The Shape of US
Populism
By
Henry C.K. Liu
Part I: Legacy of
Free Market Capitalism
Part II: Long-term
Effects of the Civil War
Part
III: The Progrssive Era
Part IV: A Panic-Stricken
Federal Reserve
Part V: The Great
Depression, the New Deal and the 2007 Credit Crisis
This article appeared in AToL
on May 21, 2008
More than two years after the
October 1929 stock market
crash, a commission originally established by the Republican-chaired
Senate
Banking and Currency Committee to prepare official
Republican
defense for the upcoming presidential election finally began hearings
in March,
1932 in the depth of the
ensuring
depression to examine the causes of the market crash and to recommend
reforms
to prevent future recurrences. During the eight months
leading
up to the 1932 presidential election in November, with an upsurge of
populist
sentiments caused by two years of severe economic pain, Democrats
predictably
criticized the original commission for whitewashing Republican policy
responsibility in
causing the financial crisis and in failing to prevent the market crash
from
turning into the resultant economic depression.
The political dynamics in 1932 has similarities
with that of
the upcoming 2008 presidential election in the aftermath of the credit
market
crisis that broke out in August 2007. The main difference between 1932
and 2008
is that, unlike in 1932 when Democrats could disclaim policy
responsibility for
the 1929 crash, they cannot deny in 2008 the policy responsibility of
the
two-term Clinton
administration
(1993-2001) for the credit bubble that burst in 2007. Another
difference is
that the full impact of the final bursting of the serial bubbles would
not be
fully felt until after the 2008 election. The 1932 election was held in
the
midst of a severe depression.
The Implosion of
Rubinomics
It was Robert Rubin, special economic assistant to President
Clinton and later Treasury Secretary, who worked out what has come to
be known
as Rubinomics, the strategy of dollar hegemony through the promotion of
unregulated globalization of financial markets based on a fiat dollar
that also
forced deregulation on the US
financial market. See my April
11, 2002 AToL article: Dollar Hegemony.
The argument that financial market regulation would reduce
US competitiveness because it would force US financial institutions to
relocate
overseas had assumed an air of immaculate logic in the ideological
context of
neo-liberal globalization during the Clinton years. That neo-liberal
mentality
set the stage for US
government abdication of regulatory responsibility over the financial
sector
and allowed the free market to move towards the inescapable path of
eventual
self-destruction, despite historical experience of the Roaring Twenties
and the
New Deal having shown the need for regulation to rein in the suicidal
excesses
of financial free markets.
The neo-liberal strategy was set in motion with the help of
an ever-accommodating Federal Reserve to supply more liquidity to foil
even the
slightest stock market correction on what Fed chairman Alan Greenspan
observed
as “irrational exuberance”. Since for almost two decades the finance
sector had
grown faster than the real economy, most of the excess liquidity
injected by
the Fed went to develop serial debt bubbles that simply got bigger and
bigger
each time through financial innovations. These ever bigger bubbles were
generated by increasingly sophisticated and complex debt instruments
that
carried synthetic credit ratings structured in linked hierarchies of
risk
exposures and marketed worldwide as “safe” investments to supposedly
nondiscretionary conservative institutional investors managing money of
clients
who normally were not in any position to take such risks. Such triple-A
rated
“safe” investment-grade instruments were theoretically protected by a
solid
base of large number of dispensable financial frontline yeomen
instruments. The
structured finance regime nevertheless mandates that when enough of the
frontline yeomen die, the lords who depend on a tolerable yeomen
survival rate
for protection also fall into jeopardy.
Both the Greenspan Fed
and the Clinton Treasury Injected Excessive Cash into the
Bubble Economy
Through much of the Clinton
administration, the Greenspan Fed kept short-term interest rate too low
for too
long for a healthy economy, notwithstanding the alleged safety provided
by
sophisticated hedging of risks. Towards the end of the Clinton
presidency, an
abnormal term structure on interest rates was created in early 2000 by
the
Greenspan Fed finally raising short-term Fed funds rate targets to
fight
inflation while the Treasury under Larry Summers was pushing down
long-term
rates by buying back 30-year Treasury bonds with funds from a Federal
budget
surplus derived from a debt bubble, flooding the market with excessive
cash.
Silly Talks of the
End of the Business Cycle and the Goldilocks Economy
As all market participants know, an inverted rate curve is a
classic signal for recession down the road. Yet silly talk of the “end
of the
business cycle” was extravagantly entertained by neo-liberal government
economists, along with silly talk of the “end of history” by
neo-conservative
superpower strategists. The so-called “goldilocks” economy fantasy of
not too
hot, not too cold, but just right, was born, along with the superpower
fantasy
that goldilocks will pay for costly foreign wars of moral imperialism
around
the world without hurting the domestic economy. Goldilocks was called
upon to
provide the US
with both guns and butter.
George W Bush won the November 2000 presidential election
along with the bursting of the Clinton
debt bubble. The Greenspan Fed again came to the rescue by turning on
the fiat
money spigot to fund a housing bubble mistaken as a miraculous boom,
applauded
by a grateful Congress overtaken with unquestioning awe and blind
adulation
normally reserved only for living gods. See my February 24, 2004 article in AToL: The
Presidential Election Cycle Theory and
the Fed.
The policy of moral
imperialism brought spectacular
terrorist attacks on the US homeland, forcing the Bush administration,
less
than nine months in office, to turn Clinton’s foreign war of moral
imperialism
into a global war on terrorism that some have estimated will cost up to
$2
trillion or 20% of US GDP, a cost even a goldilocks economy cannot
afford. The
9-11 2001 terrorist attacks on the US homeland gave
the Fed a convenient excuse to flood the market with massive liquidity.
The
goldilocks economy got a new lease on life from the global war on
terrorism,
allowing structured finance to blossom as a regime of global financial
terror.
The destruction of 911 goes pale against the still unfolding
destruction of the
2007 credit crunch.
The Political
Repercussions of the Great Depression
Back in the 1930’s, the Great Depression that followed the
1929 market crash had direct political repercussions. In the 1930
mid-term elections,
the Democrats gained control of Congress, and in 1932, Democratic
candidate
Franklin D. Roosevelt was easily elected president over Republican
incumbent
Herbert Hoover, carrying over 40 states. The Democrats finally gained
control
of both Congress and the Executive Branch after more than a decade of
Republican rule.
Findings of Pecora
Commission
The new Democratic chairman of the Senate Banking and
Currency Committee, Senator Duncan U. Fletcher of Florida,
immediately dismissed the Republican general counsel of the Commission
on the
1929 Crash and appointed as replacement Ferdinand Pecora, an assistant
district
attorney for New York.
Known
thereafter as the Pecora Commission, its new investigation after 1930
revealed
a host of conflicts of interest in the financial sector in the years
leading up
to the 1929 crash, such as bank underwriting of unsound securities to
save near
non-performing bank loans, rampant insider trading and “pool
operations” by
speculators banding together to move a stock and to close out the pool
at peak
price for profit, leaving the manipulated public with subsequent
losses.
More shocking still, the Pecora Commission uncovered the
embarrassing fact that JP Morgan and his fellow banking titans not only
continued to reap huge profit from rescuing firms they helped put in
distress
while the economy fell into severe depression, but they were also able
to avoid
paying any income tax in 1931 and 1932 through tax loopholes on paper
losses of
distressed companies they acquired. These bankers were in fact buying
up a
country in economic distress with their tax deductions.
Revival of Populism:
Henry George and the Single Land Tax
The excesses of the Roaring Twenties revived populist calls
for reform and even radical demands for revolutionary systems of
taxation. The Robert
Schalkenbach Foundation (RSF) was organized in 1925 to promote public
awareness
of the social philosophy and economic reforms advocated by Henry George
(1839-1897), centering around the “single tax on land values” first published in The
Christian Advocate in
1890. The Henry George
Foundation of America
was formed in 1926 as a non-profit entity by some of the leading
luminaries of
the progressive wing of the Democratic Party in Pittsburgh,
Pennsylvania.
According to the RSF web site, “George began with the
ethical premise that all people have an equal right to the use of the
earth.
From that he concluded that exclusive private ownership of land
(natural
resources) creates unwarranted special privileges. Furthermore, he
observed
that holding land out of production drives down [both] real wages and
returns
to capital equipment [as distinct from capital per se]. This
process is
further exacerbated by taxes on production and income that 1) increase
unemployment, 2) discourage productive investment, and 3) encourage
unproductive land speculation and rent-seeking. To counteract
this
self-destructive system, George advocated shifting taxes from labor and
capital
onto the value of land and natural resources.”
Riding on a wave of populism, George ran, though
unsuccessfully, twice for mayor of New York,
the first run in 1886 when he came in second ahead of a young Theodore
Roosevelt. George died in the midst of his second run in 1897 at
age 64.
Between elections, he traveled around the world promoting his vision of
economic justice, influencing many reformers. In pre-revolution Russia,
George’s ideas were popularized by Leo Tolstoy, and in China
by Sun Yatsen, the leader of the revolution that overthrew in 1911 the
267-year-old Qing dynasty. George’s grand daughter was the
celebrated American choreographer Agnes
George de Mille.
Socio-Economic Darwinism
The 1920’s were a time of revival for 1860’s socio-economic
Darwinism manifesting itself through laissez-faire
market capitalism which condones no-holds-barred competitiveness not
just for
economic growth but for corporate survival. It denied the early
American
communal spirit of cooperation. Big business adopted the “survival of
the
fittest” theme of English sociologist Herbert Spencer and Yale
professor
William Graham Sumner with self-righteous morality. Yet survival of
the
fittest among the animal kingdom is practiced only between species,
while
intra-specie cooperation is the general law. The symbiotic
interdependence of different
species is well recognized in all ecological systems. Moreover, the laissez-faire market system is far from
a natural phenomenon, but a contrived mechanism with the purpose of
reconciling
individual pursuit of self interest with the welfare of society. It was
becoming clear that this reconciliation was again failing in the 1920s
and it
had been in the 1860s.
Other Populist Voices:
Ward, Veblen and Bellamy
Reacting against economic individualism, other populist
voices beside Henry George included Lester Frank Ward (1841-1913),
Thorstein
Veblen (1857-1929) and Edward Bellamy (1850-1898).
Ward asserts that man should use his
intelligence to control and direct his future, making a distinction
between the
“telic” and the “genetic”, insisting that there is “no natural harmony
between
natural law and human advantage.” Thus laissez-faire
market capitalism does not necessarily promote human progress, and when
it runs
amuck, could pervert economic progress to reverse human progress in
civilization. Ward’s views paved the way to positive socio-economic
planning by
government that the Progressive and the New Dealers promoted.
Veblen published The
Theory of the Leisure Class in 1899 in which he separates industry,
the
production of wealth, from business, the acquisition of wealth. Veblen
coined
the term “robber Baron” to describe the titans of business in the 1860s
and
also the term “conspicuous consumption” to describe the behavioral
pattern of
the nouveau riches.
Bellamy advocated a state socialism based on Christian
ethics. His best-selling utopian novel: Looking
Backward, became influential and sparked the formation of the
“Nationalist”
political movement and several accompanying utopian living experiments
during
the 1890's. By late 1888, the first of the Bellamy Nationalist Clubs
was formed
and the movement soon spread across the country. The main purpose of
the clubs
was to create and promote the practical realization of Bellamy’s
utopian
vision. Members became involved with other reform political groups and
the
Nationalists were represented at the 1891 Populist Party convention.
Eugene
Debs, the up and coming Socialist leader, also advocated some of
Bellamy’s
programs. However, the Nationalist movement stressed an evolutionary
not
revolutionary approach to social change. A small group of educated
leaders, not
masses of laborers or workers, would usher in the new society. This
attitude
alienated some of the more radical Socialist and Populist supporters of
Nationalism. Despite temporary
solidarity with these
groups, the Nationalist movement lost popularity and was essentially
defunct by
1894.
Populism and New
Security Laws
With a backdrop of such populist ideas, the 1932 hearings
and findings of the reconstituted Pecora Commission galvanized broad
public
support for new securities laws. As a result, Congress passed and Roosevelt
signed into law the Security Act of 1933, referred to as the “truth in
securities” law, with two basic objectives: 1) require that investors
receive
financial and other significant information concerning securities being
offered
for public sale; and 2) prohibit deceit, misrepresentations, and other
fraud in
the sale of securities.
Congress also passed in 1933 the Glass-Steagall Act, which
mandated a separation of commercial banks that took deposits and
extended
loans, from investment banks that underwrote, issued, and distributed
stocks,
bonds and other securities. The House of Morgan had to split into JP
Morgan
Bank, a commercial bank, and Morgan Stanley, an investment bank to
satisfy
Glass-Steagall, even though both were still controlled by Morgan.
The next year, Congress passed the new Security Exchange Act
of 1934, creating the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) to
protect the
interests of the small investor. The Act empowers the SEC with broad
authority
over all aspects of the securities industry, including the power to
register,
regulate, and oversee brokerage firms, transfer agents, and clearing
agencies
as well as the nation‘s securities self regulatory organizations
(SROs). The
various stock exchanges, such as the New York Stock Exchange, American
Stock
Exchange and National Association of Securities Dealers which operates
the
NASDAQ system are SROs.
Joseph P Kennedy, First
SEC Chairman
President Roosevelt appointed Joseph P. Kennedy as first
chairman of SEC. Kennedy was a highly
successful speculator on Wall Street with a wide network of business
dealings,
not all of which were respectable if not outright illegal, whose
appointment Newsweek described as “a former
speculator and pool operator will now curb speculation and prohibit
pools.”
Unlike other run-of-the-mill speculators, Kennedy had
farsighted political vision which he realized by the shrewd use of his
considerable wealth gained from market tactics that he was now
responsible for
policing. In his first speech as SEC Chairman, Kennedy pronounced a new
populist path for the stock market: “The New Deal in finance will be
found to
be a better deal for all.” Kennedy’s
populism paved the way for his son, John F. Kennedy, to the White House
three
decades later in 1961.
Bill Clinton’s
Rejection of the FDR/Kennedy Populist Tradition
Ironically, another Democratic president, Bill Clinton,
elected on a populist platform in 1992 another three decades later,
repealed in
1999 Glass-Steagall that had created the SEC. The Front Line program of
Public
Television produced a documentary detailing the role of Clinton
Administration
in The
Long Demise of Glass-Steagall.
On November 12, 1999,
President Clinton signed into law the Gramm-Leach-Bailey Financial
Services Modernization Act which repealed the Glass-Steagall Act of
1933, to
allow commercial & investment banks to re-consolidate. The repeal
of the
Glass-Steagall Act, by combining the conflicting roles of lending
institutions
and security issuing institutions, facilitated the development of
structured
finance and debt securitization that contributed structurally to the
2007 credit
crisis.
Phil Gramm, Populist
turned Neo-liberal Republican
Phil Gramm, who began his political career as a Democratic
congressman in the Texas
populist
tradition, changed party affiliation to become a neo-liberal Republican
senator
from Texas. As
Republican
chairman and ranking member of the Senate Banking Committee, he
spearheaded the
Gramm-Leach-Bailey Act of 1999 with the conviction that higher bank
profits
commensurate with higher risk is the salvation of the economy,
reversing the
age-old principle that banks should be the most risk-averse institution
in the
economy.
Between 1995 and 2000, Gramm received over $1 million in
campaign contribution from the securities and investment industry, more
than he
received from oil and gas interests that traditionally were a key
source of
financial energy in Texas
politics. After retiring from politics, Gramm became vice-chairman of
the
investment banking arm of Union Bank of Switzerland (UBS), an
institution
currently in the spotlight for massive losses from subprime mortgage
exposure.
Gramm has been an economic adviser to the presidential campaign of
Republican
candidate John McCain since summer 2007. Also, he is rumored to be one
of
several possible running mates to McCain for 2008.
Enron Controversy
Gramm became linked to the Enron scandal when it came to
light that his wife Wendy, while serving on the Commodity Futures
Trading
Commission, was involved in granting an exemption for Enron from
federal
oversight, immediately after which she was named a director at Enron.
It came
to light later that Gramm had helped to turn the regulatory exemption
into law
as well as push through the deregulation of energy markets that led to
the
Enron scandal. During this period, Enron was a major contributor to
Gramm’s
political campaigns.
Populist Litigation
Against Enron Fraud
The University of California, lead plaintiff for an
investors class action in the Enron securities litigation, obtained
court
approval of a settlement reached on October 6, 2004 with certain of
Enron’s
former directors in which the investor class received $168 million,
consisting
of $155 million in insurance proceeds and more than $13 million in
personal
contributions of insider trading proceeds by Enron directors, including
Wendy
Gramm.
Pursuant to the agreement, the $200-million remaining
balance of Enron’s directors and officers insurance policy was paid
into the
registry of the court and the personal contributions of the directors,
totaling
over $13 million, was deposited in trust with class counsel.
The agreement marked the fourth settlement in the case,
totaling almost one-half billion dollars already recovered for the
class. UC
reached a $222.5-million settlement with Lehman Brothers in October
2004, a
$69-million settlement with Bank of America in July 2004, and a $40
million
settlement in July 2002 with Arthur Andersen’s international umbrella
organization that released Andersen Worldwide SC and its non-US member
firms
from liability and dismissed them from the suit. Arthur Andersen’s US
arm, which served as Enron’s auditor, remains a defendant in the case.
On
December 15, 2004, a unanimous three-judge panel of the US Court of
Appeals for
the Fifth Circuit, sitting in New Orleans, upheld the Anderson
Worldwide SC
settlement.
The defendants in the shareholders’ lawsuit included the
financial institutions of J P Morgan Chase, Citigroup, Merrill Lynch,
Credit
Suisse First Boston, Canadian Imperial Bank of Commerce, Barclays Bank,
Toronto-Dominion Bank and the Royal Bank of Scotland,
all considered key players in a series of fraudulent transactions that
ultimately cost Enron investors billions of dollars. Other defendants
included
various former officers of Enron, its accountants, Arthur Andersen, and
two law
firms.
These defendant banks set up false investments in
clandestinely-controlled Enron partnerships, used offshore companies to
disguise loans and facilitated the phony sale of phantom Enron assets.
As a
result, Enron executives were able to deceive investors by reporting
increased
cash flow from operations and by moving billions of dollars of debt off
their
balance sheets, thereby artificially inflating securities prices.
Unlike Lehman
Brothers, Bank of America and the settling directors, the remaining
bank
defendants are potentially liable for Enron investors’ entire loss.
In February 2002, the University
of California was named
lead
plaintiff in the Enron shareholders’ class action suit previously filed
against
29 top executives of Enron Corp. and its accounting firm, Arthur
Andersen LLP.
UC filed a consolidated complaint on April 8, 2002, adding nine banks and two law
firms as defendants in the
case. In April 2003, US District Court Judge Melinda Harmon completed
her
rulings on the various defendants’ motions to dismiss and lifted the
stay on
discovery. Following those rulings, UC filed a second amended complaint
on May 14, 2003.
Other institutional investors acting as representative
plaintiffs on behalf of Enron investors include Washington State
Investment
Board, the UNITE Family of Funds, San Francisco City and County
Employees’
Retirement System, Employer-Teamsters Local Nos. 175 & 505 Pension
Trust
Fund, Hawaii Laborers Pension Plan, Greenville Plumbers Pension Plan,
Archdiocese of Milwaukee and Staro Asset Management.
The Post-WWI
Republican Decade of Harding, Coolidge and Hoover
After eight years of Woodrow
Wilson as
Democrat president, for the following twelve years from 1921 to 1933,
three
Republican presidents, Warren G. Harding, Calvin Coolidge and Herbert
Hoover,
administered national policy with a conviction that the primary
function of
government was to assist big business in making maximum profit, rather
than to
police unsavory predatory corporate practices for the protection of
small
entrepreneurs and the consumer public. The
phony prosperity of the Roaring Twenties
provided temporary but
false validation of the conjured correctness of such convictions.
Indeed,
corporate profit soared to enable new investment in industrial
expansion,
increasing productivity and the national wealth. But much of the
prosperity
benefited only the financial elite, albeit some did trickle down to
wage
earners in the form of higher employment, low-cost consumer goods and a
generally rising standard of living.
Regressive
Impact of Excessive Corporate Profit
Although a significant portion
of the
population was still trapped in poverty, neither conservatives nor
liberals in
the 1920s were astute enough to realize that while the policy of
stimulating
maximum corporate profit might have been valid in the age of Alexander
Hamilton
when the US was a weak emerging economy plague with underdevelopment
due to
capital scarcity, and even after the Civil War when the US economy was
transitioning from agrarianism to industrialism, such policy of
condoning the
mal-distribution of wealth in the name of the need for capital
formation would
inevitably lead to structural implosion in the new era of abundance and
overcapacity. Public spending in education, health and social safety
fell
behind investment in the private sector. Regional
development was non-existent in
government policy, leaving vast
regions of the country in dire poverty, forcing rural population to
migrate to
urban areas to create massive problems of unguided urbanization,
resulting in
urban slums and the deterioration of central business districts. A
similar
policy blunder of neglecting the public sector was made in the 1990s
and 2000s
under both Democratic and Republican administrations.
Speculative
Bubbles as Solution to Insufficient Demand
To keep growing in an economy
of overcapacity due to insufficient demands, expansion could come only
from
speculative bubble to speculative bubble fueled by debt. Policymakers
in the
1920’s then embraced wholesale dismantle of regulation adopted during
the
Progressive Era to again let the foxes guard the chicken in the
financial
market and to turn to debt/speculation-driven growth, rather than
relying on
the fundamental, utilitarian option of increasing wage income to combat
insufficient demand. Eventually, the debt bubble burst from income
being too
low to sustain inflated asset prices or to meet either debt service or
to
sustain needed consumption, leading to widespread bank failures and
company
insolvencies.
Economic
Equity is a Utilitarian Necessity
Only then did it became apparent
to the
voting public that government abdication of its primary role of
maintaining
fair and equitable wealth distribution had been the key contributing
factor
behind the structural weakness of free market capitalism. Economic
equity is a
utilitarian necessity, not just a moral principle. Fundamentally, the
structural weakness of income mal-distribution and disparity behind the
1929
crash also caused the credit crisis of 2007 when debt greatly outpaced
the
ability of income to service it. The US,
leading the rest of the world, became the victim of a top-heavy finance
sector
expanding at a faster pace than the real economy, with massive amount
of fiat
money going to the places where it was not needed, such as speculation,
rather
than to rising wages on which a balance between supply and demand
critically
depended.
Wealth Disparity
Creates Supply/Demand Imbalance
The economy of the 1920’s was not all fluff. Significant
growth of production resulted from new scientific discoveries and
technological
inventions, new sources of inexpensive power, and new commercial and
financial
techniques to advance market efficiency. By 1929, sixty-nine workers
could
produce the same amount produced by one hundred workers in 1920,
pushing
aggregate production up by 45%. In 1929, national income reached $82
billion,
an increase of 31% after inflation from 1919, against a population
increase of
11%. But wage income as a proportion of national income continued to
decline.
Production value of basic necessities, such as food and clothing
dropped from
58% of the economy to 43%, with sharp increases in new buildings and
machinery
and in durable goods such as autos, household appliances and
telephones. Real
wealth had been created in the 1920s; the only problem was that the
wealth was
not shared equitably, resulting in a supply/demand imbalance. And the
imbalance
was masked by an overblown prosperity created by debt and speculation.
Workers
were encouraged to speculate in the stock market with easy credit and
low margin,
pushing up share prices of companies whose profit strategy was to push
down
worker wages.
Similarity between
1920s and 1990s
Similarly, the economy of the 1990’s was highly innovative.
Epoch making inventions and technical advances greatly increased
productivity
and vastly improved efficient use of resources. Communication made big
leaps in
speed, capacity, mobility and cost reduction. The digital revolution
enabled
exponential gains in information processing and data management, making
the
management of vast, complex systems over long distances routine. These
advances
required new regulations and standards to guide evolving systems toward
paths
of common good and away from paths destructive of sustainable growth.
But while
obsolete regulations were discarded, new relevant regulations were
resisted for
fear of hampering further creative innovation.
Within an unprecedented short time, the financial forces
that commanded the rapid growth of profit from human intelligence
managed to
exploit deregulation to structure a socioeconomic regime that took on
the
appearance of natural law. Under neo-liberal ideology, the economy was
encouraged to mimic the law of the jungle to favor the financially
strong,
rushing towards self destruction as the bottom of the food chain
thinned out
from over hunting and the top of food chain suffered from liver failure
caused
by an excessively rich diet. The problem was exacerbated by an
unsustainable
debt bubble and wild speculation. Easy
access to debt replaced even the need for capital, transforming
capitalism into
a debt-o-mania orgy.
In the 1920’s, the middle class for the better part of a
whole decade was able to enjoy a standard of living previously only
available
to the very rich. A new service sector
of the economy emerged, giving rise to white collar workers as blue
collar
workers in manufacturing declining in proportion faster than in number. By 1930, only 58% of the work force was
engaged in production while between 1920 and 1929, industrial workers
declined
by 500,000 and farm workers declined by 250,000. Over 30% of the work
force was
engaged in the service sector, much of it devoted to serving
speculative needs
of the finance sector.
Henry Ford: Populist
Industrialist
While the expansion of the late 19th
century was centered on railroads, steel and oil, the expansion of the
1920’s
was dominated by a building boom related to the manufacturing of
automobiles.
Henry Ford who formed the Ford Motor Company in 1901, was the first,
and
perhaps the only populist industrialist in US
history. His Model T automobile, introduced in 1908, was produced with
innovative assembly line technology to achieve a selling price for a
quality
product that was affordable by Ford workers, thus transforming the
automobile
from an expensive hand-made toy for the rich to a massed-produced
utilitarian
machine that transformed the transportation pattern of the nation and
the
world. Ford also introduced the 40-hour
week, giving workers leisure to enjoy outings with their families in
his cars.
Ford was able to carry out his populist idea of paying high wages to
create
buyers who could afford to buy the cars they built because he refused
to
surrender his control and independence to bankers and institutional
investors
who would insist on keeping wages at subsistence level to maximize
corporate
profit every quarter. Fordism spread to the entire manufacturing
sector,
producing household appliances, such as washer/driers, dishwashers,
refrigerators, radios, etc at falling prices with rising wages that
directly
improved living standards. Fordism was one of the key factors in
propelling the US
into world
power status.
General Motors and Du
Pont
In 1904, William Capro “Billy” Durant at age 43 gained
control of the Buick Motorcar Company which fell into financial
difficulty
selling luxury cars. Turning Buick into a successful mass production
company of
upscale vehicles for a mass market, Durant use the resultant profit to
acquire
other obsolete car producers and part suppliers such as Oldsmobile,
Pontiac and
Cadillac and others small companies in quick order into a giant
corporation
called General Motors (GM).
Overextended financially during the recession of 1910, GM
was taken over by its bankers and control passed from Durant through a
voting
trust for five years. Durant then went
on to establish Chevrolet in September, 1915
to
produce a car that would compete in price and volume with the Ford
Model T, but
offering more sale-inducing amenities such as a choice of colors
against the
black Model T.
When the bankers’ voting trust expired, Durant regained
control of GM with financial support from the E.I. Du Pont family which
had
made a fortune with its exclusive pattern on dynamite production during
World
War I. War production continued to be highly profitable nonstop since.
In the spring of 1934, five and a half years before the
beginning of World War II when Germany invaded Poland in September
1939,
Fortune magazine ran an article entitled “Arms and Man”, a cheap expose
unworthy of its lofty title. Among other things, it claimed that while
it cost
the War Department $25,000 to kill an enemy soldier, Chicago
gangsters were doing it for $100 a head. Senator Gerald Nye
(Republican, North Dakota),
chairman of a special committee to
investigate illegal links between business and armament, entered the
article
into the Congressional Records, remarking that “there has not been
published in
ages anything so enlightening.” The Nye investigation exposed a few
well-known
“surprises” about the international arms trade: that bribery occurred
in Latin
America and Asia - without linking the observation to the fact that
most arms
purchasers at the time were located in those two turbulent regions,
that home
governments were enlisted to secure foreign sales, that arms
manufacturers
always sold to any customer paying cash or with good credit regardless
of
morals or politics, and often to both sides of the same conflict, and
that arms
embargoes were universally opposed by the arms industry as ineffective
and only
resulting in smuggling.
The Nye investigation did reveal that Du Pont’s plant near Nashville
had grossed a profit of 40,000 percent on its capital, soliciting a
response
from Pierre DuPont that since his company was selling explosive
technology
rather than a commodity (gunpowder) to the government, looking at
return on
capital was misleading. Microsoft uses essentially the same
rationalization on
spectacular profits derived from intellectual property a century later,
as does
the drug industry.
With predatory acquisition and financial manipulation, GM
overnight became the biggest automaker in the world and the most
spectacular
moneymaker of the 1920’s. GM was in the business of making money and
the fact
that it did so through auto manufacturing was only incidental. Ford’s
paternalistic management style was no match for the organizational
approach of
GM. Anyone who invested $25,000 in GM in 1921 was a millionaire by 1929. Durant became one of the richest men in the
country. By 1928, 24.5 million cars had been produced, employing 4
million
workers, about 10% of the work force, while Federal and state
governments spent
over $1 billion a year to build roads for them, with the effect of
greatly
increasing land value in the new “suburban” bedroom towns.
Other industries also experienced unprecedented growth, the
most spectacular being the rapid increase in electricity production,
which
increased from 7.5 billion horsepower to 44 billion, a 600 per cent
increase
from 1912 to 1930 (1 hp. = 2,545. 6 BTU per hour). Aviation was another
technological triumph. The Wright brothers made their first flight in
December
1903 and Charles Lindbergh flew the Spirit of St Louis in a historic
first
cross-Atlantic flight from NY to Paris
in 1927. The age of coal and steam was being replaced by the age of oil
and
electricity which historians labeled the Second Industrial Revolution.
A wave
of unimpeded optimism swept the whole nation.
Free Market Failed to
Distribute Income Fairly
Unfortunately, a serious weakness in the economic system was
the inability of the free market to distribute income fairly to sustain
consumption needed for absorbing the increased production. With each
passing
decade since the Civil War, corporatism had achieved increased
dominance in the US
economy and
a greater share of its new wealth. In 1929, out of 460,000
corporations, 1,350
had annual income in excess of $1 million, earning 80% of all corporate
profits. Half of the corporate wealth and 25% of the national wealth
were
concentrated in 200 firms. Gigantism was in full bloom under a general
rule of
grow or die. Many did die so that a few might become giants who kept
most of
the wealth for their shareholders.
Though wages did rise enough to check the growth of
unionism, wages rose at half the rate of productivity all though the
1920’s. Wages in the decade rose 33%,
management salary rose 42%, corporate profit rose 76% and stockholder
dividend
rose 108%. Pension funds were not significant investors until after the
New
Deal strengthened worker pensions, thus dividend income in the 1920s
went
mostly to the rich. Wage earners were receiving a smaller share of
national
income. Half of the farming families had annual income below $1,000,
less than
$3 a day, less than what low wage workers in Asia
receive today under globalization.
Too much money was going to the rich elite who invested
their savings in more productive capacity and too little money was
going to
wage earners whose spending was needed to balance supply with demand.
Overcapacity then was handled with sharp rise in consumer debt and by
encouraging speculative gains on all levels. But debt addiction
required more
debt until the debt bubble rose beyond the ability of income to carry.
When the
speculation bubble burst, the excessive outstanding debt faced default
through
the decline of the market value of the collaterals. The broad
interconnection
of debt obligations caused a systemic collapse and the Great Depression
began.
Fundamentally, the debt crisis of 2007 had similar causes.
GM shares fell sharply as the stock market began to stall in
April 1929. Durant could have stood on the sideline to wait for the
recovery.
Instead, he was forced by high leverage to try to protect his investors
and
employees by attempting in vain to support GM share prices, buying in
the open
market with full use of margins with limited backing from the
Rockefeller
interests. By October, GM share price had fallen by two-thirds of its
previous
April price of $42 to $14, a fraction of its peak price of $210 in
1926. On
November 16, Durant barely managed to meet a new margin call for
another
$150,000 when the Rockefellers cut off further support.
Two days later, when the GM share price fell
by another 50 cents, Durant failed to meet a new margin call and lost
control
of his 3 million shares of GM stock to JP Morgan and the Du Ponts.
Unlike top
executives of failed firms in 2008 who left in disgrace and still
managed to
leave with tens of million of dollars of company money in severance
pay, in
1929, one of the world’s ten richest men went bankrupt at age 68 and
spent the
rest of his days with a small stipend from GM, managing a bowling alley
in
Flint, Michigan for another 18 years until he died at age 86 in 1947. Those who insist that 2008 is not like 1929
have a point. The other difference is that in 1929, the loss was not
borne by
pension funds which were largely created by the New Deal, unlike 2008
when
pension funds have lost untold billions on supposedly no-risk AAA-rated
investments.
Cutting Production to
Maintain Prices
Instead of cutting prices to maintain production, the
financial establishment in the 1930’s opted for maintaining prices
through
price fixing by cutting production volume, which caused fixed cost per
unit to
increase and unemployment to rise and aggregate wage income to fall
further in
a downward spiral. Another cause of the 1930’s depression was the
economy’s
excessive dependence on the sale of luxury and capital goods, rather
than on
basic necessities. In bad times, such discretionary luxury sales
dropped
precipitously and caused the economy to stall. These conditions are
similar to
those in 2008.
A Matter of
Confidence
Material economic factors were not the only causes for the
Great Depression. The speculative frenzy had pushed the economy into
overdrive
and the bursting of the speculative bubble left investors with more
than just
losses. It wiped out all optimism as well as savings. Confidence in the
market
and the economic system vanished in a matter of days and capitalism was
left
without its key source of energy. Loss of confidence is the major cause
of a
liquidity trap, a situation in which preference for cash overrides all
other
market decisions.
Friedman’s
Counterfactual Conclusion
Milton Friedman in his study of the 1929 crash and the
subsequent depression (Monetary History of the United States, 1963)
concluded
that if only the Fed had provided adequate liquidity, the stock market
crash
would have recovered to avoid the depression. Friedman concentrated his
focus
on the curative effect of monetary policy on recessions and did not
have much
to say about the preventive role of monetary policy on debt bubbles
except that
inflation is a monetary phenomenon. Friedman did not have much to say
about
debt and bubbles.
Friedman accepted the technical definition of inflation as
measured, if not caused, by rising wages. He held out hope that a
monetary
policy focused exclusively on price stability could moderate if not
eliminate
the business cycle, at least moderate the severity of the bursting of a
debt-pushed economic bubble without hampering the boom. His monetarist
dogma
gave support to the flawed central bank doctrine of measuring inflation
by the
rate of increase of wages and consumer prices while detaching inflation
from
asset price increases which central banks welcomed as desirable “wealth
effect”, which permitted the debt bubble and masked the problem of
earned
income deficiency for servicing the outstanding debt.
Friedman’s counterfactual claim of a liquidity magic-wand
solution for the Great Depression was merely academic speculation since
in 1929
the Fed could not legally print money without increasing its gold
holdings, set
at $30 per ounce by the Gold Standard Act of 1900. The act specified
that the
dollar should consist of twenty-five and eight-tenths grains of gold
nine-tenths fine, as established by Section 3511 of the Revised
Statutes of the
United States, shall be the standard unit of value, and all forms of
money
issued or coined by the United States shall be maintained at a parity
of value
with this standard, and it shall be the duty of the Secretary of the
Treasury
to maintain such parity. Friedman was advocating the abandonment of the
Gold
Standard, a position long held by populists.
Greenspan Applied the
Friedman Solution to Save the Market from the 1987 Crash
The 1987 market crash on Black Monday, October 19 when the
Dow Jones Industrial Average fell 22.9% in one day from the effects of
portfolio insurance and program trading, was more severe than on Black Monday, October 28, 1929
when the
DJIA dropped 11.7%. Black Monday 1987 saw the largest one-day decline
since
1914. Greenspan, newly appointed by President Reagan as chairman of the
Fed in
1987, bought Friedman’s liquidity fallacy wholesale. He issued a
one-sentence
statement at 8:41 a.m. on Tuesday, Oct. 20, 49
minutes before
the markets opened at 9:30 a.m.:
"The Federal Reserve, consistent
with its
responsibilities as the nation’s central bank, affirmed today its
readiness to
serve as a source of liquidity to support the economic and financial
system."
Greenspan, free from the gold standard
that constrained the
Fed in 1929, proceeded to use the Fed’s now unlimited power to create
fiat
money to offset the losses in the 1987 crash to keep the market from
seizure,
with E. Gerald Corrigan, president of the New York Federal Reserve
Bank, which
normal transaction of over $1 trillion in the money market each day,
strong-arming all the major banks not to withhold payments for fear of
counterparty default. This posture of
the Fed saved the market but started a dangerous trend of moral hazard
in
subsequent economic slowdowns. The Fed has since provided endless
liquidity to
finance consecutive debt bubbles and their subsequent collapses: 1987
(23%
drop, recovered in 9 months), 1998 (36% drop, recovered in 3 months)
and 2002
(37% drop, recovered in 2 months), each time leading to a bigger debt
bubble. After
18 years of debasing the dollar with excess liquidity, the Greenspan
approach
ultimately landed the debt-infested global economy in its current
disastrous
state of collapsing asset prices denominating in rapidly depreciating
money,
causing a financial meltdown that additional liquidity of increasingly
worthless money can no longer hold up. Worse yet, spiraling prices in
food and
energy, exempted by the Fed from its core inflation index, while wage
income
has remained stagnant, are creating social and political instability
around the
world.
Bernanke Continues
the Friedman/Greenspan Liquidity Fallacy to Deal with Insolvency
The Bernanke Fed has adopted the
Freidman/Greenspan liquidity fallacy and has been desperately trying to
provide
more liquidity to try to regenerate a finance sector stalled by the
August 2007
credit market seizure. Yet many companies outside of the financial
sector, at
least those that have not yet been acquired by private equity firms
with
leveraged debt, are flooded with cash of declining purchasing power but
cannot
find profitable investments for it, mostly because falling prices of
assets are
still too high relative to declining earnings from weak market demand.
Private
equity firms were acquiring companies at high valuation with massive
debt.
Financial institutions are now desperately trying to raise additional
capital
to meet write downs from mounting losses.
Wachovia, the fourth-largest US bank
by assets, warned on April 14, 2008 that the US economy was
deteriorating more
rapidly than expected as it revealed plans to raise $7 billion in
additional
capital with the sale of common stock and convertible preferred shares,
a
discount of more than 15% to Wachovia’s share price on the previous
Friday
closing, after announcing a first-quarter loss of $393 million. It will cut dividend by 41%, providing an
additional $4 billion of capital in two years, and shed 500 jobs in its
investment bank. Wachovia acquired major California
adjustable rate
mortgage lender Golden West Financial for $26 billion at the height of
the
housing boom, a purchase widely derided at the time as too expensive
and
riddled with risk.
Washington Mutual, the largest US
savings and loan group, said a week earlier it would raise $7 billion
in
additional capital. Many more US
banks are expected to raise additional capital in the coming months to
shore up
balance sheets weighed down by rising defaults on mortgages, credit
cards, auto
and other big-ticket item consumer loans. What the need for additional
capital
means is that more liquidity is not a solution for insolvency.
Keynes
on Liquidity Trap
As Keynes observed, no amount of liquidity can overcome a
liquidity trap. In that situation, injecting more liquidity into a
stalled
market serves no purpose except to cause more inflation without halting
economic slowdown. The problem in 1929 was, as it is in 2008, that
asset prices
buoyant by speculation had outstripped the purchasing power of stagnant
income
of consumers. Assets and commodities in the economy were valued at
price levels
that aggregate wage income could not sustain. The solution was not to
inject
more useless liquidity to sustain inoperative price levels which will
only make
the problem worse, but to introduce demand management through full
employment
and to let wages quickly rise back up to the level of wage-price
equilibrium. This was the policy
objective of Roosevelt’s New Deal Program, an
objective
not yet recognized by policymakers in 2008 even amid a revival of
populist
rhetoric.
Denials in 1929 and
2007
During the summer before the stock market crash in October
1929, symptoms of the economy stalling were surfacing with layoffs in
construction, steel, the auto sector and capital goods manufacturing.
Official
reaction was adamant denial in 1929, as it was in 2007, pointing to the
booming
financial sector as evidence of a new economy of endless growth,
assuring the
public with empty talks of good fundamentals in the economy and that
the
economy was merely going through growing pains, wringing out
inefficiencies to
move on to new heights.
Unfazed unemployed workers spent their idle days at retail
brokerage houses making more money trading stocks than their working
wages ever
brought home, expecting to be part of a new nation of speculative
millionaires
who no longer needed to do productive work. They used as capital the
appreciated equity in the homes, the only substantial asset they owned,
albeit
did not earn, and speculate on high margin eagerly provided by their
brokers,
fighting each other to plunge into an overheated market that pundits
kept
telling them would go still much higher.
Banks Promoted
Speculation
For example, in the 1920s, the National City Bank under
Charles H. Mitchell, the forerunner of CitiGroup today, along with its
competitors, did everything possible to encourage stock trading by as
many
common folks as possible, providing credit to anyone willing to sign
for a loan
collateralized by the shares he intended to buy. The loan was based on
the
value of the collateral, not the creditworthiness of the borrower. It
fact, the
less creditworthy borrowers were charged higher interest rates against
“safe”
collaterals of rising share prices, making them preferred customer for
the
banks.
In the 2000s, subrpime status was a credit score for
charging higher interest rates, not a factor to deny credit because the
mortgage was collateralized by houses of rising market price. The
mortgages
were then securitized into tranches of varying credit rating and sold
to
investors with varying risk appetite. In 1929 as in 2007, as prices
turned
against these highly leveraged buyers with insufficient cash flow,
their
brokers were forced to sell their holdings as borrowers failed to meet
margin
calls, not unlike what Bear Stearns & Company was faced with in one
weekend
in late March 2008, except that the Fed in 1929 did not come to the
rescue of
the small speculators who, unlike Bear Stearns, were deemed dispensable
because
they individually were not “too big to fail”. The irony was that, as a
group,
individual small speculators in 1929 were as big if not bigger than
Bear
Stearns’ dispersed counterparty network, or that of any other single
broker-dealer even today. The cumulative effect of default by large
number of
small speculators brought down the entire market.
Economic Crisis
Dominated Politics
The economic crisis of the 1930s that followed the 1929
crash dominated US politics for a whole decade until the onset of World
War II.
Both Republican President Herbert Hoover and later Democrat President
Franklin
D. Roosevelt attempted to bring about recovery within the context of
their
separate ideologies. Government encouragement of, and assistance to
economic growth
had been the established practice of the US
since the time of Alexander Hamilton. However, under Roosevelt, the
measures
adopted by the New Deal were unprecedented in scope and involved
far-reaching
change in the relationship between government and big business, and
more
importantly, on behalf of the common man. It was a politics of Populism.
Hoover and the Corporate State
Hoover
was
apprehensive of the growing power of the state to threaten the spirit
of
private enterprise which, if unchecked, would eventually produce a
“super state
where every man becomes the servant of the State and real liberty is
lost.” He
was oblivious to the danger of the corporate state in which the freedom
of the
common man is threatened. As a Quaker, Hoover
believed that relief for the unemployed and other individual victims of
disasters should be left to voluntary private charity funded by those
more
fortunate. In Hoover’s
world, the
more fortunate tended to be those favored by government policies. On
the other
hand, if needy individuals fell into the habit of dependence on
government
assistance, liberty and the enterprising spirit will be undermined.
The White House biography on Hoover
reads: After the Armistice, Hoover,
a member of the Supreme Economic Council and head of the American
Relief
Administration, organized shipments of food for starving millions in
central Europe.
He extended aid to famine-stricken Soviet Russia in 1921. When a critic
inquired if he was not thus helping Bolshevism, Hoover
retorted, “Twenty million people are starving. Whatever their politics,
they
shall be fed!”
It was a far cry from the US
foreign policy of trade and economic sanction after WWII against
nations deemed
undemocratic.
On the other hand, Hoover
felt that the Federal government might legitimately give financial and
regulatory assistance to big business to preserve private enterprise
for the
common good, because he saw private profit as the sole source of wealth
on
which the government as well as private charity depended for funds. It
was an
approach of feeding the horse that pulls the carriage. Yet as economist
John K.
Galbraith famously quipped about trickling down prosperity: If you feed
the
horse enough oats, the sparrows will eventually benefit from its
droppings.
Hoover held strong personal conviction and showed
considerable strength in standing by his belief through the initial
months of
the depression that began in late 1929. Yet
his willingness to give Federal aid to big
business while denying
public assistance to starving families caused him to appear heartless
and
contrary to the American good Samaritan tradition.
Hoover was a man of high personal integrity, an efficient
administrator and extremely hard-working, but his elitist approach put
him in
history as a president who took office under favorable auspices and
left more
distrusted and disliked except Andrew Jackson immediately after the
Civil War
and perhaps George Bush in 2008. Ironically, he was urged to ran for
the
highest office as a Democrat in 1911 by none other than a young and
rising
Franklin D. Roosevelt, but Hoover declined, commenting that he could
not ran
for a party whose only member in his boyhood home had been the town
drunk.
Yet during the first two years after the 1929 crash, Hoover
doubled Federal spending on public works through private contractors,
urged big
business not to cut wages and sponsored expansionary monetary policies
to
extend credit to companies. Before the crash, Hoover
called a special session of Congress in the summer of 1929 to deal with
early
signs of economic slowdown, which turned into a free for all for
special
interests demanding high tariffs against unfair foreign competition
that sold
goods and agricultural products to US consumers at prices below those
charged
by domestic producers.
Impact of
Smooth-Hawley on Trade
After the 1929 crash, the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act was passed
by overwhelming majority in Congress and signed into law by Hoover
despite a petition signed by over 1,000 economists warning against it. Other governments immediately imposed
countervailing tariffs and world trade came to a screeching halt. The
value of US
export fell from $5.2 billion in 1929 to $1.6 billion in 1932, the
lowest in
constant dollars since 1896. The stock market, having tracked the
fortune of
Smoot-Hawley in Congress, began a downward slide for two and a half
years after
the bill became law.
In 1929, the Federal Reserve, whose powerful chairman,
Benjamin Strong, having recently died, was left without leadership and
continued Strong’s long-established anti-inflation bias of an earlier
era. Many
observers in hindsight, including Milton Friedman, quoted Strong’s 1928
statement that “the very existence of the Federal Reserve System is a
safeguard
against anything like a calamity growing out of money rates. … We have
the
power to deal with such an emergency by flooding the Street with money.” The counterfactual conclusion is that if the
Fed had “flooded the Street with money”, the depression could have been
avoided. This is a controversial point. It might be that flooding the
Street
with money would only create a bigger bubble that would burst later, as
Greenspan and Bernanke would find out seven decades later.
Hoover Misread Dead Cat Bounce
as Recovery
Hoover
was not
being purposely deceptive when he announced that “prosperity is just
around the
corner,” as he truly believed that with a revival of confidence,
recovery would
be at hand. The year 1929 ended with what is now known as a “dead cat
bounce”
which was widely mistaken for a recovery. The market rebound continued
until
the Spring of 1930 despite a continuing decline in economic activities.
When a
group of concerned clergy went to Hoover to urge a public works program
to help
the unemployed, the confident president told them that they had “come
six
months too late; the depression is over.” Having fallen almost
20% from its all time high of 14,164 in October 2007 to 11,740 in March
10, 2008, the DJIA has since surged almost 11% from its low in two
months. It shows all the signs of another dead cat bounce.
By the summer of 1931, as the economic depression spread
around the world, Hoover
persuaded
the victorious WWI allies to accept a one-year moratorium on all war
debts and
reparation payments which never resumed with the election of Adolf
Hitler in Germany.
Right wing populism infested German politics and paved the way for the
rise of
Nazism. At home, Hoover
proposed a
comprehensive program of aid for home owners threatened with
foreclosures and
bankruptcy, putting emphasis on the needs of the economy rather than
the needs
of individual families, arguing that neighborhood blight could result
from
vacant houses, somewhat similar to the range of programs proposed in
2008.
The Democrats gained control of Congress in the 1930 midterm
election from a resurgence of farm-belt progressivism. Yet the new
Congress did
not respond quickly to the Hoover
proposed programs. The Democrats wanted more appropriation for direct
relief to
distressed individuals rather than through subsidies to distressed
corporations. After long and bitter debate and confrontation with the
Hoover
White House, the Democratic Congress created a Reconstruction Finance
Corporation to lend funds to needy corporations. Home-owners threatened
with
foreclosure could have their mortgages refinanced by one of the twelve
newly
created Federal Home Loan Banks while farmers could receive help from
the new
Federal Land Banks.
Six decade later, the Financial Institutions Reform,
Recovery and Enforcement Act of 1989 (FIRREA) enacted in the wake of
the
Savings and Loan crisis of the 1980s and signed into law in August 1989
by
Republican President George HW Bush established the Resolution Trust
Corporation (RTC) to close hundreds of insolvent thrifts and provided
funds for
pay out insurance to their depositors.
The Savings and Loan
Crisis of 1980
Since early 19th century, Savings and Loan
institutions have existed to finance homeownership though the pooling
of
community funds. They were tightly regulated with ceilings on the
interest
rates they were allowed to offer to depositors and the limitation on
funding
residential mortgages only within their homicide. High inflation in the
1970’s
and deregulation of money markets mandated by Depository Institutions
Deregulation and Monetary Control Act of 1980 (DIDMCA) signed into law
by
Democratic President Carter removed the power of the Federal Reserve
Board of
Governors under the Glass-Steagall Act and Regulation Q to set the
interest
rates of savings accounts and caused significant outflows of low-rate
deposits
from S&Ls, as depositors moved their money to the new high-yield
money-market funds. With funds locked up in long-term (30-year
mortgages
written years earlier at fixed interest rates - variable rates
mortgages were
illegal until 1981) that were worth less than face value in a high
interest
rate environment, many S&L’s were threatened with insolvency in a
regime of
term mismatch of interest rates between deposits and loans.
The situation was further exacerbated for the Savings and
Loan institutions by Regulation Q which regulated the interest rates
that
savings and loans and banks were allowed to offer on their savings
accounts.
Interest rates were capped at 5.25% for banks and 5.5% for Savings and
Loans.
While S&Ls were offering 5.5% to their depositors, US Treasury
bills were
yielding over 8% in 1970 and over 15% around 1980. Between 1978 and
1981 money
market mutual funds grew from $9.5 billion to $188.6 billion in assets,
and
many of their customers came from banks and S&Ls.
Policymakers focused on the symptoms of the sick S&L
industry in 1979 and 1980. To address the problems created by a
portfolio full
of long-term, fixed-rate assets, Congress and the administration sought
to
offer S&Ls additional investment opportunities. Thus, adjustable
rate
mortgages were finally allowed to track market rates and to transfer
interest
rate risk from the lenders to borrowers.
The 1980 DIDMCA signed by Democrat president Carter and the
Gain-St Germain Depository Institutions Act of 1982 signed by
Republican
president Reagan also expanded acceptable S&L investments by
permitting
them to make short-term consumer loans, issue credit cards, and
commercial real
estate loans nationwide outside of their home communities. Policymakers
hoped
that broader powers would allow S&Ls to better diversify their
portfolios
so that they could increase their short-term earnings and be less
vulnerable to
future interest rate volatility and economic instability. Policymakers
also addressed
S&Ls' funding problems. The 1980 DIDMCA initiated a six-year phase
out of
deposit interest rate ceilings and encouraged the development of new,
longer-term savings instruments.
In a last-minute conference committee compromise, Congress
also expanded federal deposit insurance coverage from $40,000 per
account to
$100,000 per account, greatly increasing the government’s liability. In
addition to raising the amounts covered by insurance, the amount of the
accounts that would be repaid was increased from 70% to 100%. Increased
coverage by Federal Savings and Loan
Insurance Corporation (FSLIC), also permitted managers to take
more risk
to try to work their way out of insolvency so the government would not
have to
take over an institution. FSLIC was
created as part of the National Housing Act of 1934 in order to insure
deposits
in S&Ls, a year after the FDIC was created to insure deposits in
commercial
banks. It was administered by the Federal Home Loan Bank Board (FHLBB).
In the 1980s, during the Savings and Loan Crisis, the FSLIC
became insolvent. Outstanding US
mortgage loans grew from $700 billion in 1976 to $1.2 trillion in 1980.
FSLIC
was recapitalized with taxpayer money several times, including with $15
billion
in 1986 and $10.75 billion in 1987. However, by 1989 it was deemed too
insolvent to save and was abolished along with the FHLBB by the FIRREA;
savings
and loan deposit insurance responsibility was transferred to the FDIC
One of the most important contributors to the S&L crisis
was deposit brokerage in which brokers were paid a commission by the
customer
to find the highest yield certificate of deposit (CD) issued by a
S&L
anywhere in the nation. These CDs are usually risk-free short-term
$100,000 CDs
fully guaranteed by FSLIC. With the lifting of the previous 5% limit of
brokered deposits, any small single branch thrift could attract a large
number
of deposits simply by offering the highest rate. In order to make money
off
this expensive money, it had to lend at even higher rates to riskier
investments.
This system was made even more damaging when some deposit
brokers instituted a scam known as “linked financing” in which a
deposit broker
would approach a thrift institution with the offer of steering a large
amount
of deposits to that thrift on condition that the thrift would lend to
specified
borrowers. Some of these borrowers were real estate developers who
agreed to
pay a fee to the broker for securing the loan. Other borrowers were
paid by the
broker to apply for loans that they agree to turn over to the deposit
broker
and subsequently defaulted. Michael Milken of Drexel, Burnham and
Lambert
packaged brokered funds for deposit in several large S&Ls on the
condition
that the institutions would buy high-yield junk bonds of his clients.
Drexel
went bankrupt and Milken went to prison as part of the fallout of the
S&L
crisis.
Hoover Promoted Home Ownership
In 1921, Hoover,
as Commerce Secretary under President Harding, launched the “Own Your
Own Home”
campaign to promote ownership of single-family dwellings, including the
Better
Houses in America
movement, the Architects’ Small House Service Bureau, and the Home
Modernizing
Bureau. He worked with bankers and the savings and loan industry to
promote the
new long term home mortgage, which dramatically stimulated home
construction.
As president, Hoover
urged the Federal Reserve to liberalize extension of credit to banks to
allow
them to lend to bank customers. The major error Hoover
made was a tax increase to keep the budget balanced, instead of using
deficit
financing as Roosevelt did two years later. The
Hoover
recovery program did not have a chance to take effect as by the time
they came
into operation the 1932 presidential election was approaching.
Republicans
since Hoover have
repeatedly looked
to tax cuts as the preferred path to stimulate the economy and to cut
Federal
spending to balance the Federal budget. The problem with that approach
is that
tax cuts tend to favor the rich who pay more taxes and cuts in Federal
spending
tend to penalize the poor who depend more on government services. It
further
exacerbates the distribution imbalance of wealth that results in
insufficient
demand.
The 1932 Presidential
Election
During the 1932 campaign, Hoover,
running as an incumbent against Roosevelt,
defended his
recovery program as beginning to show results and that the severe
depression
was caused by global conditions over which the US
had no direct control. The Democrats
also ran on a platform of promising a balanced budget, a cut in Federal
expenditure, a sound currency and no government interference in the
private
sector. Roosevelt even accused Hoover
of failing to keep the budget balanced. But voters were looking for a
change in
leadership even though both parties were promising very similar
solutions to
the economic crisis.
The economy took a drastic turn for the worse right after
the 1932 election, as effective leadership was largely absent during
the
political campaign. By February 1933, panicked depositors were
withdrawing
money from banks at such an alarming rate that state governments were
compelled
to intervene. Michigan
declared a
bank “holiday” in the state on February 14 and by the time Roosevelt
took office on March 4, every other state in the union had taken
similar
action. GNP fell a record 13.4%; unemployment rose to 13 million or
23.6%.
FDR
Before being elected president, few observers expected Roosevelt
to be the outstanding leader he actually turned out to be. Though fully
devoted
to the American ideal of popular democracy with an innate sympathy for
the
underdog and distaste for the privileged and for exploitation and
injustice, Roosevelt
entered the White House with no fixed ideological doctrine but with a
high
degree of Yankee pragmatism.
In fighting to achieve his political objectives of social
justice, Roosevelt showed stubborn courage and
consummate political skill. Above all he was unequal in intuitive grasp
of
popular sentiment and unmatched in capacity for giving it political
expression
and policy direction. His radio speeches, given as “fireside chats” in
simple
language that common folks could understand, enabled him to reach more
people
than any previous leader. This common touch from a Brahman background
along
with his trademarked Rooseveltian gusto and self-assurance made him a
folk
hero.
His supporters both during his lifetime and in history
consider him the greatest of US presidents. His
detractors, on the other hand, accused him
of too incline to
concentrate authority, of capacious administration that led to
duplication,
confusion and waste, and most significantly of dictatorial tendencies,
notwithstanding the fact that Roosevelt was a
leader in
times of crisis and war.
Next: the
Birth of
the New Deal
|