the university's Graduate School of
Business, told Bloomberg news that “Naming the institute for Friedman
will
honor the economist, whose libertarian theories helped the spread of
capitalist
systems of government, and will attract donors from around the world.
When you
think about the big battle between socialism and free markets -- he led
the
charge on behalf of the University
of Chicago. There are a lot
of people
who will give back because of his name and effort and legacy.” Crony capitalism is giving birth to crony
intellectualism.
In an ironic twist of Friedman’s “money matters”, a Committee
for Open Research on Economy & Society (CORES) has been formed to
protest
and oppose the proposed Friedman Institute. CORES is co-chaired by
Bruce
Lincoln, the University’s Caroline E. Haskell Professor of History of
Religions.
More than 100 other tenured faculty members from a broad range of
disciplines
who are concerned with the promotion of doctrinal hegemony by money
power have
signed a petition opposing the concept and structure of an institute
whose
stated aim is to promote and legitimize a narrow, controversial (now
largely
discredited by events), ideology-based scholasticism incompatible with
the tradition
of an open university devoted to independent search for truth. At issue
is the
strong influence the Chicago
School
had exerted in recent decades on government policy and corporate
attitude regarding
its faith-based exultation of the alleged merits of market
fundamentalism which
nevertheless has produced glaring, unwholesome results the world over
in the
past two decades.
The Chicago School of Economics is closely identified with vehement
opposition to government intervention in national economies and with
wholesale rejection
of regulation in free markets. Its ideological bend is that on economic
issues,
or even on all issues, the market knows best, based on its attachment
to price
theory. Government intervention, even if well intentioned, is deemed to
always
do more harm than good. The advancement of civilization can be
intermediated
through the price mechanism in free markets. This dogma has been
buttressed by exhaustive
studies of historical data and rationalized with a large reservoir of
path-opening theories to pluck conceptual holes created by
overstretched generalization.
The Chicago School,
a refuge for snubbed market fundamentalists during the Keynesian era,
began to
enjoy broad establishment support after the end of the Cold War, when
the sole
remaining superpower no long needed to win the hearts and minds of the
world by
reining in systemic exploitation of the weak by the strong. The function of government shifted from
protecting the weak from the strong, to freeing the strong to
cannibalize the
weak under the doctrine that survival of the fittest strengthens the
specie.
Economically, the shift began when Milton Friedman became policy
advisor to conservative Republican candidate Barry Goldwater in his
1964 unsuccessful
presidential campaign against liberal Democrat Lyndon Johnson. In his
acceptance speech of the nomination, Goldwater said: “My fellow
Americans, the
tide has been running against freedom. Our people have followed false
prophets.” The highpoint of the speech was: “I would remind you that
extremism
in the defense of liberty is no vice. And let me remind you also that
moderation in the pursuit of justice is no virtue.”
Goldwater attacked Kennedy/Johnson liberalism
as a threat to liberty, in violation of the nominal rules of political
epistemology.
In 1976, Friedman penned an essay that declared: “the Great
Depression was produced by government mismanagement,” ignoring the
historical
fact that government non-interference in the market all through the
post WWI era
produced the stock market frenzy of the Roaring Twenties. At any rate,
both non-intervention
and intervention are government policies, only the former is positive
and the
latter normative.
The market fundamentalist doctrines of the Chicago
School
were enthusiastically
embraced by vested-interest opportunists. At long last, vulture-ism was
sanctified as a positive natural law. Economic oppression through
uneven market
power was redefined as a natural law. The Chicago
School
overnight enjoyed enthusiastic support from the finance sector because
its tilted
theories could be exploited to spectacularly enrich financiers who were
looking
to push the ethical envelope of commerce without government
interference. Transnational
financial institutions and conglomerates used market fundamentalism to
lure Third World policymakers into accepting
neo-imperialism disguised as
neo-liberalism.
The target of Friedman’s evangelical crusade was John
Maynard Keynes and the Keynesians who dominated government policy since
the New
Deal. Actually, both Keynes and Friedman were pro-market economists,
their
difference was that while Keynes proposed to save the market from its
self-destruct
tendencies, Friedman asserted that the market could self-correct with a
simple
governmental monetary policy of focusing on the money supply . Paul
Volcker
tried Friedman’s formula in 1980 with his "new operating method" of
controlling the money supply with sharp interest rate volatility and
almost
caused the Fed to loose control of the Fed funds rate, the most
effective
instrument for controlling the money supply without calling on the
heavy
artillery of the discount rate and bank reserve requirements. Alan
Greenspan also
followed Friedman’s advice of monetarist management of the economy and
set the
global economy on a two-decades-long joy ride of serial bubbles with
his loose
use of liquidity laxative. It landed the world in 2007 in the worse
financial
crisis since the Great Depression. (See my September 14. 2005 AToL
article: Greenspan,
the
Wizard of Bubble Land)
Just as President Nixon declared “We are all Keynesians now”
when he reintroduced wage-price control and decoupled the dollar from
gold in
1971, Larry Summers, Treasury Secretary in the final years of the
Clinton
administration, wrote: “Any honest Democrat will admit that we are now
all
Friedmanites,” in a tribune on Friedman’s death in 2006, when signs of
a
pending collapse of Friedman-esque free market fundamentalism were
already
clearly visible to those who did not operate on a denial mode.
The Chicago School
is strongly identified with monetarism in macroeconomics. Central
Bankers, many
trained by Chicago School
monetarists, became blind-sighted by Friedman. Chicago
School
monetarism enjoyed
respectful awe from central bankers because it provided them with a
simple
formula for handling complex problems, by accepting that inflation is
always
and everywhere monetary phenomenon, which relieved them from the
dilemma of
choosing between full employment and price stability. A natural rate of
unemployment is structural in a market economy and therefore not the
fault of
central bankers. Full employment is not even a policy prerogative of
the
central bank.
Critics have long pointed out that the data behind the Chicago
School
theories are selectively
collected and arranged to support a preconceived ideology, which is
more a vertical
system of beliefs than the outcome of truly open scientific inquiry.
Economics
is a complex subject. Any subject, however complex, if looked at in the
right
way, will become even more complex. On the other hand, if it is looked
at in a simplistic
way, it can lead to convenient but misleading conclusions. This truth
escapes
many experts who tend to avoid small errors meticulously while sweeping
on to grand
fallacy. This was what happened to the Chicago
School
economists.
In his 1953 essay: The
Methodology of Positive Economics, Friedman argues against the
“basic
confusion between descriptive accuracy and analytical relevance that
underlies
most criticisms of economic theory.” The paper asserts that complex
realities
can be scientifically reduced to simple fundamental structures. And the
test of
this hypothesis is its fruits. A theory is the way we perceive “facts”
and we
cannot perceive “facts” without a theory.
David Hume (1711-86) pointed out in his Inquiry into Human
Understanding that since the conclusion of a valid inference could
contain no
information not found in the premise, there could be no valid
conclusion from
observed to unobserved phenomena.
Immanuel Kant (1724-1804) emancipated man’s command of
knowledge from Humean skepticism. In his Critique of Pure Reason
(1781), Kant
emphasized the contribution of the knower to knowledge. While
acknowledging
that the three great issues of metaphysics—God, freedom and
immortality—could
not be logically determined, he asserted that their essence is a
necessary
presupposition. In his subsequent publications, Critique of Practical
Reason
(1788) and Critique of Judgment (1790), Kant asserted as a moral law
his famous
categorical imperative requiring moral actions to be unconditionally
and
universally binding to absolute goodwill.
Goodwill is singularly absent in market
fundamentalism. God
and immortality appeared to have been claimed by some market
fundamentalists on
the basis of their alleged logic on the issue of freedom.
Positive/normative questions are distinguished by the “is/ought”
dichotomy. John Neville Keynes, lesser known father of John Maynard
Keynes,
divided economics into “positive” (the study of “what is”, and the way
the
economy works), “normative” (the study of “what should be”), and the
“art of
economics” (applied economics – how to make “what should be” into “what
is”).
Intervention then is inescapable for progress.
In the same essay on positivism, Friedman tried to deny the
‘is/ought’ dichotomy by arguing that answers to ‘ought’ questions
necessarily
depend on a prior establishment of ‘what is’. Nevertheless, most
critics of
Friedman’s positive methodology feel he was arguing against normative
economics
and thus assume that he was only arguing in favor of positive
economics. Yet “what
is” determines “what ought to be”, reflecting on the value judgment of
the
applied economist. Thus positive methodology must precede normative
prescriptions. But if positive methodology is used to justify “what is”
without
proceeding to “what ought to be”, then positive investigation becomes
superfluous.
The claim of the Chicago School
that prosperity will spring
from markets left free of government interference is challenged by
developing
facts. Recurring financial crises appear to have jelled into a pattern
of
10-year
cycles, as evidenced by the crashes of 1987, 1997 and 2007. By now,
after three
decades of hegemonic dominance in government policy penchant and
private
enterprise philosophy, the Chicago
School
theology can no longer rest on its secure platform of political power
disguised
as theoretical supremacy. The collapse of market fundamentalism in
economies
everywhere is putting the Chicago
School
theology on trial. Its big lie has been exposed by facts on two levels.
The
Chicago Boys’ claim that helping the rich will also help the poor is
not only
exposed as not true, it turns out that market fundamentalism hurts not
only the
poor and the powerless; it hurts everyone, rich and poor, albeit in
different
ways. When wages are kept low to fight inflation, the low-wage regime
causes
overcapacity through over investment from excess profit. And monetary
easing
under such conditions produces hyperinflation that hurts also the rich.
The
fruits of Friedman test are in – and they are all rotten.
The policy ascendance of the Chicago
School
evolved around the core of
macroeconomic monetarism, of which Milton Friedman was the leading
guru. “Money
matters” became its popular slogan. But the slogan is only half true.
Money
matters enough for it to be not just an economic issue; it is an
important political
issue. Students of monetary history know that money has been an issue
of
intense political contention throughout history. For the United
States, a comparative new nation set
on seeking
a new form of government through popular democracy, the issue of money
surfaced
in every chapter of its political history.
But the Chicago School
is more than just a movement of economic theory. In
recent decades, it has become an aggressive
agent of intellectual imperialism, taking on the dusty mantle of social
Darwinism, applying its economic doctrines to other disciplines such as
political science, legal theory, history, sociology, international
relations
and even theology.
Getting rich has become the equivalent of doing god’s work
in market capitalism. Yet many religions consider the attitude toward
money as
often more indicative of a person’s true worth than the mere possession
of it.
The same is true for civilizations. This explains why modern societies,
whose
members would be obsessed with a single-minded quest for material
wealth, would
be constantly faced with recurring crises of values. The pursuit of
maximization of wealth leads inevitably to the betrayal of human values
that
would otherwise forbid unconscionable exploitation of and impersonal
disregard
for others. Human values cannot be intermediated through price, the
infamous
World Bank memo by Larry Summers on the economic efficiency gained by
allocating pollution to the Third World
notwithstanding.
Super-winners in market capitalism are not only respected
and admired for what they do to win in the market but also for their
alleged
wisdom in life. They are sought out constantly for pronouncements on
the great
questions of the age, even those far removed from their fields of
competence.
The University of Chicago historically aimed at encouraging a
community of scholars of varied views and expertise to germinate broad
ideas on
big social problems not by doing timid empirical research on the status
quo, but
by bold new leaps of pure intellect that will be future subjects of
empirical
research, as under the presidencies of education giants such as William
Rainey
Harper and Robert Maynard Hutchins. It
is therefore ironic that it is home to the Chicago School of Economics,
generally viewed as a doctrinal garrison.
In 1856, Democratic Senator Stephen A Douglas, of
Lincoln-Douglas debates fame, who introduced the anti-slavery Freeport
doctrine that permitted the new territories to exclude slavery in the
name of
popular sovereignty, offered a grant of 10 acres of land to
Presbyterians “for
a site for a University in the City of Chicago”.
The elitist Presbyterians declined and the offer fell by default to the
populist
First Baptist Church of Chicago which believed that God’s grace is for
everyone
and not just predestined individuals.
The Baptist trustees relied on the subscriptions of wealthy
Chicagoans to finance the building of the university. However, the
Great Fire
of 1871 and the Panic of 1873 rendered worthless a large proportion of
the
subscriptions that had been secured without conditions. These
calamities left
the university heavily in debt, which it never managed to pay back. The
commencement on June 16, 1886
marked the end of the first University
of Chicago.
To keep the university alive, Baptist trustee Thomas
Goodspeed asked John D Rockefeller, also devout Baptist, who had never
visited Chicago,
for financial support. At the time, Rockefeller was thinking of
creating a
great Baptist university in New York.
After negotiations between New York
and Chicago through the
intermediation
of Baptist clergyman Frederic Taylor Gates and Jewish scholar William
Rainey Harper,
Rockefeller opted for Chicago.
Gates
was a key advisor in convincing Rockefeller of his need for
philanthropy to
develop a social purpose for his enormous wealth and to rebuild the
public
image of his name by supporting projects and institutions devoted to
the public
good.
With the Interstate Commerce Act of 1887 and of the impending
Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890, Chicago
had the advantage of being far from Wall Street and would avoid talks
of a special
relationship between moneyed interests and the new university. The Chicago
School of
economics and the
proposed Milton Friedman Institute seem to have totally overcome such
sensitivity.
In 1890, Rockefeller agreed to donate $600,000 (the
equivalent of $14 million in 2008 dollars – much less than what is
being sought
now for the Milton Friedman Institute) if local Chicagoans could come
up with
another $400,000. Goodspeed turned to Chicago
banker and philanthropist Charles Hutchinson to lead the Chicago
elite to match the Rockefeller condition and the new university was
born.
Merchant Marshall Field donated land for a new campus in Hyde
Park.
Harper was appointed president and opened the new University
of Chicago on October 1, 1892 without
ceremony. He was an
academic prodigy who earned a Ph.D. from Yale when he was eighteen.
Harper, schooled
in Hebrew and biblical studies, commanded linguistic competence in
Aramaic,
Arabic, Syriac and Akkadian. As the
first president of the new university, Harper foresaw a glorious future
for the
University of Chicago, which would destined to rival Ivy League schools
such as
Harvard and Yale, not by copying them but by frog-leaping over them.
Rockefeller
made his first visit to the university only in 1897. The university
eventually grew
into one of the greatest in the world. The University
of Chicago marked the
beginning of
a massive program of Rockefeller philanthropy in education all over the
world.
The final decades of the 19th Century were a turbulent
period for the US
economy. Serial financial panics and agricultural crises appeared
along
the emergence of monopolies that acted as midwives to the birth of the
industrial economy. The concentration of ownership through
predatory finance,
while facilitating spectacular growth, caused public resentment due to
widespread fraud, financial manipulation and labor abuse. Agrarian
crusades and
trade unionism were met with unspeakable violence from capitalists and
management
who hired goons as private security force who literally take the law
into their
own hands. Populist reformers such as Henry George, Bimetal
monetarists,
Progressives, and even Silverite Republicans became active and sought
advice
from progressive economists for conceptual support of their political
positions.
The new University of Chicago, charged with Harper’s vision
of overtaking the Eastern academic power centers, started an aggressive
program
of poaching young rising stars from leading institutions, a strategy
since
copied by all universities of financial means. As practically all
economists of
respectability at the time were in various degree Apologists who
defended the
new industrial capitalism, blemish and all, the University offered
arch-conservative economist J. Laurence Laughlin, who studied under
Charles
Dunbar at Harvard, later dropped out of academia to make a small
fortune in insurance,
then returned to teach at Cornell for two years before the
newly-created University
of Chicago invited him, in 1892, to form its first economics
department. Laughlin
set a tradition for the university by expanding intellectual space and
appointed
several institutionalists, notably his former student at Cornell,
Thorstein Veblen,
to head Chicago’s Journal
of
Political Economy. Theory of
the Leisure Class, a classic critique of consumerism, was written
by Veblen
in Chicago.
Laughlin, himself an avid free-marketeer, along with Frank Taussig
at Harvard, Arthur T. Hadley and social Darwinist William Graham
Sumner,
both at Yale, refused to become members
of the American Economic Association, which had been conceived by the
"new
school" as the US equivalent of the German Verein für
Sozialpolitik,
making the association a stronghold of the emerging institutionalists
by
default. Laughlin’s establishment reputation rests on his work in
monetary economics, as a vocal opponent to bimetallism and an energetic
promoter of central banking.
The American Apologists employed religious and moral
arguments to defend the status quo of industrial capitalism as the working
of “eternal
laws of economics”, god-given and moral, even if not altogether just.
Any attempt
to interfere with it, such as anti-trust legislation or legalized
unions, was
unnatural if not outright immoral, and would eventually spell self
destruction for
the human specie by destroying its survival instinct. Veblen, with
Henry J
Davenport and Frank H Knight, had a grand time making fools of the
Apologists
with their own nonsensical utterances.
Frank H. Knight, known as the "Grand Old Man" of Chicago,
commanded as much respect as Joseph Schumpeter at Harvard. Jointly with
Jacob
Viner, Knight presided over the Department of Economics at the University
of Chicago from the 1920s
to the
late 1940s, and played a central role in setting the character of
the
department. His famous dissertation Risk, Uncertainty and Profit
(1921),
remains one of the most interesting reads in economics, particularly at
this
time. Knight made a distinction between “risk” from randomness with
knowable
probabilities and “uncertainty” resulting from randomness with
unknowable
probabilities, which is now known as Black
Swan Theory
coined by Nassim Nicholas Taleb, brilliant theoretician on
quantitative finance. Frank set forth the role of the entrepreneur in a
distinctive theory of profit and gave one of the earliest presentations
of the famous
law of variable proportions in the theory of production.
Viner was an upside-down Keynesian in that he believed
depressions were due to deflation in output prices occurring at a
faster rate than
the collapse in costs. Recovery, he believed, required a restoration of
profit
margins even if brought about by government-induced inflation, but not
by
monetary expansion or inflation targeting, but rather by deficit fiscal
spending
to create the necessary price rise while costs remain lagging and
profit rises.
Friedman mistakenly described Viner as an early monetarist. The hole in
Viner’s
prescription is that without rising wages and full employment, no
depression can
recover. This is particularly true today when overcapacity is a core
problem. As
Henry Ford discovered, the way to profit is through higher-than-living
wages.
The intellectual thrust of the Chicago
School of
1920-1950 differed
significantly from its later incarnation. Led by Knight, the
School was
highly suspicious of positive economic methodology to study how the
economy works
currently. Faculty members denounced intellectual imperialism, arguing
for a
confined role for economic analysis. They were suspicious of the
efficiency claims of laissez-faire economics, accepting it
only on a
“non-consequential” basis. Efficiency is not contagious; it tends
to
increase through a decrease of efficiency is other areas. The Chicago
Boys of
this era welcomed active government policies to cure recessions
including Henry
Simons’s Chicago Plan for
counter-cyclical monetary policy. On the faculty was Paul Douglas, a
passionate
New Deal liberal, who left to become a US
senator of great influence even in foreign policy. Through the Chicago
School
of Sociology, Douglas developed an intellectual
affinity
with Jane Adams, social reformer and the first American woman to be
awarded the
Nobel Pease Prize. Another member was card-carrying socialist Oskar
Lange who
developed a model for market socialism. Lange was expected to become a
major
figure in the department but instead left Chicago
at the end of World War II to join the new communist government in Poland
and served as its ambassador to the new United Nations.
In the 1960s, the department began to congeal into a new
shape, led by George J. Stigler and Milton Friedman. This is
sometimes
referred to as the Second Chicago
School,
famous for its anti-Keynesian
polemics. It eventually came to be known as the Chicago School of
Economics as the term is understood today. The Stigler-Friedman period
of neoclassical
economics adamantly deny of the possibility of market failure, with
militant hostility
toward imperfect competition in which market entry is restricted such
as in the
case of monopolies. Above all Chicago Boys of this era saw themselves
as
natural born nemeses of Keynesian economics.
The Chicago Boys were outstanding propagandists, making good
use of their two influential journals: the Journal
of Political Economy and the Journal
of Law and Economics. Learning
from the
secular success of
the Manchester School of Economics of free trade from having been
buttressed by
direct British government policy support and industry financial
sponsorship,
the Chicago School focused on building ideological alliance inside
Washington with
conservatives on domestic issues and neo-liberals on international
issues, and
building financial alliances with Wall Street bankers who wanted less
government interference and central banker who wanted simple formulae
that
would absolve them from accountability. These market fundamentalists
hid behind
their vigorous research methodologies to abduct truth as their private
property, notwithstanding other equally vigorous economists were
drawing
diametrically opposing conclusions, albeit less amenable to the moneyed
interests. The Chicago Boys soon captured key posts in the policy
apparatus of
government and power points in business management to avenge their year
in the
wilderness during the Keynesian era. Friedman became the hero of
business when he wrote an article in The New York Times Magazine on
September 13, 1970 with the title: The Social Responsibility of
Business is to Increase Its Profits.
In microeconomics, led by George Stigler the neoclassical
paradigm was extended by incorporating new observations amenable to
economic
analysis, breaking new path with economics interpretations of human
capital,
ownership rights and transaction cost, assigning measurable values to
all
things so that marginal utility could inform decision making. It was an
approach that allowed efficiency to overshadow direction. It did not
matter
where the nation was going as long as it was going there fast and at
lowest
cost. Business and finance, previously the province of trade schools,
were
brought in the intellectual realm philosophy in the university and
incorporated
into neoclassical economics. Corporate planning became indispensable
for
survival and respectable undertakings but national planning was deemed
a threat
to liberty. Profit began to achieve the equivalent status of
immortality. Political
science and institutional theory were restructured to rest on a
financial base
rather an economic foundation, even for national security and
international
relations.
On one level, the Milton Friedman Institute controversy at the University
of Chicago
is a local issue in a private university. But the University
of Chicago is world-class
institution with connections and influence all over the world. What
happens at Chicago
carries wide implications elsewhere in the world. On that level, the
struggle at Chicago
is global. Institutions of
higher learning everywhere are all struggling against the illegitimate
use of
overwhelming, ill-gained financial resources to perpetuate flawed
ideologies
that had rationalized such ill-gains at the expense of the well-being
of
billions all over the world, and to blindly increase the efficiency of
a global
exploitative regime. The problem is especially acute in emerging
economies. The struggle at the University
of Chicago could act as a
beacon
around the world to strip market fundamentalism of its pseudo-science
pretense
and exposed it as a propaganda device to rationalize the exploitation
of the
many by a few the world over.
Professor Lincoln of CORES encourages all who identify with
the aim of the struggle at Chicago
to express their support via its website: http://www.stat.uchicago.edu/~amit/MFI/
as heralds of truth.
September 2, 2008 |