|
Rising Oil Prices
and the Falling Dollar
By
Henry C.K. Liu
This article appeared in AToL as Flat-Earther
Blind to Oil Facts on June 28, 2008
Celebrated New York Times columnist Thomas L. Friedman, a
flat-earthling, in a provocative polemic (Mr. Bush, Lead or Leave, June
22, 2008) accused the president of the United States of being the
nation’s addict-in-chief to oil with “a massive, fraudulent, pathetic
excuse for an energy policy.” He described the
president’s strategy as getting “Saudi Arabia, our chief oil pusher, to
up our dosage for a little while and bring down the oil price just
enough so the renewable energy alternatives can’t totally take off.
Then try to strong arm Congress into lifting the ban on drilling
offshore and in the Arctic National Wildlife Refuge.”
Friedman admits that “we’re going to need oil for years to come.” But
he said that for geopolitical reasons he prefers the US getting as much
oil as possible from domestic wells. He also admits that “our future is
not in oil.” He wants the president to tell the country an allegedly
much larger truth: “Oil is poisoning our climate and our geopolitics,
and here is how we’re going to break our addiction: We’re going to set
a floor price of $4.50 a gallon for gasoline and $100 a barrel for oil.
And that floor price is going to trigger massive investments in
renewable energy — particularly wind, solar panels and solar thermal.
And we’re also going to go on a crash program to dramatically increase
energy efficiency, to drive conservation to a whole new level and to
build more nuclear power. And I want every Democrat and every
Republican to join me in this endeavor.”
Friedman talks as if he wants the president to be an autocratic
dictator. Does Friedman not know that with $4.50 gas and $100 oil, a
large number of working people will not be able to make ends meet with
their current income, or retirees on social security will not be able
to heat their homes this winter? Airlines and other transportation
companies would face bankruptcy? Does he not know that in a democracy,
sustained $100 oil translates into a serious political problem? The oil
problem does not lend itself to simplistic solutions. Yet that is
precisely what our flat-earthling proposes.
Even multinational corporations are being forced to raise prices to
ward off losses from high energy costs. For example, Dow Chemical
(NYSE: DOW) has just announced it will raise the price of its products
by as much as an additional 25% in July, on top of the 20% increase in
June, in an effort to offset the continuing relentless rise in the cost
of energy and hydrocarbon feed stocks. The Company also will implement
a freight surcharge of $300 per shipment by truck and $600 per shipment
by rail, effective August 1, 2008.
Furthermore, Dow is temporarily idling and reducing production at a
number of manufacturing plants, having reduced its ethylene oxide
production worldwide by 25%, and idled 30% of its North America acrylic
acid production. Dow also will idle 40% of its European styrene
production capacity, and has reduced its European polystyrene
production rate by 15%. In light of a sharp decline in auto sales,
Dow’s Automotive unit is announcing a series of cost reduction measures
covering facilities, people and external spending, divesting its paint
shop sealer business and is implementing plant consolidations resulting
in the closure of three production units. In addition, Dow Building
Solutions temporarily idled 20% of its European capacity for producing
STYROFOAM insulation. Earlier this month, Dow announced plans to
idle three Dow Emulsion Polymers plants representing 25% of North
America capacity and 10% of European capacity related to declines in
the housing and consumer sectors, as well as rising costs.
Andrew N. Liveris, Dow chairman and CEO, described the steps as
“extremely unwelcome but entirely unavoidable” as the global cost of
oil, natural gas and hydrocarbon derivatives surge ever higher, despite
company efforts to improve energy efficiency by 22% from 1995 to 2005,
and to target another 25% by 2015, to cut costs significantly, and with
an array of efforts around alternative energy and alternative
feed-stocks. Over the past five years, Dow’s bill for hydrocarbon feed
stocks and energy has surged four-fold, from $8 billion in 2002 to an
estimated $32 billion-plus this year.
General Motors announced plans to close four plants manufacturing
trucks and SUVS, citing decreased sales of large vehicles in the wake
of rising fuel prices. Ford took similar actions. Yet
about 65% of oil consumption is related to transportation, a sector
where alternative fuel technology is relatively easy to tackle, with
alternatives such as electric and substitute fuel engines.
In China, steelmakers were forced to agree to a record increase in
annual iron ore prices in a move likely to boost the cost of cars,
machinery and other products globally. Chinese millers agreed to pay
Anglo-Australian miner Rio Tinto up to 96.5% more for their ore
supplies this year, the largest ever annual increase and ten folds the
9.5% increase paid in 2007, surpassing the record increase of 71.5% in
2005 when the commodities boom
began to gather pace. The development fuels fears that global
commodity-led inflation will continue. Anglo-Australian BHP Billiton,
the world’s largest primary resources company, said the 96.5% record
increase in iron ore cost announced by Rio Tinto was not enough,
signaling it could ask for a rise above 100% with its steelmaker
customers.
In South Korea, Pohang Iron and Steel Company (Posco),
the third largest steel producer in the world, increased prices by up
to 21%, taking the cumulative price inflation to about 60%. German
steelmaking giant Salzgitter A.G, successor company of Reichswerke
Hermann Göring of the Third Reich, also said it would raise prices
by 20%.
In my May 26, 2005 article in Asia Times on Line: The
Real Problem with $50 Oil, I laid out the economics and geopolitics
of oil. The main points are updated below to show the impact of a $100
floor for oil as proposed by Friedman.
It is unfair of Friedman to label Saudi Arabia as “our chief oil
pusher”. Since Arabs are also Semites, one is tempted to point out that
Friedman opens himself to accusations of anti-Semitism when he picks on
Saudi Arabia unfairly.
The world’s oil problem began in 1973 when OPEC, having formed in 1960,
emerged as an effective cartel after the Arab oil embargo against the
US, Western Europe and Japan for supporting Israel in the Yom Kippur
War. The embargo started on October 19, 1973, and ended on March 18,
1974. During that six-month period, the price for benchmark Saudi Light
increased from $2.59 in September 1973 to $11.65 in March 1974. Since
then, OPEC has been setting bottom benchmark prices for its various
kinds of crude oil in the world market, with Saudi Arabia as swing
producer to increase or decrease supply to stabilize prices. To keep
oil price at the $100 floor proposed by Friedman, the cooperation of
Saudi Arabia is needed to reduce production whenever oil price drops
below the $100 floor. By that standard, Saudi Arabia can hardly be
called a “chief oil pusher”.
By 1984, the effects of a decade of higher oil prices had affected US
demand in the form of better insulated homes and more energy-efficient
industrial processes, and in substantial improvement in automobile fuel
efficiency, not to mention new competitive use of cleaner coal, wind
and solar and other alternatives. At the same time, crude-oil
production was increasing throughout the world, stimulated by higher
prices. During this period, OPEC total production stayed relatively
constant, around 30 million barrels per day. However, OPEC’s market
share was decreased from more than 50% in 1974 to 47% in 1979. The OPEC
loss of market share was caused by non-OPEC production increases in the
rest of the world. Higher crude prices caused by OPEC production
sacrifices had made exploration more profitable for everyone, not just
OPEC, and many non-OPEC producers around the world rushed to take
advantage of it, including the US.
Global demand for oil had peaked by 1979 and it became clear that the
only way for OPEC to maintain prices was to reduce production further
to compensate for the high production of non-OPEC producers. OPEC
reduced its total production by a third during the first half of the
1980s. As a result, the cartel’s share in world oil production dropped
below 30%. Non-OPEC producers, including the US, got a big lift from
higher prices, larger market shares, and an expanded definition of
proven reserves which expanded as oil prices rose.
After two decades of high prices, oil dipped below $10 per barrel after
the Asian financial crisis of 1997 as demand fell when the global
economy stalled. After oil prices peaked above US$58 a barrel in early
April, 2005, the White House announced that it wanted oil to go back
down to $25 a barrel. When oil rises above $50 a barrel and stays there
for an extended period, the resultant changes in the economy become
normalized facts. These changes go way beyond fluctuations in the price
of oil to produce a very different economy. I listed in 2005 ten new
economic facts created by $50 oil. I now adjust these facts for $100
oil as proposed by Friedman to see if his proposal makes sense. The key
fact is that while $100 oil may stimulate development of alternative
energy modes, such development cannot be expected to bring oil price
back down, or the stimulated alternative energy sector will go
bankrupt. While there is no known solution to the oil problem that will
lead to lower oil prices short of a global recession, $100 oil is not
without problems.
Fact 1: Oil-related
transactions involving the same material quantity involve greater cash
flow, with each barrel of oil generating $100 instead of $25. The
United States consumed in 2007 about 22 million barrels of oil each
day, about 25% of world consumption of 87 million barrels. China
consumes 7.3 million barrels per day. Yet daily world production is
only about 85 million barrels, leaving a deficit of 2 million barrels
which are being made up from inventory. This fact is the fundamental
reason why oil prices have risen. It can be expected that production
will increase as a result of high prices to remove the supply deficit.
US consumption has been fairly constant in the past few years. About
10.2 million barrels were imports and only 5.5 million barrels from
OPEC. At $100 a barrel, the aggregate oil bill for the US comes to $2
billion a day, $730 billion a year, about 5.6% of 2007 US gross
domestic product (GDP). About 50% of US consumption is imported at a
cost of $1 billion a day, or $365 billion a year. Oil and gas import is
the single largest component in the US trade deficit, not imports from
Japan or China.
As oil prices rise, consumers pay more for heating oil and gasoline,
truckers pay more for diesel, airlines pay more for jet fuel, utility
companies pay more for fuel as coal price rose with oil prices,
petrochemical companies pay more for raw material, and the whole
economy pays more for electricity. Now those extra payments do not
disappear into a black hole in the universe. They go into someone’s
pocket as revenue and translate into profits for some businesses and
losses for others. In other words, higher energy prices do not take
money out of the economy, they merely shift profit allocation from one
business sector to another. More than $365 billion a year goes to
foreign oil producers who then must recycle their oil dollars back into
US Treasury bonds or other dollar assets, as part of the rules of the
game of dollar hegemony. The simple fact is that a rise in monetary
value of assets adds to the monetary wealth of the economy.
Fact 2: Since energy
is a basic commodity and oil is a predominant energy source, high
energy cost translates into a high cost of living, which can result in
a lower standard of living unless income can keep up. High energy cost
translates into reduced consumption in other sectors unless higher
income can be generated from the increased cash flow. Unfortunately,
pay raises typically have a long time lag behind price increases.
Higher prices translate into higher aggregate revenue for the economy
and explain why corporate profit is up even when consumer discretionary
spending slows. A large part of the oil problem comes from the fact
that higher corporate revenue from rising prices has failed to
translate into higher wages.
Fact 3: As cash flow
increases for the same amount of material activities, the GDP rises
while the economy stagnates from wage depreciation. Companies are
buying and selling the same amount or maybe even less, but at a higher
price and profit margin and with employees at lower pay per unit of
revenue. As oil price rose within a decade from about $10 a barrel to
$150, a 15-fold increase, those who owned oil reserves see their asset
value increase also 15 folds. Those who do not own oil reserves protect
themselves with hedges in the rapidly expanding structured finance
world. Since GDP is a generally accepted measure of economic health,
the US economy then is judged to be growing at a very acceptable rate
while running in place or even backwards. There is an expanding oil
bubble, albeit smaller than the recently collapsed housing bubble, if
one understands that a bubble is defined as a price regime that has
risen beyond an economy’s ability to sustain it with compensatory
income from wages.
Fact 4: With asset value ballooning from the
impact of a sharp rise in energy prices, which in turn leads the entire
commodity-led price chain in an upward spiral, the economy can carry
more debt without increasing its debt-to-equity ratio, giving
much-craved support to the residual debt bubble that began to burst
before oil prices began to rise. Since the monetary value of assets
tends to rise in tandem over time, the net effect is a de facto
depreciation of money, misidentified as growth.
Fact 5: High oil
prices threaten the economic viability of some commercial sectors, such
as airlines, trucking and motor vehicles, which have exhausted their
price elasticity. These sectors cannot pass on increased cost without
causing their sales volume to fall. Detroit, namely Ford and General
Motors, with their most profitable models being the gas-guzzling trucks
and sport utility vehicles (SUVs) that can now take more than $300 to
fill their tanks, are going down the same distress route as their
under-funded pension obligations.
Fact 6: Industrial plastics, the materials
most in demand in modern manufacturing, more than steel or cement, are
all derived from oil. Higher prices of industrial plastics will mean
lower wages for workers who assemble them into products. But even steel
and cement require energy to produce and their prices will also go up
along with oil prices. While low Asian wages are keeping global
inflation in check through cross-border wage arbitrage, rising energy
prices are the unrelenting factor behind global inflation that no
interest-rate policy from any central bank can contain. Ironically,
from a central bank's perspective, a commodity-led asset appreciation,
which central banks do not define as inflation, is the best cure for a
debt bubble that the central banks themselves created with their loose
money policies. Since most assets are exponentially larger than the
rate of consumption, the wealth effect of higher asset value can
neutralize the rise in consumer prices. This is the key reason why
central banks are not sensitive to the need to keep wages rising.
The monetary system is structured to work
against wage earners who do not own substantial assets.
Fact 7: War-making is
a gluttonous oil consumer. With high oil prices, America’s wars will
carry a higher price, which will either lead to a higher federal budget
deficit, or lower social spending, or both. This translates into rising
dollar interest rates, which is structurally recessionary for the
globalized economy operating under dollar hegemony. But while war is
relentlessly inflationary, war spending is an economic stimulant, at
least as long as collateral damage from war occurs only on foreign
soil. War profits are always good for business, and the need for
soldiers reduces unemployment. Fighting for oil faces little popular
opposition at home, even though for the United States the need for oil
is not a credible justification for war. The fact of the matter is that
the US already controls most of the world's oil without war, by virtue
of oil being denominated in dollars that the US can print at will with
little penalty. Petro-war is launched to protect dollar hegemony which
requires oil to be denominated in dollars, not physical access to oil.
Much anti-war posturing in an election year is merely campaign
rhetoric. Military solutions to geopolitical problems arising from
political economy will remain operative options for the US regardless
who happens to be the occupant of the White House, populist or not.
Fact 8: There is a
supply/demand myth that if oil prices rise, they will attract more
exploration for new oil, which will bring prices back down in time.
This was true in the good old days when oil in the ground stayed a
dormant financial asset. But now, as explained by Facts 3 and 4 above,
in a debt bubble, oil in the ground can be more valuable than oil above
ground because it can serve as a monetizable asset of rising value
through asset-backed securities (ABS) in the wild, wild world of
structured finance (derivatives). So while there is incentive to find
more oil reserves to enlarge the asset base, there is little incentive
to pump it out of the ground merely to keep prices low.
Gasoline prices also will not come down, not because there is a
shortage of crude oil, but because there is a shortage of refinery
capacity. The refinery deficiency is created by the appearance of
gas-guzzlers that Detroit pushed on the consuming public when gasoline
at less than a $1 a gallon was cheaper than bottled water. Refineries
are among the most capital-intensive investments, with nightmarish
regulatory hurdles. Refineries need to be located where the demand for
gasoline is, but families that own three cars do not want to live near
a refinery. Thus there is no incentive to expand refinery capacity to
bring gasoline prices down because the return on new investment will
need high gasoline prices to pay for it. After all, as Friedman
tirelessly reminds us, the market is not a charity organization for the
promotion of human welfare. It is a place where investors try to get
the highest price for products to repay their investment with highest
profit. It is not the nature of the market to reduce the price of
output from investment so that consumers can drive gas-guzzling SUVs
that burn most of their fuel sitting in traffic jams on freeways.
Fact 9: According to
the US Geological Survey, the Middle East has only half to one-third of
known world oil reserves. There is a large supply of oil elsewhere in
the world that would be available at higher but still economically
viable prices. The idea that only the Middle East has the key to the
world’s energy future is flawed and is geopolitically hazardous.
The United States has large proven oil reserves that get larger with
rising oil price. Proven reserves of oil are generally taken to be
those quantities that geological and engineering information indicates
with reasonable certainty can be recovered in the future from known
reservoirs under existing economic and geological conditions. According
to the Energy Information Administration (EIA), the US had 21.8 billion
barrels of proven oil reserves as of January 1, 2001, twelfth-highest
in the world, when oil price was around $20 per barrel. These reserves
are concentrated overwhelmingly (more than 80%) in four states - Texas
(25%, including the state's reserves in the Gulf of Mexico), Alaska
(24%), California (21%), and Louisiana (14%, including the state's
reserves in the Gulf of Mexico).
US proven oil reserves had declined by about 20% since 1990, with the
largest single-year decline (1.6 billion barrels) occurring in 1991.
But this was due mostly to the falling price of oil, which shrank
proven reserves by definition. At $100 a barrel, the reserve numbers
can be expected to expand greatly. The reason the US imports oil is
that importing is cheaper and cleaner than extracting domestic oil. At
a certain price level, the US may find it more economic to develop more
domestic oil instead of importing, but the formula depends more on
price gap between import and domestic oil which in a global market is
not expected to stay wide for long. The idea of achieving oil
independence as a strategy for cheap oil is unworthy of serious
discussion.
The economics of petroleum is as important as geology in coming up with
reserve estimates since a proven reserve is one that can be developed
economically. But it is important to remember that political economy
extends beyond the supply and demand fixation of market
fundamentalists. If the Middle East and the Persian Gulf implode
geopolitically and oil from this region stops flowing, the US, as an
oil producer will be a main beneficiary of $50 oil, or $100 oil, or
even $1,000 oil, as would Britain with its North Sea oil and countries
such as Norway, Indonesia, Nigeria and Venezuela. But the biggest
winner will be Russia. For China, it would be a wash, because China
currently imports energy not for domestic consumption, but to fuel its
growing export machine, and can pass on the added cost to foreign
buyers. In fact, the likelihood of the US bartering below-market Texas
crude for low-cost Chinese manufactured goods is very real possibility
in the future. Similar bilateral arrangements between China-Russia,
China-Middle East/Gulf, China-Nigeria, China-Venezuela and
China-Indonesia are also good prospects. Also, China’s off-shore
reserves have so far stayed largely undeveloped.
Fact 10: Fifty dollar
oil bought the US debt bubble a little more time, but bubbles never
last forever and it burst in August 2007. But in a democracy, the White
House in 2005 was under pressure from a misinformed public to bring the
oil price back down to $25, not realizing that the price for cheap oil
could accelerate the bursting of the debt bubble. Despite all the
grandstand warnings about the need to reduce the US trade deficit, a
case can be made with ease that the United States cannot drastically
reduce its trade deficit without paying the price of a sharp recession
that could trigger a global depression.
The Economics of Oil
Since the discovery of petroleum, its economics has never been about
cutting a square deal for the consumer, corporate or individual, let
alone the little guys or the working poor. It has to do with squeezing
the most financial value out of this black gold.
John D Rockefeller consolidated the US oil industry into a monopoly by
eliminating chaotic competition to keep the price high, not to push
prices down. Neo-classical economics views higher prices of consumables
as inflation, but asset appreciation is viewed as growth, not
inflation. Since oil is both an asset and a consumable commodity,
neo-classical economics faces a dilemma in oil economics. The size of
oil reserves is exponentially greater than the annual flow of oil to
the market. What is even more fundamental is that as the flow of oil to
the market decreases, the price of oil goes up, enlarging proven
reserves by definition. Thus while a rise in the market price of oil
adds to inflation, the corresponding rise of the asset value and size
of oil reserves create a wealth effect that more than neutralizes the
inflationary impact of market oil prices. The world should not care
about an few added percentage points in inflation if the world’s assets
would appreciate 100% as a result, except that when oil is not owned
equally among the world’s population, a conflict emerges between
consumers and producers, making oil a domestic political and
geopolitical problem.
In fact, on an aggregate basis, cheap oil can have a deflationary
impact on the economy by reducing the wealth effect of all assets. For
the US economy, since the United States is a major possessor of oil
assets, both on- and off-shore, high oil prices are in the national
interest. What we have is not an inflation problem in rising oil
prices, but a pricing problem that distributes unevenly the benefits
and pains of price adjustments among oil owners and oil consumers, both
domestically and internationally. This is a political problem.
Politicians are under populist pressure to keep oil prices low when the
solution is to equalize the benefits and pain of high oil prices.
Oil Price and Monetary Policy
Failure by the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) to
cut production at its meeting in November 1998 prompted prices to
collapse to a 12-year low of $10.35 a barrel in New York the following
month. A combination of excess production, rising inventories and poor
demand for winter heating fuels pushed prices down. In March 1999, oil
prices climbed 17%, going higher as oil-producing countries, unified by
low prices, succeed in cutting output. Oil prices began making a sharp
recovery in the late winter of 1999, rising from the low teens at the
beginning of the year to more than $22 a barrel by the early autumn,
and crossed $30 a barrel in mid-February 2000. A major cause was
production cuts settled upon in March 1999 by OPEC and other major
oil-exporting nations.
On March 12, 1999, St Louis Federal Reserve Bank president William
Poole said in a speech that the growth of the US money supply, which
was then at more than 8% when inflation was below 2% annually, was “a
source of concern” because it outpaced the rate of inflation. The M2
money supply had been growing at an 8.6% annual rate for the previous
52 weeks to keep the economy from stalling before the 2000 election.
The US Federal Reserve was also watching the rate of inflation, held
down mostly by low oil prices.
Poole warned that “we cannot continue to rely on the decline of oil
prices at the [low] pace of the last couple of years.” He said
investors who had pushed bond yields to their highest level in six
months were correct in assuming the Fed’s next move would be to
increase interest rates. The Fed Open Market Committee (FOMC), when it
met on February 2, 1999, had left the Fed Funds rate (FFR) target
unchanged at 4.75%. Poole voted in 1998 for the FOMC to cut the FFR
target three times between September and November to 4.75% when oil was
at $12.
Today, with oil at around $135, the FFR target is 2% effective since
April 30, 2008. On June 25, the Fed opted for keeping the Fed funds
rate target unchanged. In its statement, the Fed Open Market Committee
(FOMC) said: “Tight credit conditions, the ongoing housing contraction,
and the rise in energy prices are likely to weigh on economic growth
over the next few quarters.”
Annualized growth rate for M2 in Q4 2007 was 6.8%, with a Fed funds
rate target of 2%, as compared with the 1999 M2 growth rate of 8.6%
against a Fed funds rate target of 4.75% in response to fallouts from
the 1997 Asian Financial Crisis. However, in the past seven quarters
before end of 2007, V2 (the velocity of M2) declined by 2.3% annum
rate, causing GDP growth to decelerate from 3.5% to 2.2%. GDP growth
for Q1 2008 was 0.6% which justified a 2% Fed funds rate target.
Yet if the Fed is really concerned with fighting inflation expectation,
$135 oil and 2% Fed funds rate target simply do not mix, even with a
falling money-supply growth rate. There is strong evidence that instead
of worrying about inflation expectation, the Fed is really more worried
about the economic debris from the burst debt bubble, which stealth
inflation through asset appreciation is expected to help clean up with
less pain. If high oil prices are the handiwork of speculators, the Fed
is the speculator-in-chief. But there is very little speculation in the
oil market because hedging is not speculation as all competent market
analysts know. The rise in oil price is the direct result of a
debasement of money coordinated by the world’s central banks led by the
Fed.
In July 1993, when the US economy had been growing for more than two
years from M2 growth of over 6%, Fed chairman Alan Greenspan remarked
in congressional testimony that “if the historical relationships
between M2 and nominal income had remained intact, the behavior of M2
in recent years would have been consistent with an economy in severe
contraction.” With the M2 growth rate down to 1.44% in July 1993,
Greenspan said, “The historical relationships between money and income,
and between money and the price level, have largely broken down,
depriving the aggregates of much of their usefulness as guides to
policy. At least for the time being, M2 has been downgraded as a
reliable indicator of financial conditions in the economy, and no
single variable has yet been identified to take its place.”
Yet M2, adjusted for changes in the price level, remains a component of
the Index of Leading Economic Indicators, which some market analysts
use to forecast economic recessions and recoveries. A positive
correlation between money-supply growth and economic growth exists only
on inflation-adjusted M2 growth, and only if the new money goes into
new investment rather than as debt to support speculation on rising
asset prices. Sustainable economic expansions are based on real
production, not on speculative debt.
In 2004, longer-term interest rates actually declined
from their June high of 4.82% to 4.20% at year-end even as short-term
rates rose in a “measured pace” to 2.25% in December 2004 (from all
time low of 1% in June 2003 to 5.5% in June 2006), with the 2004 money
supply growing at a 5.67% annual rate. This reflected a credit market
unconcerned with long-term inflation despite a sinking US dollar and
oil prices rising above $50 a barrel. The reason is that $50 oil raised
asset value at a faster pace than price inflation of commodities. $100
oil only doubles the impact.
In March 2000, OPEC punctured the Greenspan easy-money bubble by
reversing the fall of oil prices. The FOMC was forced to respond to the
change in the rate of inflation, no longer being held down by declines
in oil prices. Because the easy money had stimulated only speculation
that did not produce any real growth, the easy-money bubble of 2000
evolved into the next debt-driven asset bubble in housing that burst in
August 2007. The smart money realized in 2000 that the market’s march
toward $50 oil was on, as the smart money realized in 2007 that the
march towards $150 oil was on. And in 2005, $50 oil appeared to be
giving Greenspan’s debt-driven asset bubble a second life, most of
which ended in the real-estate/housing sector. If oil should fall back
to $25 a barrel as the White House wanted, the debt-driven asset bubble
would have popped with a bang.
As it turned out, the housing bubble burst from a credit collapse in
August 2007 that the Fed under Bernanke tried to bail out with massive
liquidity injection and oil went on to $130. The Fed now appears to be
assuming that oil prices will soon subside, based in large part on
information on futures prices. Yet there are limits to the extent to
which futures prices can indicate price trends, since arbitrage
prevents them from moving very far out of line with current prices.
There was solid evidence that the 1970s recycling of petrodollars,
which mostly ended up in the dollar assets in the United States anyway,
contributed to US inflation as much as the higher retail price of
gasoline. It in essence siphoned off additional global funds to
purchase higher-priced oil for investment in US real estate, which was
the only sector the then unsophisticated Arab money managers thought
they knew enough about to handle. By the 1990s, they were more
sophisticated. Some had expected that a new injection of petrodollars
would sustain the collapsing “new economy” equity market of the 1990s.
It did not work because, even at $35, oil was still behind its pre-1973
price relative to the peak Nasdaq in June 1999, the equivalent of which
would bring $120 oil.
The drop in oil prices after 1997 was mostly a cyclical effect of the
drastic reduction of demand from the Asian financial crisis, which
impacted the whole world. There was zero pressure even in the US to
raise oil prices at that time, because of the effect they had on
keeping easy-money inflation low. Even oil companies were not really
upset by this temporary condition because, until oil prices dropped
below $7 per barrel, it was not a big deal since that was the offshore
production cost in the North Sea. The wellhead cost on land was less
than $4 per barrel, plus market-induced leasehold costs. North Sea oil
was higher because of fixed offshore drilling investments. In 1998, oil
could stay at anywhere above $7 for quite a few years without doing any
lasting harm to the US or Europe. It was widely expected to go back up
to $35 by the end of 2000, and a lot of people would get rich in the
process. OPEC was touting the line of argument that high prices would
stimulate new exploration to get the non-OPEC consumers to accept
costlier oil. In the long run, less new exploration would be good for
OPEC. Before 1973, the whole world was happy with $3 oil. As for the
US, cheap oil kept inflation (as measured by the Fed) low, the dollar
high and dollar interest rates low. These benefits outweighed the
oil-sector problems created by a collapse in oil prices. In oil, no one
has told the truth for more than 80 years, or since its discovery.
The problem with cheap oil
It is often overlooked that the United States is a major oil producer.
In fact, before the discovery of oil in the Middle East in the 1930s,
the US was the world’s biggest exporter of oil. “Oil for the lamps of
China” was a slogan of the Standard Oil monopoly. It is not clear that
cheap oil is in the national interest of the US. Cheap oil distorts the
US economy in unconstructive ways. In recent years of cheap oil,
advances in conservation have all been abandoned. Until this year, US
consumers were buying eight-cylinder SUVs with 400 horsepower that
deliver only six miles per gallon in urban traffic, as well as
air-conditioned convertibles. Even with $4 gasoline, commuters face
only a $1,000 annual increase in their gas bills. Vehicle prices have
risen faster than gasoline prices in recent decades. Of course, the
rest of the world outside the US has been operating on $4 gasoline for
a long time.
Hundred-dollar oil is not an economic disaster but it is a political
problem. Hundred-dollar oil needs not be damaging to the global
economy, but it nevertheless forces a restructuring of the global
economy in ways that have political reverberations. To begin with, $100
oil will in the long run stimulate more exploration and production, and
reactivate idle wells that are uneconomic at $10 per barrel. It will
also make alternative energy economically more viable. Also the global
economy is growing more energy-efficient with new technology and the
effect of oil price on the economy is much less than in the 1970s. And
$100 oil will prevent a return to the era of abusive waste of energy
caused by excessively low oil prices. Just as low wages encourage
misuse of labor, unreasonably low oil cost creates incentives for
misuse of energy and discourages the search for alternative energy
sources.
The only trouble is that $100 oil takes money from the pocket of
consumers and delivers it to the oil producers (not just Arabs), who
then reinvest it in Wall Street. The net result is a transfer of wealth
from the “working families” of the world to the capitalists the world
over. Consumer demand will shift, with more money spent on fuel and
utilities and less for other types of consumption that improve the
standard of living, but equity prices will rise because there will be
more dollars chasing the same number of shares. What is more troubling
is that the appreciation of the resultant enlarged proven oil reserves
will fuel more debt at the same debt-to-equity ratio. The current
structure of the overcapacity economy is such that more debt can only
go to support consumption and speculative, not productive, investment,
causing a new unsustainable debt bubble.
A reduction of oil taxes will leave more money in
consumers’ pockets. Governments can make up the resultant tax shortfall
by increasing tax rates on oil-asset appreciation - perhaps, in the
case of the United States, to fund the coming Social Security
shortfall. But governments tend to resist fuel-tax reduction because of
the flawed ideology that fuel taxes encourage conservation.
Capital-gain tax measures are resisted on the doctrine that what hurts
capital hurts the poor also, if not more. This ideological fixation is
increasingly inoperative in a world saddled with overcapacity and
widening income disparity. Any development that reduces demand is
deadly for the current global economic structure. Therein lies the key
issue of the coming oil crisis - ballooned equity prices unsupported by
wage income and a dampening of consumer demand due to high prices. The
world enjoyed a boom from $10 oil for a decade. During that boom,
income disparity increased both domestically and globally. Now, a
return to operative market price for oil should not be allowed to
continue this trend of widening income disparity.
I wrote in 2005: “We now appear to be heading toward a replay of the
early 1980s when a widening trade deficit and a precipitous fall of the
dollar triggered the 1987 collapse of the equity markets. Greenspan’s
strategy of reducing market regulation by substituting it with crisis
intervention is merely swapping the extension of the boom for increased
severity of the bust down the road. Greenspan appears to be looking to
$50 oil to sustain his debt bubble. While $50 oil is not a problem in
the long run, it could give Greenspan a super-size headache if it
serves merely to fuel more debt. Greenspan started his tenure at the
Fed with a market crash. Will the wizard of irrational exuberance end
his tenure with another market crash?” My question was answered two
years later by the 1997 credit crisis which even the Fed now is saying
the market would not see a bottom until the end of 2009.
June 25, 2008
|
|
|
|
|